• 沒有找到結果。

Health-Related Quality of Life after Stroke: Review of the literature and Implications for Future Research

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Health-Related Quality of Life after Stroke: Review of the literature and Implications for Future Research"

Copied!
6
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

From the 1

Department of Business Management, National Sun Yat-Sen University, Kaohsiung, Taiwan; 2

Department of Neurology, Chi-Mei Medical Center, Tainan, Taiwan.

Received November 15, 2006.

Revised and Accepted December 13, 2006.

Reprint requests and correspondence to: Huey-Juan Lin, MD. Department of Neurology, Chi-Mei Medical Center, No. 901, Chung-Hwa Road, Yong-Kang, Tainan, Taiwan.

E-mail: huikuanlin@gmail.com

INTRODUCTION

Limits on health care resources naturally mandate that resource-allocation decisions be guided by consid-eration of cost in relation to expected benefits. It there-fore leads to an increased demand for economic evalua-tion and medical technology assessment. There are some major kinds of economic evaluation in health and medicine(1,2). Among them, cost-effectiveness analysis

(CEA) has emerged as a favored analytic technique. As the National Health Insurance (NHI) system in Taiwan is trying to control costs while maintaining or even improving quality of care, it is not surprising to find that CEA would attract more and more attention in our health care decision-making.

In CEA, the resources (costs) used and the health outcomes (effects) associated with each specific inter-vention (such as drugs, devices, procedures, and

pro-Health-Related Quality of Life after Stroke:

Review of the Literature and Implications for Future Research

Mei-Chiun Tseng

1

and Huey-Juan Lin

2

Abstract- Limits on health care resources mandate that resource-allocation decisions be guided by

consid-eration of cost in relation to the associated expected benefits. It therefore leads to an increased demand for economic evaluation and medical technology assessment. Nowadays, cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) has emerged as a favored analytic technique for economic evaluation in health care. Currently the leading stan-dard in Western countries is the use of health-adjusted life years (HAYLs) in CEA of medical care and health interventions, as well as in estimating burden of disease. Being an umbrella term of a family of mea-sures, HALYs include quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) and disability-adjusted life years (DALYs). In this review we give a concise overview on QALYs and DALYs, and examine variations in QALYs and DALYs estimates currently used in stroke studies. Given the lack of reliable and valid measurement meth-ods in eliciting utility values in QALYs or disability values in DALYs, CEA needs to be addressed in a clear and transparent way to ensure its proper use in practice.

Key Words: Cost-effectiveness analysis, Quality-adjusted life years (QALYs), Disability-adjusted life years

(DALYs), Stroke

(2)

grams) are estimated and compared to show the tradeoffs involved in choosing among interventions. Health out-comes have long been evaluated by mortality-based indi-cators such as life expectancy, all-cause and disease-spe-cific mortality. However, these mortality-based rates are insufficient for evaluating disease burden, health out-comes, or the comparative impact of an intervention because the burden of chronic disease, injury, and dis-ability among survivors are unrecorded. Moreover, to assess relative worth in different health interventions across diverse diseases, a standard measurement is required.

Nowadays, the leading standard in Western countries is the use of health-adjusted life years (HALYs) in CEA of medical care and health interventions, as well as in estimating burden of disease. Theoretically, HALYs are summary measures of population health that merge esti-mates of life expectancy with measures of the quality of life with a disease. Being an umbrella term of a family of measures, HALYs include quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) and disability-adjusted life years (DALYs). Of note is that the particular type of CEA that uses QALYs or DALYs is sometimes referred to as cost-utility analy-sis (CUA)(1)

. Following some authors(2)

, we make no dis-tinction between CEA and its variant, CUA, throughout our discussion. We simply describe these analyses as CEA with QALYs or DALYs when they are used as the measure of effectiveness. Meanwhile, we use the terms ‘utility’, ‘value’, and ‘preference’ interchangeably, although in fact they are different(1).

The purpose of this article is to give a concise review on QALYs and DALYs, and to examine varia-tions in QALYs and DALYs estimates currently used in stroke studies.

THE CONCEPT OF QALYS

As a common metric for health, QALYs combine information regarding both length and quality of life. Every QALY is equivalent to one year of life in full health. For example, if major stroke is assumed to have a quality of life 0.4, then for a patient suffering a major stroke, each year spent in that state of health is

consid-ered to be 0.4 QALY, and 8 years lived after a major stroke would be counted as 3.2 (8Ű0.4) QALYs. Thus, the number of QALYs gained is the arithmetic product of the additional life expectancy gained owing to the health care intervention and the quality of these years.

In CEA, information regarding additional life expectancy gained after a disease, usually measured from clinical trials or epidemiological data, is relatively easy to obtain. Assessing the quality of that additional life, however, is more difficult. The preferences or utility values for different health states, also called quality-of-life (QoL) weights, have to be assessed with appropriate measurement instruments. Such instruments include, for example, standard gamble (SG), time trade-off (TTO), and direct rating (DR) methods (including category rat-ing and visual analogue scales)(1,2)

. These are the three most widely used methods to measure directly the pref-erences of individuals for health outcomes. An alterna-tive that is also widely applied is to use any of the multi-attribute health status classification systems such as Health Utilities Index (HUI), Quality of Well-Being (QWB), or the European Quality of Life Questionnaire (EuroQoL)(1)

.

In general, utility values range from 0 for death to 1 for perfect health. Negative utility values are possible for some health states. For example, some people may con-sider being in a permanent vegetative state less prefer-able than death, and thus the health state would be given a negative utility value.

QALYs were developed in the late 1960s, primarily for use in CEA. A CEA of chronic renal disease is among the earliest(3)

. After much deliberation, the US Public Health Service Panel on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine, as well as other consensus groups, concludes that a QALY measure is required for general-izable cost-effectiveness calculations(2)

. However, differ-ent elicitation methods (and perspectives of the evalua-tors) tend to yield different preferences or utility values from the same respondents for the same health states, and there is little consensus on which is to be preferred. Readers are referred to the literature(1,2,4,5)

for a more detailed discussion on QALY.

(3)

THE CONCEPT OF DALYS

DALYs were first introduced in the World Development Report (World Bank 1993) as a method for estimating the global burden of disease, and as an out-come measure for use in CEA(6,7)

. DALYs are the sum of the present value of years of lifetime lost through prema-ture mortality and the present value of years of lifetime adjusted for the average severity of disability (mental or physical) caused by a disease or injury. That is to say, DALYs are the sum of years of life lost (YLLs) and years of life lived with disability (YLDs). It is noted that DALYs are a measure of something ‘lost’ rather than ‘gained’.

With the DALY approach, each state of health is assigned a disability weighting factor on a scale from 0 (perfect health) to 1 (death) by an expert panel. Future burdens are discounted (usually at a rate of 3% per year), and years of life in childhood and old age are counted less. Specifically, the general equation for YLLs is as follows:

YLL =

where a is the age at death, L the remaining standard life

expectancy at death, r the discount rate, β the parameter for the age-weighting factor, K the age-weighting factor, and C a constant (0.1658).

The formula for YLD is basically the same except for that it is multiplied with a numeric disability weight

(D), and that a is the age of onset of disability and L is

the duration of disability: YLD =

Just like the increasing awareness that valuations for QALYs may differ when the QALYs accrue to different patients or are evaluated at different times, there are con-cerns about the ethics and validity of DALYs.

Particularly, the DALY framework not only is health-weighted, but also contains a weighting of life years that accentuates the dependency of the very young and the very old. This unique property of DALY has naturally caused some controversy. On the other hand, however, the assumption that all QALYs are of equal value no matter who gains them or when they occur during the life span is just equally controversial(2,8)

.

QUALITY OF LIFE AFTER STROKE

Although utility values are the key component of QALYs, given the nature of QALYs, it is not surprising to find that different studies report different utility values after stroke. In their comprehensive review of all QoL estimates for stroke appearing in the peer-reviewed liter-ature between 1985 and 2000, Tengs et al(9) found that QoL estimates range from -0.02 (indicating that major stroke is worse than death) to 0.71 for major stroke, from 0.12 to 0.81 for moderate stroke, from 0.45 to 0.92 for minor stroke, and from 0.29 to 0.903 for general stroke. Possible reasons for this variation include the aforemen-tioned different utility assessment methods, different types of respondents (patients, general population, or clinicians), and the defined bounds of the scale (1 corre-sponds to perfect health or merely the absence of stroke).

Post et al(10)

did a similar review published soon after the aforementioned one, and found that patients at risk for stroke assigned utilities of 0.26 and 0.55 to major (Rankin Scale 4 to 5) and minor (Rankin Scale 2 to 3) stroke, respectively. Stroke survivors assigned relatively higher utilities, 0.32 for major stroke and 0.71 for minor stroke.

Meta-analyses of QoL studies are rare in general. A meta-analysis of QoL estimated for stroke(11)

reported utility values of 0.87 for minor stroke, 0.68 for moderate stroke, and 0.52 for major stroke if the TTO method is used and respondents are community members when the scale bounds range from death to perfect health. Furthermore, the same study found that the utility values are sensitive to severity of stroke and the bounds of the scale, but not to the elicitation methods or who the respondents are.

(4)

Since the publication of the results of NINDS rtPA Stroke Trial in December 1995, a number of comprehen-sive CEA of rtPA therapy for acute ischemic stroke have been conducted(12-14)

. The utility values used in theses studies vary greatly(15)

. In a recent CEA of rtPA(16)

, a sur-vey using the EuroQoL with a random sample of 100 first-ever stroke patients alive 1 year after discharge found the mean utility values were 0.22 for disabled (Barthel Index <95) and 0.77 for autonomous (Barthel Index ≥95) patients. Among the more recent studies reporting utility values after stroke, O’Brien and Gage(17)

use 0.75, 0.39 and 0.12, respectively, as QoL estimates for mild residua, moderate to severe residua, and residua from recurrent stroke. Their utility estimates were based on a study(18)published almost 10 years ago. In the Duke

Stroke Policy Model (DSPM)(19)

, utility values, which were based on a large survey of patients at risk for major stroke, were 0.9 for TIA, and 0.8, 0.65, 0.5, 0.35 and 0.2 for Rankin Score 1 to 5, respectively. In a study on the cost-effectiveness of clopidogrel versus aspirin in sec-ondary prevention after vascular events(20)

, the utility value for peripheral arterial disease was 0.8, for mild stroke, 0.76, for moderate stroke, 0.39, and for severe stroke, 0.11. In a study of CEA of screening for obstruc-tive sleep apnea (OSA) in stroke patients(21)

, utility of stroke without OSA was 0.6 and stroke with untreated and treated OSA were 0.4 and 0.6, respectively, in their reference cases.

None of the above mentioned CEA of rtPA therapy applied the DALY approach. However, DALYs have been used in CEA across various conditions(22,23)

, includ-ing one that compared aspirin therapy with thrombolytic therapy in stroke care(24)

. Different disability weights for stroke have been used in different studies. In the 1990 Global Burden of Disease (GBD) study, disability weights for first-ever stroke with long-term disability is 0.224 for treated patients and 0.262 for untreated patients(25), so is in the GBD 2000 study. The main reason

not to estimate the disability weights according to level of severity in the GBD 1990 study is the lack of disabili-ty data from the vast majoridisabili-ty of the world regions. A Dutch study, however, provides some information: dis-ability weights for first-ever stroke with mild, moderate

and severe level of long-term disability are 0.36, 0.63 and 0.92, respectively(26)

.

DISCUSSION

Although noted to be of great importance in health care decision-making, less are known about the underly-ing “true” QoL weights of QALYs that reflect the desir-ability of living in some health state or set of outcomes. There are continuing debates over which method (to obtain the required preference weights) and whose pref-erences to use in QALY calculations(1,2)

. According to a review focusing on utility values elicited with the TTO method and from the patient’s perspective regarding own current health(24)

, CEA based on currently published TTO QoL weights should not be trusted as a tool for setting priorities among diagnostic groups. Worse still, studies have found that individual preferences may be inconsis-tent with the strict assumptions of expected utility theory that underline the QALY concept(1,2,27)

. For all the criti-cism of QALYs, no acceptable alternative has yet arisen(1,27)

.

Recently, scholars at the Harvard School of Public Health and Tufts-New England Medical Center devel-oped a comprehensive registry of CEA (http://www. tufts-nemc.org/cearegistry/) and updated the utility val-ues catalog to 2001(28)

. Given the lack of consensus in estimating QoL after stroke, any of the published QoL weights may be used in a CEA of stroke management. This naturally raises concerns about the meaningfulness in calculating the cost per QALY when considering pub-lic reimbursement of interventions or decision-making in health care resource allocation.

To our knowledge, very little is known about QoL after stroke patients in Taiwan. Data reported in other countries may not be fully applicable to Taiwan because of cultural differences. Furthermore, stroke patients with moderate to severe cognitive impairments and those who exhibit communication difficulties may not be able to respond to various methods for measuring preferences. Meanwhile, although using measures of functional inde-pendence status (such as the Barthel Index) to estimate the patient’s QoL has been considered(29)

(5)

degree of heterogeneity in QoL was reported among patients with similar levels of functional status after stroke(30).

In conclusion, regardless of the competing views on economic foundations of CEA(31)

, a comprehensive and valid economic evaluation of any stroke management requires valid QoL measurements. The need for improved outcome measures for stroke, including QoL measures, is becoming increasingly important in view of the recent development of thrombolytic and neuroprotec-tive therapies. Nevertheless, studies of CEA in general, and the CEA of stroke treatment in particular, are still limited in Taiwan. As CEA becomes more essential to health care policy, we need to understand the strengths and limitations of such analyses. Given the lack of reli-able and valid measurement methods in eliciting utility values in QALYs or disability values in DALYs, CEA needs to be addressed in a clear and transparent way to ensure its proper use in practice.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This study was partially supported by a grant from the National Science Council (NSC94-2416-H-110-024), Taiwan.

REFERENCES

1. Drummond MF, O’Brien B, Stoddart GL, et al. Methods for the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programmes, 3rd ed. NY: Oxford University Press, 2005.

2. Gold MR, Siegel JE, Russel LB, et al, eds. Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine. NY: Oxford University Press, 1996.

3. Klarman HE, Francis JO, Rosenthal GD. Cost-effectiveness analysis applied to the treatment of chronic renal disease. Med Care 1968;6:48-54.

4. Gold MR, Stevenson D, Fryback DG. HALYS and QALYS and DALYS, Oh My: similarities and differences in sum-mary measures of population health. Annu Rev Public Health 2002;23:115-34.

5. Neumann PJ, Goldie SJ, Weinstein MC. Preference-based measures in economic evaluation in health care. Annu Rev

Public Health 2000;21:587-611.

6. Murray CJ, Acharya AK. Understanding DALYs. J Health Econ 1997;16:703-30.

7. Fox-Rushby JA, Hanson K. Calculating and presenting dis-ability adjusted life years (DALYs) in cost-effectiveness analysis. Health Policy Plan 2001;16:326-31.

8. Tsuchiya A. QALYs and ageism: philosophical theories and age weighting. Health Econ 2000;9:57-68.

9. Tengs TO, Yu M, Luistro E. Health-related quality of life after stroke a comprehensive review. Stroke 2001;32:964-72.

10. Post PN, Stiggelbout AM, Wakker PP. The utility of health states after stroke: a systematic review of the literature. Stroke 2001;32:1425-9.

11. Tengs TO, Lin TH. A meta-analysis of quality-of-life esti-mates for stroke. Pharmacoeconomics 2003;21:191-200. 12. Sandercock P, Berge E, Dennis M, et al. Cost-effectiveness

of thrombolysis with recombinant tissue plasminogen acti-vator for acute ischemic stroke assessed by a model based on UK NHS costs. Stroke 2004;35:1490-7.

13. Sinclair SE, Frighetto L, Loewen PS, et al. Cost-Utility analysis of tissue plasminogen activator therapy for acute ischaemic stroke: a Canadian healthcare perspective. Pharmacoeconomics 2001;19:927-36.

14. Fagan SC, Morgenstern LB, Petitta A, et al. Cost-effective-ness of tissue plasminogen activator for acute ischemic stroke. NINDS rt-PA Stroke Study Group. Neurology 1998; 50:883-90.

15. Tseng MC, Chang KC. Cost-effectiveness analysis of tissue plasminogen activator for acute ischemic stroke: a compar-ative review. Acta Neurol Taiwan 2004;13:149-55.

16. Mar J, Begiristain JM, Arrazola A. Cost-effectiveness analysis of thrombolytic treatment for stroke. Cerebrovasc Dis 2005;20:193-200.

17. O’Brien CL, Gage BF. Costs and effectiveness of ximela-gatran for stroke prophylaxis in chronic atrial fibrillation. JAMA 2005;293:699-706.

18. Gage BF, Cardinalli AB, Owens DK. The effect of stroke and stroke prophylaxis with aspirin or warfarin on quality of life. Arch Intern Med 1996;156:1829-36.

19. Matchar DB, Samsa GP, Liu S. Cost-effectiveness of antiplatelet agents in secondary stroke prevention: the lim-its of certainty. Value Health 2005;8:572-80.

(6)

20. Schleinitz MD, Weiss JP, Owens DK. Clopidogrel versus aspirin for secondary prophylaxis of vascular events: a cost-effectiveness analysis. Am J Med 2004;116:797-806. 21. Brown DL, Chervin RD, Hickenbottom SL, et al. Screening

for obstructive sleep apnea in stroke patients: a cost-effec-tiveness analysis. Stroke 2005;36:1291-3.

22. Creese A, Floyd K, Alban A, et al. Cost-effectiveness of HIV/AIDS interventions in Africa: a systematic review of the evidence. Lancet 2002;359:1635-43.

23. Muennig P, Pallin D, Sell RL, et al. The cost effectiveness of strategies for the treatment of intestinal parasites in immigrants. N Engl J Med 1999;340:773-9.

24. Moodie ML, Carter R, Mihalopoulos C, et al. Trial applica-tion of a Model of Resource Utilizaapplica-tion, Costs, and Outcomes for Stroke (MORUCOS) to assist priority setting in stroke. Stroke 2004;35:1041-6.

25. Truelsen T, Begg S, Mathers C, et al. The global burden of cerebrovascular disease in the year 2000. WHO, 2002. 26. Arnesen T, Trommald M. Roughly right or precisely

wrong? Systematic review of quality-of-life weights elicit-ed with the time trade-off. J Health Serv Res and Policy 2004;9:43-50.

27. Brauer CA, Neumann PJ. Quality-adjusted life years: how useful in medico economic studies. Fundam Clin Pharmacol 2005;19:603-7.

28. Brauer CA, Rosen AB, Greenberg D, et al. Trends in the measurement of health utilities in published cost-utility analyses. Value Health 2006;9:213-8.

29. van Exel NJ, Scholte op Reimer WJ, Koopmanschap MA. Assessment of post-stroke quality of life in cost-effective-ness studies: the usefulcost-effective-ness of the Barthel Index and the EuroQoL-5D. Qual Life Res 2004;13:427-33.

30. Samsa GP, Matchar DB. How strong is the relationship between functional status and quality of life among persons with stroke? J Rehabil Res Dev 2004;41:279-82.

31. Brouwer WB, Koopmanschap MA. On the economic foun-dations of CEA. Ladies and gentlemen, take your positions! J Health Econ 2000;19:439-59.

參考文獻

相關文件

MR CLEAN: A Randomized Trial of Intra-arterial Treatment for Acute Ischemic Stroke. • Multicenter Randomized Clinical trial of Endovascular treatment for Acute ischemic stroke in

Transfer of training: A review and directions for future research. (1992).“Formal and

We do it by reducing the first order system to a vectorial Schr¨ odinger type equation containing conductivity coefficient in matrix potential coefficient as in [3], [13] and use

An additional senior teacher post, to be offset by a post in the rank of CM or Assistant Primary School Master/Mistress (APSM) as appropriate, is provided to each primary

Incorporated Management Committees should comply with the terms in this Code of Aid and abide by such requirements as promulgated in circulars and instructions issued by the

An additional senior teacher post, to be offset by a post in the rank of APSM, is provided to each primary special school/special school with primary section that operates six or

220V 50 Hz single phase A.C., variable stroke control, electrical components and cabling conformed to the latest B.S.S., earthing through 3 core supply cable.. and 2,300 r.p.m.,

Comparison of B2 auto with B2 150 x B1 100 constrains signal frequency dependence, independent of foreground projections If dust, expect little cross-correlation. If