• 沒有找到結果。

External market condition and tournaments: Theory and evidence

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "External market condition and tournaments: Theory and evidence"

Copied!
18
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

S

EMIVARIANCE

A

PPROACH

TO

D

ETERMINING

THE

H

EDGE

R

ATIO

SHENG-SYAN CHEN CHENG-FEW LEE* KESHAB SHRESTHA

A new mean-risk hedge ratio based on the concept of generalized semi-variance (GSV) is proposed. The proposed mean-GSV (M-GSV) hedge ratio is consistent with the GSV-based risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977), Bawa (1975, 1978), and Harlow and Rao (1989). The M-GSV hedge ratio can also be considered an extension of the GSV-minimizing hedge ratio considered by De Jong, De Roon, and Veld (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000). The M-GSV hedge ratio is estimated for Standard & Poor’s (S&P) 500 futures and compared to six other widely used hedge ratios. Because all the hedge ratios considered are known to converge to the minimum-variance (Johnson) hedge ratio under joint

The authors thank two anonymous referees, the editor, Robert Webb, Gautam Vora, and seminar participants at the 1998 FMA meetings for helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are the authors’.

*Correspondence author, Faculty of Management, Rutgers University, Janice H. Levin Building, Rockafeller Road, Piscataway, New Jersey 08854-8054; e-mail: lee@business.rutgers.edu

Received December 1999; Accepted October 2000

Sheng-Syan Chen is an Associate Professor in the Department of Finance in the College of Management at Yuan Ze University in Taoyuan, Taiwan.

Cheng-Few Lee is a Distinguished Professor in the Department of Finance in the Faculty of Management at Rutgers University in New Brunswick, New Jersey.

Keshab Shrestha is an Associate Professor in the Faculty of Administration at the University of Regina in Regina, Saskatchewan, Canada.

The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 21, No. 6, 581–598 (2001) ©2001 by John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

(2)

normality and martingale conditions, tests for normality and martingale conditions are carried out. The empirical results indicate that the joint normality and martingale hypotheses do not hold for the S&P 500 futures. The M-GSV hedge ratio varies less than the GSV hedge ratio for low and relevant levels of risk aversion. Furthermore, the M-GSV hedge ratio con-verges to a value different from the values of the other hedge ratios for higher values of risk aversion. © 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 21: 581–598, 2001

INTRODUCTION

There is a considerable body of literature on the determination of opti-mal hedge ratios based on different criteria. Essentially, this literature suggests that hedge ratios can be classified as either risk-minimizing or utility-maximizing. The risk-minimizing hedge ratios are obtained by a specific risk measure being minimized. Various risk measures are cur-rently being used, such as variance (see Ederington, 1979; Johnson, 1960; Myers & Thompson, 1989), the mean-Gini coefficient (see Cheung, Kwan, & Yip, 1990; Kolb & Okunev, 1992; Lien & Luo, 1993; Shalit, 1995), and generalized semivariance (GSV), also known as the lower partial moment (see De Jong, De Roon, & Veld, 1997; Lien & Tse, 1998, 2000).

The mean-risk hedge ratios, however, are obtained by the maximiza-tion of the utility funcmaximiza-tion or a specific funcmaximiza-tion of expected return and risk (see Cecchetti, Cumby, & Figlewski, 1988; Howard & D’Antonio, 1984; Hsin, Kuo, & Lee, 1994; Kolb & Okunev, 1993). As with the risk-minimizing hedge ratio, variance and the mean-Gini coefficient have been used as risk measures in the derivation of the mean-risk hedge ratio. However, the GSV has not been used to represent the risk in the context of the mean-risk hedge ratio.

In this article, we suggest the use of GSV to represent risk in the derivation of the mean-risk hedge ratio. This hedge ratio is called the mean-GSV (M-GSV) hedge ratio. The M-GSV hedge ratio can be considered an extension of the risk-minimizing hedge ratio (called the

GSV hedge ratio here) considered by De Jong et al. (1997) and Lien and

Tse (1998, 2000). Two important features make the GSV a suitable alternative to other measures of risk. First, the GSV, because of its emphasis on return below target return, is consistent with the risk perceived by managers (see Crum, Laughhunn, & Payne, 1981; Lien & Tse, 2000). Second, the GSV is consistent with the concept of stochastic dominance (see Bawa, 1975, 1978; Fishburn, 1977).

(3)

Even though the concept of GSV is consistent with the concept of stochastic dominance, the GSV hedge ratio considered by De Jong et al. (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000) may not be consistent with stochastic dominance. For the GSV hedge ratio to be consistent with stochastic dominance, it should be independent of the target return. Because the GSV hedge ratios are usually different for different target returns, the independence condition is not satisfied. Therefore, the GSV hedge ratio is not consistent with the concept of stochastic dominance. As an alternative to the GSV hedge ratio, we propose the M-GSV hedge ratio, which is consistent with the risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978) and used by Harlow and Rao (1989) in the context of asset pricing.

This article differs from the existing literature, especially De Jong et al. (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000), in many respects. First, as mentioned previously, we propose a GSV-based mean-risk hedge ratio that is consistent with the risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978). Because the GSV hedge ratio considered by De Jong et al. and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000) ignores the expected return on the hedged portfolio, the M-GSV hedge ratio can be considered an extension of the GSV hedge ratio. Second, we clarify an issue regarding the consistency of the GSV hedge ratio with respect to stochastic dominance. We show that the GSV hedge ratio, consid-ered by De Jong et al. and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000), is not consistent with stochastic dominance. Third, we derive a condition under which the M-GSV hedge ratio will be the same as the minimum-variance (MV) hedge ratio. This condition is different from the normality and martingale conditions required for the convergence of the GSV hedge ratio to the MV hedge ratio. Fourth, we empirically compare the M-GSV hedge ratio with the mean-Gini coefficient hedge ratio, the Sharpe ratio-based hedge ratio, the mean-variance hedge ratio, and the MV hedge ratio. Fifth, we perform the normality and zero expected return (martingale) tests. It is well known that if the spot and futures returns are jointly normal and if the futures price follows a pure martingale process, all the hedge ratios considered will converge to the MV hedge ratio. Therefore, these tests are important from an empirical point of view. Finally, we estimate the semi-variance-based hedge ratio for the Standard & Poor’s (S&P) 500 futures, which is different from the currency futures used by De Jong et al. and the Nikkei 225 futures analyzed by Lien and Tse (1998, 2000).1

1Even though both the Nikkei 225 and S&P 500 futures are stock index futures, the Nikkei 225 is a

price-weighted index, whereas the S&P 500 is a value-weighted stock index. Therefore, we expect them to behave differently.

(4)

The article is divided into five sections. The second section is devot-ed to a literature review. In the third section, the proposdevot-ed M-GSV hdevot-edge ratio is discussed. The optimal hedge ratio is empirically estimated with the S&P 500 futures and is compared with many different hedge ratios in the fourth section. The last section provides a summary and concluding comments.

EXISTING HEDGE RATIOS

In this section, we briefly review different hedge ratios that have been proposed. To facilitate a systematic discussion of these hedge ratios, we divide them into two broad categories: (a) risk-minimizing hedge ratios and (b) mean-risk hedge ratios. A list of the hedge ratios is presented in Table I for easy reference.

Risk-Minimizing Hedge Ratio

The basic concept of hedging is to combine spots and futures positions to form a hedged portfolio that will eliminate (or reduce) fluctuations in the value of the hedged portfolio. Specifically, consider a hedged portfo-lio consisting of one unit of spot position and h units of futures position. Let St and Ft denote the spot and futures prices, respectively. Then, the profit on the so-called hedged portfolio, Rh, is given by

Rh Rs hRf (1)

TABLE I

List of Different Hedge Ratios

Risk-Minimizing Hedge Ratio

Notation Risk Measure Objective Function

MV Variance Minimize (variance) risk

MEG Mean-extended-Gini coefficient (MEG) Minimize (MEG) risk

GSV Generalized semivariance (GSV) Minimize (GSV) risk

Mean-Risk Hedge Ratio

Sharpe Standard deviation Maximize Sharpe ratio

HKL Variance Maximize risk–return function

M-MEG Mean-extended-Gini-coefficient Maximize risk–return function

(5)

where Rs St1 St and Rf Ft1 Ft are one-period profits on spot and futures, respectively.2 The standard risk-minimizing hedge ratio, which is known as the MV hedge ratio, is obtained by minimization of the variance of Rh (see Ederington, 1979; Johnson, 1960). Another risk-minimizing hedge ratio, which is called the mean-extended-Gini (MEG)

hedge ratio, is obtained by minimization of the MEG coefficient, v(Rh), defined as follows (see Cheung et al., 1990; Kolb & Okunev, 1992; Lien & Luo, 1993; Lien & Shaffer, 1999; Gregory-Allen & Shalit, 1995):

v(Rh) vCov(Rh,(1 G(Rh))v1) (2)

where G is the cumulative probability distribution function and v is the risk-aversion parameter. Note that 0 v  1 implies risk seekers, v  1 means risk-neutral, and v 1 means risk-averse investors. This MEG hedge ratio can be shown to be consistent with second-order stochastic dominance (see Shalit & Yitzhaki, 1984, 1989; Yitzhaki, 1982, 1983). Furthermore, Shalit (1995) showed that if the prices are jointly normally distributed, the MEG hedge ratio will be the same as the MV hedge ratio. Yet another risk-minimizing hedge ratio is obtained by minimization of the following GSV (see De Jong et al., 1997; Lien & Tse, 1998, 2000):3

(3) where G(Rh) is the probability distribution function of the return on the hedge portfolio Rh. This hedge ratio is called the GSV hedge ratio. The parameters d and a (which are both real numbers) represent the target return and risk aversion, respectively. Here, the risk is defined in such a way that the investors consider possibilities of the returns below the tar-get return (d) as risky but not the returns above the tartar-get return. It can be shown (see Fishburn, 1977) that a  1 represents a risk-seeking investor and a 1 represents a risk-averse investor.

The GSV is consistent with the risk perceived by managers (see Crum et al., 1981; Lien & Tse, 2000). Furthermore, as shown by

Vd,a(Rh) 

d

(d  Rh) a

dG(Rh), a 7 0

2Sometimes, the return on the hedged portfolio is considered, in which case R

s (St1 St)兾St,

Rf (Ft1 Ft)兾Ft, and the hedge ratio is given by hFt兾St.

3De Jong et al. (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000) computed the optimal hedge ratios by

mini-mizing the GSV given by Equation 3 for various values of a. If the values of a are restricted to posi-tive integers, GSV is also known as the lower partial moment. Because we allow a to be any posiposi-tive real number, we prefer to call it the GSV instead of lower partial moments. Although both Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1978) discussed the relationships among GSV, stochastic dominance, and expect-ed utility, Bawa restrictexpect-ed the value of a to positive integers, whereas Fishburn allowexpect-ed a to be any positive real value.

(6)

Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978), the GSV is consistent with the concepts of stochastic dominance. Specifically, Vd,a(Rh) is consistent with the first-order (FSD), second-order (SSD), and third-order stochas-tic dominance (TSD) relations for a  0, a  1, and a  2, respectively.4 Lien and Tse (1998) showed that if the futures and spot returns are jointly normally distributed and if the futures price follows a pure mar-tingale process, the GSV hedge ratio will be equal to the MV hedge ratio.

Mean-Risk Hedge Ratio

All hedge ratios, discussed under the risk-minimizing hedge ratios, ignore the expected return aspect of the hedged portfolio. Next, we con-sider the class of hedge ratios that incorporate both risk and expected return in the derivation of the hedge ratios. These hedge ratios are called

mean-risk hedge ratios. One example of a mean-risk hedge ratio is the

Sharpe ratio-based hedge ratio considered by Howard and D’Antonio (1984). This hedge ratio, which is called the Sharpe hedge ratio, is obtained by maximization of the following risk–return function:

(4) where i is the risk-free rate. The Sharpe hedge ratio does not explicitly incorporate the risk-aversion parameter. A mean-risk hedge ratio that explicitly incorporates the risk-aversion parameter was considered by Hsin et al. (1994); the hedge ratio is obtained by maximization of the fol-lowing risk–return function:

(5) where is equal to Var(Rh) and A represents the risk-aversion parame-ter. This hedge ratio is called the HKL hedge ratio. Both the Sharpe and HKL hedge ratios will be the same as the MV hedge ratio if the futures price follows a pure martingale process.

However, another type of mean-risk hedge ratio is obtained by maxi-mization of the following risk–return function (see Kolb & Okunev, 1993):

U(Rh) E(Rh) v(Rh) (6) s2h

V(E(Rh), sh; A)  E(Rh) 0.5Ash2

u  E(Rh) i sh

4We discuss the consistency of the GSV with the concept of stochastic dominance more when we

(7)

This risk–return function uses the MEG coefficient as the measure of risk. This hedge ratio is called the M-MEG hedge ratio. It can be shown that the M-MEG hedge ratio is consistent with SSD (see Shalit & Yitzhaki, 1984, 1989; Yitzhaki, 1982, 1983). It is clear that if the futures price follows a pure martingale process, the M-MEG hedge ratio will be the same as the MEG hedge ratio. From Shalit (1995), it is clear that in addition to the martingale property, if futures and spot prices are jointly normally distributed, the M-MEG hedge ratio will be the same as the MV hedge ratio.

Kolb and Okunev (1992) found that for low levels of the risk-aversion parameter (v  2–5), the MEG hedge ratio is close to the MV hedge ratio, whereas for higher levels of the risk-aversion parameter, the MEG hedge ratio is quite different from the MV hedge ratio. However, Kolb and Okunev (1993) found that for higher levels of the risk-aversion parameter, the M-MEG hedge ratio converges to the MV hedge ratio.

M-GSV HEDGE RATIO

In this article, we extend the GSV hedge ratio considered by De Jong et al. (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000) to the M-GSV hedge ratio, where the optimal hedge ratio is obtained by maximization of the follow-ing risk–return function:

U(Rh) E[Rh] Vd,a(Rh) (7) The M-GSV hedge ratio is similar to the GSV hedge ratio (Equation 3), except that the GSV hedge ratio ignores the expected return on the hedged portfolio. In this model, we do not use the risk-aversion parame-ter to multiply the GSV as done in the HKL model (see Equation 5). This is because the risk-aversion parameter is implicitly included in the defi-nition of Vd,a(Rh), where a represents the risk aversion.

At this point, we explain the reason for extending the GSV hedge ratio to the M-GSV hedge ratio. This has to do with the fact that for the GSV hedge ratio to stochastically dominate all other hedge ratios, the GSV hedge ratio should be independent of the target return d (see Bawa, 1975, 1978; Fishburn, 1977). It can be shown that, in general, the GSV hedge ratio is not independent of the target return.5 Therefore, a better way of using the GSV as a measure of risk is to base the hedge ratio on the mean-semivariance rule or the risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978), who provided the theoretical

(8)

justifications for such a mean-semivariance rule. This is accomplished by the proposed M-GSV hedge ratio, which is consistent with the risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978). The GSV hedge ratio will be the same as the M-GSV hedge ratio if the futures price follows a pure martingale process. Furthermore, as shown by Lien and Tse (1998), if the futures price follows a pure martingale process and if the futures and spot returns are jointly normal, the MV hedge ratio will be the same as the GSV hedge ratio. Because the M-GSV and GSV hedge ratios are the same under the martingale property, M-GSV, GSV, and MV hedge ratios will be the same if joint normality holds in addition to the martingale property. Another condi-tion, which does not require the normality assumpcondi-tion, is given in the following proposition:

Suppose that the futures price follows a pure martingale process (i.e., the return on the futures is equal to zero). Furthermore, suppose that the return on the hedged portfolio is symmetrically distributed around the target return d. Then, the M-GSV, GSV, and MV hedge ratios will be the same for a  2.

As for the estimation of the M-GSV hedge ratio, there are different methods that can be used (see Ahmadi, Sharp, & Walther, 1986; Lien & Tse, 1998, 2000). We choose the empirical distribution-based technique because of its simplicity and desirable small-sample property. For exam-ple, the estimate of GSV based on the empirical distribution is unbiased (see Ahmadi et al., 1986).

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

We estimate the M-GSV hedge ratio and compare it with five other hedge ratios (see Table I) with the weekly S&P 500 futures data from April 21, 1982 to December 27, 1991 (490 weeks of data). Data were obtained from Datastream.

Before estimating any of the hedge ratios, we must determine whether the futures and spot price changes are normally distributed and whether the futures price follows a pure martingale process. The nor-mality and pure martingale tests on the S&P 500 futures are given in Table II. It is clear that the expected futures price change is positive and is more than eight times its standard error. This clearly indicates that the futures price does not follow a pure martingale process. With respect to normality, we computed two different statistics. The Jarque–Bera test statistics (see Jarque & Bera, 1987) are highly significant (even at the

(9)

0.5% level) for both spot and futures price changes. The same conclu-sion is true for the D’Agostino D statistic (D’Agostino, 1971). Therefore, it is clear that neither normality nor the pure martingale hypothesis hold for S&P 500 spot and futures prices. This means that for the S&P 500 futures, Sharpe, HKL, GSV, M-GSV, MEG, and M-MEG ratios are expected to be different from the standard MV hedge ratio. Because one of the objectives of the article is to compare the M-GSV hedge ratio with other hedge ratios, we first discuss the estimation of the MV, Sharpe, and HKL hedge ratios. The MV hedge ratio is equal to 0.8523. As for the Sharpe hedge ratio, in our case it does not exist. This has to do with the fact that the Sharpe ratio given by Equation 4 continuously increas-es with the hedge ratio. Therefore, there is no finite optimal solution. Actually, if we use the formula given by Howard and D’Antonio (1984, their Equation 6), we get the hedge ratio corresponding to the minimum, instead of the maximum, Sharpe ratio. This is because the second-order condition is not satisfied. For our sample, the dependence of the Sharpe ratio on the hedge ratio is shown in Figure 1. From the figure, it can be seen that the Sharpe ratio does not have the maximum, and the zero slope point corresponds to the minimum Sharpe ratio instead of the maximum one. Such behavior makes the Sharpe ratio-based hedge ratio less reliable. This is also supported by the fact that De Jong et al. (1997) found the hedge ratio fluctuated widely (e.g., from 41.41 to 88.48 for Japanese yen).

TABLE II

Summary Statistics of the Spot and Futures Price Change

Statistics Spot Price Change Futures Price Change

Sample mean 0.5934 0.5928

Standard error of mean (SE) 0.0727 0.0730

Skewness 3.546 5.023

Standardized kurtosis 41.200 68.356

Jarque–Bera test 35,683.09 97,456.85

D’Agostino D statistic 32.908 41.879

Number of observations 490 490

Note: The standard error of the sample mean is computed with the following formula, which corrects for the serial auto-correlation:

where denotes the lag j autocovariance. The Jarque–Bera test statistic is based on Jarque and Bera (1987) and is asymptotically chi-square-distributed with 2 degrees of freedom. The critical values at 5 and 1% are 5.991 and 9.210, respectively. The D’Agostino D statistic is based on D’Agostino (1971) and is asymptotically distributed as a normal N(0,1). The critical values at 5 and 1% are 1.960 and 2.576, respectively.

g(j) SE B 1 T a jT1 j(T1)c 1  0j0 T d g(j)

(10)

Next, we estimate different mean-risk (HKL) hedge ratios based on the Hsin–Kuo–Lee model (Equation 5) for different values of the risk-aversion parameter (A). The optimal HKL hedge ratios are shown in Figure 2. It is clear from the diagram that the optimal HKL hedge ratio smoothly converges to the MV hedge ratio for values of A greater than 3.0. This is expected because for high values of the risk-aversion parameter, the expected return becomes less important and the resulting hedge ratio will be the same as the risk-minimizing hedge ratio.

FIGURE 1

Sharpe ratio as a function of the hedge ratio (Howard–D’Antonio model).

FIGURE 2

Optimal mean-risk hedge ratio based on the Hsin–Kuo–Lee model for different values of risk aversion (A).

(11)

Now we turn to the estimation of the MEG- and GSV-based hedge ratios. Before the GSV-based hedge ratios can be estimated, we need to decide on the two parameters: the target return d and the risk-aversion parameter a. In the empirical analysis, two different target returns d are used. First, the target return d is set to the sample average of the S&P 500 spot price changes (which is equal to 0.5933 per week). This choice is consistent with the empirical result obtained by Harlow and Rao (1989). They inferred that the target return is related to the market mean return. Alternatively, the target return d is set to zero (this is the value used by De Jong et al., 1997). Once the value of d is fixed, the optimal hedge ratios are calculated for a range of values of the risk-aversion parameter a (1.25–60). Because the MEG-based hedge ratios also depend on the risk-aversion parameter (v), these hedge ratios are also estimated for the same range of values for the risk-aversion param-eter v. However, even if we use the same range for a and v, a value of a does not correspond to the same value of v; that is, v 1 is not equiva-lent to a 1.6

The estimates of the MEG and GSV hedge ratios are presented in Table III and plotted in Figure 3. The GSV hedge ratio is higher than the MEG hedge ratio. Both the GSV and MEG hedge ratios seem to converge to fixed but different values as the risk-aversion parameter becomes large. The MEG hedge ratio seems to converge to a ratio that is close to the MV hedge ratio. However, the GSV hedge ratio seems to converge to a higher value. We discuss this issue of convergence more when we dis-cuss the M-MEG and M-GSV hedge ratios next.

The remaining two hedge ratios, M-GSV and M-MEG hedge ratios, are presented in Table IV for different values of the risk-aversion parameters a and v. Figure 4 plots the two hedge ratios as well as the MV hedge ratio (0.8523). As before, two different values of the target return [d  0 and d  E(Rs)] are used. First, we compare the estimates of M-GSV and GSV hedge ratios. As discussed earlier, for the GSV-based models the relevant range of a is a 2 (see Footnote 6). For this range, the M-GSV hedge ratio varies less [0.8562 to 0.8652 for d  E(Rs)] than the GSV hedge ratio, which varies from 0.8699 to 0.8967. Furthermore, the M-GSV leads to less hedging than the GSV. This is reasonable because the sample mean of the futures price changes is

6Because some of the most widely used assumptions regarding utility functions are either risk

aver-sion or risk averaver-sion with decreasing absolute risk averaver-sion, the most relevant range of values for a is a 2. This range also covers the FSD, SSD, and TSD relations. However, we estimated the hedge ratios for values of a greater than 2 to see if there was any indication of the hedge ratios converging to a fixed value and to see if there was any association between the higher values of a and higher values of v for the MEG hedge ratio.

(12)

positive (0.5928; see Table II). Therefore, a more negative hedge ratio means a lower expected profit on the hedged portfolio. Because the M-GSV incorporates both expected profit and risk, the M-GSV hedge ratio should lead to less hedging (i.e., a less negative hedge ratio) than the GSV hedge ratio.

Another interesting observation is that both the GSV and M-MEG hedge ratios are found to converge to fixed but different values as the risk-aversion parameter becomes large. The M-MEG hedge ratio seems to converge to a value that is close to the MV hedge ratio. However, the M-GSV hedge ratio seems to converge to a higher value; that is, the M-MEG hedge ratio will lead to overhedging compared to the M-GSV hedge ratio. The convergence of the M-MEG and M-GSV hedge ratios needs to be discussed further. Our result, which indicates the convergence of the M-MEG hedge ratio to the MV hedge ratio, is not universal. As mentioned before, Kolb and Okunev (1992) found the MEG hedge ratios to converge to values different than those of the MV hedge ratios for five different commodities (including the S&P 500

TABLE III

Risk-Minimizing Generalized-Semivariance (GSV) and Mean-Extended-Gini Coefficient (MEG) Hedge Ratios for Different Values of Risk-Aversion Parameters

GSV Hedge Ratio MEG Hedge Ratio

a d E(Rs) d 0 v Hedge Ratio

1.25 0.8967 0.9013 1.25 0.9045 1.50 0.8913 0.8879 1.50 0.9171 1.75 0.8816 0.8739 1.75 0.9206 2.00 0.8699 0.8603 2.00 0.9222 2.25 0.8567 0.8452 2.25 0.9227 2.50 0.8424 0.8292 2.50 0.9227 2.75 0.8271 0.8126 2.75 0.9224 3.00 0.8107 0.7951 3.00 0.9218 4.00 0.7484 0.7377 4.00 0.9186 5.00 0.7210 0.7158 5.00 0.9138 6.00 0.7083 0.7051 6.00 0.9089 7.00 0.7011 0.6989 7.00 0.9047 8.00 0.6966 0.6949 8.00 0.9005 9.00 0.6934 0.6921 9.00 0.8968 10.00 0.6911 0.6900 10.00 0.8933 20.00 0.6822 0.6818 20.00 0.8713 30.00 0.6797 0.6794 30.00 0.8570 40.00 0.6784 0.6782 40.00 0.8510 50.00 0.6777 0.6775 50.00 0.8476 60.00 0.6772 0.6771 60.00 0.8476

(13)

FIGURE 3

Risk-minimizing GSV and MEG hedge ratios for different values of risk-aversion parameters. The GSV hedge ratio is calculated with d E(Rs). The values for the GSV hedge ratio are taken from the second column of Table III. Similarly, the values for the

MEG coefficient hedge ratio are taken from the fifth column of Table III. The MV hedge ratio is equal to 0.8523.

7They consider daily data for corn, copper, German mark, gold, and S&P 500 futures for 1989.

futures).7 However, Kolb and Okunev (1993) found that the M-MEG hedge ratio converges close to the MV hedge ratio.

As for the convergence of the M-GSV hedge ratio, the finding that the M-GSV hedge ratio converges to a value different from the MV hedge ratio is not surprising. The M-GSV hedge ratio is expected to be different from the MV hedge ratio because the M-GSV hedge ratio uses the GSV to measure the risk, whereas the MV hedge ratio uses variance as the measure of risk. So long as these two measures of risk are differ-ent, the two hedge ratios are expected to be different. Because the GSV considers below target return to be risky whereas variance considers both above and below mean return to be risky, these two risk measures are expected to be different unless the joint normality condition or the sym-metric distribution condition (as given in the proposition) is satisfied. From Table II, it is clear that none of these conditions is satisfied. Therefore, we expect the M-GSV hedge ratio to converge to values dif-ferent from the MV hedge ratio.

(14)

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

In this article, we extended the GSV-minimizing hedge ratio considered by De Jong et al. (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000) to an M-GSV hedge ratio. This article differs from the existing work, especially by De Jong et al. and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000), in many respects. First, we extended the risk-minimizing hedge ratio to a risk–return hedge ratio. This makes the M-GSV hedge ratio consistent with the risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978). Second, we clari-fied an issue regarding the consistency of the GSV hedge ratio with respect to stochastic dominance. We showed that the GSV hedge ratio, considered by De Jong et al. and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000), is not con-sistent with stochastic dominance. Third, we showed that under some cir-cumstances the assumption of symmetrical distribution is sufficient to have the M-GSV hedge ratio converge to the standard MV hedge ratio.

TABLE IV

M-GSV Hedge Ratio and M-MEG Hedge Ratios for Different Values of Risk-Aversion Parameters

M-GSV Hedge Ratio M-MEG Hedge Ratio

a d E(Rs) d 0 v Hedge Ratio

1.25 0.8562 0.8562 1.25 0.7955 1.50 0.8652 0.8582 1.50 0.8600 1.75 0.8647 0.8548 1.75 0.8800 2.00 0.8591 0.8474 2.00 0.8887 2.25 0.8500 0.8368 2.25 0.8930 2.50 0.8383 0.8241 2.50 0.8957 2.75 0.8246 0.8095 2.75 0.8972 3.00 0.8092 0.7933 3.00 0.8978 4.00 0.7483 0.7376 4.00 0.8976 5.00 0.7210 0.7158 5.00 0.8953 6.00 0.7083 0.7051 6.00 0.8921 7.00 0.7011 0.6989 7.00 0.8894 8.00 0.6966 0.6949 8.00 0.8869 9.00 0.6934 0.6921 9.00 0.8848 10.00 0.6911 0.6900 10.00 0.8813 20.00 0.6822 0.6818 20.00 0.8615 30.00 0.6797 0.6794 30.00 0.8512 40.00 0.6784 0.6782 40.00 0.8476 50.00 0.6777 0.6775 50.00 0.8462 60.00 0.6772 0.6771 60.00 0.8462

Minimum-variance (Johnson) hedge ratio 0.8523

(15)

Fourth, we compared the M-GSV hedge ratio to other hedge ratios, which include the MEG coefficient (M-MEG) hedge ratio, the Sharpe ratio-based hedge ratio, the standard mean-variance hedge ratio, and the MV hedge ratio. Fifth, we estimated all seven hedge ratios for the S&P 500 futures, which is different from the currency futures used by De Jong et al. and the Nikkei 225 futures analyzed by Lien and Tse (1998, 2000). Finally, we performed two different types of normality tests (Jarque–Bera and D’Agostino tests) as well as the martingale hypothesis tests to see if different hedge ratios converge to the MV hedge ratio.

We found that the S&P 500 futures and spot prices are neither jointly nor individually normally distributed. Furthermore, the martin-gale hypothesis does not hold, indicating that the expected futures price change is not zero. Therefore, we conclude that the various hedge ratios considered are different from the standard MV hedge ratio.

We found that the M-GSV hedge ratio varies less than the GSV hedge ratio for lower and relevant levels of risk aversion. The M-GSV hedge ratio converges to a value higher than the MV hedge ratio for large values of risk aversion. However, the M-MEG hedge ratio converges to a value close to the MV hedge ratio for large values of the risk aversion. This can be explained by the fact that the M-GSV hedge ratio uses GSV as the risk measure, unlike the MV hedge ratio, which uses variance as the risk measure.

FIGURE 4

M-GSV hedge ratio and M-MEG hedge ratio for different values of risk-aversion parameters. The M-GSV hedge ratio is calculated with d E(Rs).

The values for the GSV hedge ratio are taken from the second column of Table IV. Similarly, the values for the M-MEG hedge ratio are taken from the

(16)

APPENDIX

According to the analyses of Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1975, 1978), for the GSV hedge ratio to stochastically dominate all other hedge ratios, the GSV hedge ratio should have the minimum GSV for all values of the target return d. This condition will be satisfied if the GSV hedge ratio is independent of the target return (d). It can be shown that the derivative of the GSV hedge ratio h* with respect to d is given by the following (see Lien & Tse, 1998, 2000):

(A1)

where f(Rs, Rf) is the joint density function.8 Therefore, for to be equal to zero, we need the following condition to be satisfied:

(A2) In general, this condition is not satisfied. Therefore, in a strict sense the GSV hedge ratio will not be consistent with the concept of stochastic dominance relations and the expected utility model.9

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Ahmadi, H. Z., Sharp, P. A., & Walther, C. H. (1986). The effectiveness of futures and options in hedging currency risk. Advances in Futures and Option Research, 1, 171–191.

Bawa, V. S. (1975). Optimal rules for ordering uncertain prospects. Journal of Financial Economics, 2, 95–121.

Bawa, V. S. (1978). Safety-first, stochastic dominance, and optimal portfolio choice. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 13, 255–271. Cecchetti, S. G., Cumby, R. E., & Figlewski, S. (1988). Estimation of the

opti-mal futures hedge. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70, 623–630. Cheung, C. S., Kwan, C. C. Y., & Yip, C. Y. (1990). The hedging effectiveness of

options and futures: A mean-Gini approach. Journal of Futures Markets, 10, 61–74.



dhRf  (d Rs  hRf)a2 Rf f(Rs, Rf) dRsdRf  0 dhdd dhdd   兰 兰dhRf  (d Rs  hRf)a2 Rf f(Rs, Rf) dRsdRf 兰dhRf  (d Rs  hRf)a2 R2f f(Rs, Rf) dRsdRf

8Equation A1 corresponds to Equation 9 in Lien and Tse (2000), except that the negative sign is

missing in Lien and Tse (2000).

9Note, however, that if the return distributions are jointly normal and the futures price follows a

pure martingale process, the GSV hedge ratio will be consistent with the concepts of stochastic dominance relations and the expected utility hypothesis. This is so because the optimal hedge ratio will be equal to the MV hedge ratio, which is independent of d.

(17)

Crum, R. L., Laughhunn, D. L., & Payne, J. W. (1981). Risk-seeking behavior and its implications for financial models. Financial Management, 10(5), 20–27.

D’Agostino, R. B. (1971). An omnibus test of normality for moderate and large size samples. Biometrika, 58, 341–348.

De Jong, A., De Roon, F., & Veld, C. (1997). Out-of-sample hedging effective-ness of currency futures for alternative models and hedging strategies. Journal of Futures Markets, 17, 817–837.

Ederington, L. H. (1979). The hedging performance of the new futures markets. Journal of Finance, 34, 157–170.

Fishburn, P. C. (1977). Mean-risk analysis with risk associated with below-target returns. American Economic Review, 67(2), 116–126.

Gregory-Allen, R. B., & Shalit, H. (1999). The estimation of systemic risk under differentiated risk-aversion: A mean-extended Gini approach. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 12, 135–157

Harlow, W. V., & Rao, R. K. S. (1989). Asset pricing in a generalized mean-lower partial moment framework: Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 24, 285–311.

Howard, C. T., & D’Antonio, L. J. (1984). A risk–return measure of hedging effectiveness. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 19, 101–112.

Hsin, C. W., Kuo, J., & Lee, C. F. (1994). A new measure to compare the hedg-ing effectiveness of foreign currency futures versus options. Journal of Futures Markets, 14, 685–707.

Jarque, C. M., & Bera, A. K. (1987). A test for normality of observations and regression residuals. International Statistical Review, 55, 163–172.

Johnson, L. L. (1960). The theory of hedging and speculation in commodity futures. Review of Economic Studies, 27, 139–151.

Kolb, R. W., & Okunev, J. (1992). An empirical evaluation of the extended mean-Gini coefficient for futures hedging. Journal of Futures Markets, 12, 177–186.

Kolb, R. W., & Okunev, J. (1993). Utility maximizing hedge ratios in the extend-ed mean Gini framework. Journal of Futures Markets, 13, 597–609. Lien, D., & Luo, X. (1993). Estimating the extended mean-Gini coefficient for

futures hedging. Journal of Futures Markets, 13, 665–676.

Lien, D., & Shaffer, D. R. (1999). A note on estimating the minimum extended Gini hedge ratio. Journal of Futures Markets, 19, 101–113.

Lien, D., & Tse, Y. K. (1998). Hedging time-varying downside risk. Journal of Futures Markets, 18, 705–722.

Lien, D., & Tse, Y. K. (2000). Hedging downside risk with futures contracts. Applied Financial Economics, 10(2), 163–170.

Myers, R. J., & Thompson, S. R. (1989). Generalized optimal hedge ratio esti-mation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 71, 858–868.

Shalit, H. (1995). Mean-Gini hedging in futures markets. Journal of Futures Markets, 15, 617–635.

Shalit, H., & Yitzhaki, S. (1984). Mean-Gini, portfolio theory, and the pricing of risky assets. Journal of Finance, 39, 1449–1468.

(18)

Shalit, H., & Yitzhaki, S. (1989). Evaluating the mean-Gini approach to portfo-lio selection. International Journal of Finance, 1(2), 15–31.

Yitzhaki, S. (1982). Stochastic dominance, mean variance, and Gini’s mean dif-ference. American Economic Review, 72(1), 178–185.

Yitzhaki, S. (1983). On an extension of the Gini inequality index. International Economic Review, 24, 617–628.

數據

TABLE III
TABLE IV

參考文獻

相關文件

More than 90% of the leaders reported that the Panel Chair was also expected to ensure that all teachers followed curriculum guidelines, and to review evidence of teaching

Wang, Solving pseudomonotone variational inequalities and pseudocon- vex optimization problems using the projection neural network, IEEE Transactions on Neural Networks 17

Then, it is easy to see that there are 9 problems for which the iterative numbers of the algorithm using ψ α,θ,p in the case of θ = 1 and p = 3 are less than the one of the

Define instead the imaginary.. potential, magnetic field, lattice…) Dirac-BdG Hamiltonian:. with small, and matrix

 name common laboratory apparatus (e.g., beaker, test tube, test-tube rack, glass rod, dropper, spatula, measuring cylinder, Bunsen burner, tripod, wire gauze and heat-proof

Microphone and 600 ohm line conduits shall be mechanically and electrically connected to receptacle boxes and electrically grounded to the audio system ground point.. Lines in

• To achieve small expected risk, that is good generalization performance ⇒ both the empirical risk and the ratio between VC dimension and the number of data points have to be small..

• A delta-gamma hedge is a delta hedge that maintains zero portfolio gamma, or gamma neutrality. • To meet this extra condition, one more security needs to be