• 沒有找到結果。

The Mystery of Wealth and the Role of Divinities: The Economy in Pre-Modern Japanese Fiction and Practice

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "The Mystery of Wealth and the Role of Divinities: The Economy in Pre-Modern Japanese Fiction and Practice"

Copied!
39
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

163 Hualin International Journal of Buddhist Studies, 2.2 (2019): 163–201

FABIO RAMBELLI

University of California, Santa Barbara rambelli@eastasian.ucsb.edu

Keywords: Buddhist economics, Buddhist literature, merit-making, general economy, Buddhist and Shinto relations, Buddhist temple economic activities

DOI: https://dx.doi.org/10.15239/hijbs.02.02.06

Abstract: This article presents an overview of the economic dimen- sions of premodern Japanese Buddhism—both economic ideas and activities—by focusing on representative primary sources and im- portant secondary scholarship. It opens with a discussion of econom- ic activities in which temple-shrines and their personnel were directly engaged in. Next, in order to find some type of theorization for those practices, it examines a number of popular stories from medieval and early modern Japan (some of which are still circulating today as children’s tales) that deal with the origin of wealth. It problematizes their underlying economic thought, including examples of resistance to dominant ideas about production and wealth. Finally, the paper offers some considerations on the ‘general economy’ of premodern Japanese Buddhism.

The Mystery of Wealth and the

Role of Divinities: The Economy in

Pre-Modern Japanese Fiction and

Practice

(2)

B

uddhist institutions were important economic hubs in medieval and early modern Japan, as in other Buddhist countries. Still, it is somewhat surprising that normative canonical texts do not offer any specific teachings about the economy beyond superficial consider- ations about generosity, merit-making, and karmic retribution. One must look instead at specific economic practices and texts elucidating them (narratives, legal documents, etc.)—materials that were part of the ‘practical canon’ of Buddhism. There we see that at least some segments of premodern Japanese society tried to explain the origin of wealth in terms of the conceptual apparatus provided by Japanese vernacular Buddhist doctrines about local deities (kami). Agricultur- al production, financial interests, commercial profit, even gambling:

all these activities involved the production of something out of noth- ing. This was explained in terms of the intervention of buddhas and kami in the economic processes; divinities were thus at the center of productive and commercial activities.

This article presents an overview of the economic dimensions of premodern Japanese Buddhism—in terms of both economic ideas and activities—by focusing on representative primary sources and important secondary scholarship. It opens with a discussion of eco- nomic activities in which temple-shrines and their personnel were directly engaged in. Next, in order to find some type of theorization for those practices, it examines a number of popular stories from medieval and early modern Japan (some of which are still circulating today as children’s tales) that deal with the origin of wealth. It prob- lematizes their underlying economic thought, including examples of resistance to dominant ideas about production and wealth. Finally, the paper offers some considerations on the ‘general economy’ of premodern Japanese Buddhism.1

1 Because of its nature as a preliminary outline of issues that are overall little understood, some readers might find this article oversimplified and underdocu- mented. It is indeed a summary of research I have conducted over many years, and space prevents me from providing more extensive background and referenc- es. Nevertheless, I hope that this general picture of Japanese Buddhist econom- ics, however simplified, will stimulate further investigations.

(3)

Buddhist Economic Practices

One of the best descriptions of the economic impact of Buddhism in any society is still Jacques Gernet’s classic book on Buddhism in medieval China, originally published in 1956, entitled Buddhism in Chinese Society. Gernet strongly criticizes Buddhism for being both an economic burden on the masses and a capitalistic enterprise. He talks about the ‘cost of Buddhism to China’, such as ‘the appalling misery for the peasant class’2 that Buddhism created; ‘the imbalance between production and consumption caused by the Buddhist movement’ and the ‘fiscal problems caused by Buddhism’.3 In his treatment, Gernet takes at face value the positions expressed by Chi- nese medieval anti-Buddhist state officials (and, perhaps, also those of contemporary Maoism) and reiterates their arguments.

In short, Buddhism is presented as a burden for the state because it reduced manpower (monks were unproductive) and tax revenue (monasteries were tax-exempt), thus causing a huge depletion of state wealth (as resources were deflected into Buddhist-related unproduc- tive expenditures). In this way, Buddhism was a harm to the state and the peasants. It is worth noting here that these old Confucian arguments were rehashed in Korea first and later in Japan during the Edo period by anti-Buddhist authors and groups, and contributed to various anti-Buddhist policies from the mid-1600s culminating in the Meiji persecutions (1868–1871).4

Still, Gernet also tells us a different story, albeit in a fragmentary and almost surreptitious way. Aside from the fact that state officials and their families were engaged in huge and useless expenses for themselves (‘embroidered garments’, ‘kitchen stoves’, ‘makeup’5), we get the sense that Buddhist institutions were also important eco- nomic hubs. They hired a significant amount of labor, both skilled and unskilled; purchased a vast array of different materials, goods,

2 Gernet, Buddhism in Chinese Society, 14.

3 Gernet, 30.

4 See Ketelaar, Of Heretics and Martyrs.

5 Gernet, Buddhism in Chinese Society, 36.

(4)

and services (materials and goods which had to be produced for and delivered to the temples, thus involving other professional services);6 and reclaimed and developed non-cultivated lands;7 Buddhist temples were even involved in supporting the state’s colonization endeavors.8 In addition, temples were ‘industrial installations’ (they operated mills, presses, etc.);9 commercial and financial centers: ‘craft and commerce for the supply of devotional objects in the vicinity of monasteries’;10 ‘the great monasteries too had shops in the mar- ketplaces […]. These served, it seems, at once as inns for travelers, as shops, and as pawnshops.’11 Even though Gernet refers to financial activities with the derogatory word ‘usury’, no other agencies at the time gave any amount of loans to all kinds of people; if nothing else, loans could be an incentive for entrepreneurship that no state agency would support.

Gernet also does not say that the peasants would have been taxed anyway, and the resources extracted from them would have gone, not to temples—and through them, at least in part, back to their communities—but to the imperial bureaucracy and the military. He also does not emphasize enough that temples did provide services for the population that the state was unable or unwilling to provide:

among other things, education, health, technological innovation, and economic support. His focus on the ‘cost’ of religious institutions ignores that these ‘costs’ involved attracting workers and trades in the areas around the temples, wages being paid to workers and profes- sionals, and a general diffusion of economic benefits in those areas.

The picture described by Gernet does not seem to have been unique to China. In medieval and early modern Japan, temples were also hubs of innovative economic activities. They served as catalysts for marketplaces, centers of professional guilds, places for entertain-

6 For a detailed example, see Gernet, Buddhism in Chinese Society, 18–19.

7 Gernet, 119.

8 Gernet, 98–100.

9 Gernet, 142.

10 Gernet, 167.

11 Gernet, 168.

(5)

ment and performing arts, entrepreneurial agencies involved in land reclamation and agricultural development, technological and indus- trial innovation, financial activities, trade (including foreign trade until the early seventeenth century). This is true even in the Edo period, a time generally considered as one of decline for Buddhism.

Indeed, it is well possible that images of decline and degeneration of Buddhism were artfully spread by authors and groups who were keenly aware of the wealth and economic power of Buddhist institu- tions and had a direct or indirect interest in appropriating them.12

Contrary to received assumptions, Buddhism has never been a world-denying religion, unconcerned with, or clearly inimical to, eco- nomic activities. On the contrary, Buddhist practice has always been predicated upon a decent living, as is clear in the case of merit-mak- ing, with its goal of improving material life in the present as a way to gain security, peace of mind, and therefore the leisure to engage in Buddhist practice.

Despite the massive economic presence of Buddhist institutions and their entrepreneurial role, the scarcity of theoretical discourses about the economy and economics in canonical literature is as- tonishing. Wealthy patrons of the Buddha and his Samgha such as Vimalakirti are extolled for their generosity, but the source of their wealth is never explained in detail. An account of the origin of social and economic differences is included in the Aggañña suttanta and other later sources; this is uncannily Marxian in its description of the process that led to the formation of private property, primitive accu- mulation, and labor division and class/caste distinction. It is however

12 It should perhaps be mentioned, in this context, that Buddhist institutions in Southeast Asia (Sri Lanka, Burma, Thailand, etc.) seem to have been much less entrepreneurial than their East Asian counterparts. As Steven Collins has shown, Sri Lankan Theravada social ideology was rooted in, and promoted, a land-based subsistence economy and its social relations—an economy of stasis and poverty that resisted innovation and change (see Collins, Nirvana and Other Buddhist Felicities). It is perhaps no accident that the most lucrative economic activities in Southeast Asian Buddhist countries were taken over by foreigners—Muslims, Europeans, and Chinese.

(6)

doubtful that this sutra had any direct impact on Buddhist social practices at large; perhaps, it pointed to a need to curb what it sees as socially degenerate practices through the establishment of alternative social and political systems for the Sangha.13

The lack of canonical sources on economic matters should not be interpreted as an indication that the latter were not important for monastic communities or temple organizations; rather, it suggests that much of Buddhist economic knowledge was developed in other sources and contexts, what we could call ‘practical canon’—a set of teachings, instructions, and rules about practical, everyday matters, that were not addressed in canonical sources.14

It is thus necessary to examine actual economic practices at tem- ples and the documents that described them for clues regarding the principles behind them. Economic issues became a primary concern for Buddhist institutions in Japan from the tenth century when, as a consequence of social and political transformations, the central- ized state modeled on the Chinese empire began to collapse; tem- ples lost state support and needed to secure new forms of income in order to survive. Over a span of four hundred years, they focused on four main areas: real estate, with the acquisition of land-holdings and their revenues, finance (donations of various nature, invest- ments, levies, and so forth), technology (the creation and control of professional guilds, engineering and infrastructures, transporta- tion); and trade (with some temples hosting regular market places and in some cases even financing risky but lucrative international trade with China). They also needed to come up with marketing strategies and campaigns to promote themselves in competitions with other sacred sites; for that purpose, they relied on a vast array of itinerant religious specialists (hijiri , yamabushi 山伏, jinin , oshi お師, etc.), who spread teachings and information about temples and shrines and promoted pilgrimages and donations in in- creasingly large areas of Japan. Some of these specialists (particularly the jinin, affiliated with the large temple-shrine complexes of Nara

13 See Rambelli, ‘The Vicissitudes of the Mahāsammata in East Asia’.

14 I owe this notion to Adam Krug.

(7)

and Kyoto, and the yamabushi) were also in charge of collecting tithes and fees.

Finally, we must emphasize a crucial point: Buddhist institutions relied heavily on their ‘Shinto’ components for both theoretical aspects and practical dimensions of their economic activities; this aspect deserves some background explanation. Between the twelfth and sixteenth centuries, the period primarily discussed in this paper, what are now Shinto shrines were either full-fledged Buddhist tem- ples (dedicated to deities such as Hachiman 八幡, Tenman Tenjin 満天神, Konpira 金毘羅, etc.) or parts of large institutions dominated by Buddhist temples, and a significant number of monastics and other religious personnel were in charge of kami matters (theoretical discourses, rituals, administration, proselytism, etc.).15 It was natural for such institutions to develop discourses about the economy cen- tered on traditional, local practices and beliefs.

Sacred Properties (butsumotsu 仏物, shinmotsu 神物) and the Origin of Wealth

From around the eleventh century, religious institutions began to deal with the lack of public funding by accumulating land estates.

By the late Kamakura period (later thirteenth century), a new legal principle had gained wide recognition, according to which land do- nated to buddhas and kami cannot be returned to human ownership (butsuda senyū no chi kuikaesubekarazu 仏陀施入ノ地不可悔返).16 This principle was originally stressed by religious institutions, but later even donors recognized it explicitly.17

Religious institutions levied tributes from their estates—mostly rice, but depending on the area, also other products (salt, silk, cotton, metal, dried fish, and so forth). A portion of those tributes, known

15 For a general overview of premodern Japanese assimilation between Bud- dhism and Shinto, see Teeuwen and Rambelli, eds., Buddhas and Kami in Japan.

16 Kasamatsu, ‘Butsuda senyū no chi kuikaeshibekarazu’.

17 Amino, Muen, kugai, raku, 213.

(8)

as hatsuho 初穂 (‘first produce’) or jōbun 上分 (‘superior portion’), was offered directly to the main deity of the temple or shrine as a sign of gratitude for the harvest. This practice was probably connected to ancient customs of the Japanese archipelago. The first produce was offered to the gods (kami) and their emissaries—the local leaders—to thank them for their generosity and to secure their benevolence in the future. Particularly important in this respect were the nie , first produces (rice and delicacies from the mountains and the sea) offered to the emperor since ancient times.18 First produces offered to the kami were stored in sacred storehouses managed by the leaders of the community or by special personnel (the kugonin 供御人) at the imperial household. The following year, those rice grains were loaned to the peasants for sowing (tanemomi 種籾); after the harvest, the peasants would return the amount of grains they had borrowed with a fee—an additional offering to the kami as a sign of gratitude in the form of first produces.19 In this way, the kami were envisioned as the source of rice—and therefore, life and wealth—in a cyclical move- ment requiring human offerings to ensure a bountiful harvest and sustain life.20 This cycle is the origin of the practice of lending grains known as suiko 出挙. Under the Ritsuryō 律令 legal system (early 700s–late 900s), suiko was mostly controlled by the state (kusuiko 出挙 or public suiko), and provincial governors were the responsible for the loan of seeds preserved in public storehouses; however, there were also private rice-lenders (shisuiko 私出挙).21

Around the early eleventh century, when the state was no longer able to enforce public suiko lending, influential religious institutions such as the Grand Shrines of Ise, Hie shrine, and Kumano took con- trol over this ancient custom related to offering hatsuho to the kami,

18 According to historian Ishimoda Shō 石母田正 (1912–1986), the first pro- duce (hatsuho), especially rice (tanemomi 種籾) had a ritual and sacred nature, and were offered to the local deities and the clan leaders (Ishimoda, Nihon no kodai kokka, 359–61).

19 See Oda, ‘Kodai-chūsei no suiko’.

20 Nakazawa, Akutōteki shikō, 23.

21 Amino, Nihon chūsei ni nani ga okita ka, 55–58.

(9)

and gave it new meaning and social relevance. The rice they received as ‘superior portion’ of the harvest (jōbun), as the ‘first produces’

began to be called, were considered inalienable sacred properties belonging to kami and buddhas (respectively, shinmotsu 神物 and butsumotsu 仏物) of the temple or shrine owning the land.22 The

‘superior portion’ was then loaned at an interest (kashiage 貸上) to farmers for sowing also outside of their own estates by specialists affiliated with Kumano (yamabushi), Hie (jinin), and Ise (oshi).

Gradually, their activities extended from the Hokuriku region in north-central Japan to Kyushu; in contrast, their activities in Kantō and beyond in eastern Japan are recorded only from the Muromachi period (the reason for this regional discrepancy is not clear). After harvesting, the peasants would return to the temple or shrine, as part of the community’s annual tributes (nengu 年貢), the amount of rice they had received the previous year plus interests ranging from fifty percent to one hundred percent.

In this way, financial activity took the form of a loan of properties belonging to the buddhas and the kami which, after completion of the agricultural cycle, were returned to the divinities with an additional offering as a token of gratitude (what functioned in fact as interests). In this way, tributes and loan interests were considered as merit-making offerings to the buddhas and the temples. At this stage, the cycle connecting production, sacred offerings, and lending already existed at the intersection of several symbolic layers: ancient local practices related to production and offerings, centralized state taxation, Buddhist appropriation in terms of merit-making; this was carried out in practice by personnel affiliated to ‘Shinto’ components of large institutions.

Gradually, the concepts of ‘first produce’ and ‘superior portion’

was extended to other forms of taxation, such as levies and fees on the commodities transported by merchants when passing through toll posts controlled by religious institutions. Religious interests in the form of ‘superior portions’ were collected not only in rice, but also in salt (jōbun’en 上分塩), silk, fish, and other products. From

22 Kasamatsu, ‘Butsumotsu, sōmotsu, ninmotsu’.

(10)

the Kamakura period onward, marketplace fees and transit fees (kanshoryō 関所料), which religious institutions charged to itinerant merchants, were also understood as a kind of ‘first produce’ (hatsuho) of trade.23 Medieval historian Amino Yoshihiko 網野善彦 argued that such fees developed from offerings made to the deities when travelers crossed sacred thresholds, such as mountain passes, borders, wades, ports, and so forth, or even when traveling by sea (in ancient folklore the sea was often described as closely related to the other world).24 According to Amino, this could explain why the responsibility for collecting such fees fell on religious specialists such as kanjin shōnin

勧進上人, hijiri and jinin in general. In addition, we should also note that money loaned by Zen and Ristu temples, known as shidō maisen 祠堂米銭, was granted a special legal and economic status in medieval Japan as ‘properties of the Buddha’ (butsumotsu).25 Sacred loans (suiko) represented the basis of the way in which medieval Japa- nese society symbolized financial activity.

Amino Yoshihiko further suggested that places where economic and financial transactions occurred, variously called muenjo 無縁 (places severed from secular ties) and kugaidera 公界寺 (open temples), were considered separate from the secular world and had sacred features. Markets were located in places that were symbolically envisioned as the margins of the ordinary world: riverbanks, beaches, areas between mountains and plains, sites where a rainbow suppos-

23 In 1535 the Ōyamazaki 大山崎 jinin affiliated with Iwashimizu Hachi- mangū 岩清水八幡宮 shrine-temple called the toll (niwazeni 庭銭) they charged

‘first produce of oil business’ (abura shōbai no hatsuwo 油商売ノ初穂). In addi- tion, several other medieval documents mention ‘superior portions’ (jōbun) re- lated to fish and birds, cloths, sake. In addition, transit fees charged by Nachi in Kumano to sailors and boats were also called jōbun, as well as port fees charged by Mt. Hiko in Kyushu. See Amino, Muen, kugai, raku, 363–64.

24 On the religious role of the sea in Japan, see Rambelli, ‘Sea Theologies: Ele- ments for a Conceptualization of Maritime Religiosity in Japan’.

25 So-called ‘pure money’ (jōzen 浄銭) offered to the buddhas at temples was used for loans (shidōsen) at an interest of one hundred percent a year; see Iwai, Shihonshugi wo kataru, 248–49.

(11)

edly originated—all envisioned as thresholds between this world and the invisible world of kami and buddhas.26 According to legal historian Katsumata Shizuo 勝俣鎮夫, it was only in such places that things could acquire the status of commodities and be exchanged or sold for profit. Katsumata argues that markets were places where things were separated from their worldly ties; the seller would give them temporarily to the deities, who in turn would give them to the buyer; in this way, the deities were the center of trade interactions. At the marketplace, then, objects exchanged ceased to be part of a gift economy and became commodities, thus giving birth to commerce.27 This would also explain why marketplace fees, charged by supervisors affiliated with religious institutions, were sometimes considered ‘first produce’—offerings for the divinities as signs of gratitude. Not only were value and surplus produced by the deities, but their production also occurred in specific places that were considered sacred. In this way, the relation between religion and economy became even stron- ger. The language of agricultural production was thus used, at least initially, to explain the production of surplus value in trade. Howev- er, the origin of wealth in trade could not be fully explained based on agriculture, which was normally conceptualized as a static source of an unchangeable amount of production. As we shall see below, many medieval tales describe the sudden origin of wealth as due to the intervention of some divinity after the protagonist’s visit to a mar- ketplace, a temple/shrine, or along the road (which was considered at the time a no-man’s land and thus a potential site for supernatural encounters).

Fiction, Wealth, and the Sacred

At least some segments of medieval Japanese society tried to explain (or construct) the ‘mystery’ of the production of wealth in terms of the conceptual apparatus provided by religious institutions and their

26 See Amino, Muen, kugai, raku.

27 Katsumata, ‘Baibai, shichiire to shoyū kannen’.

(12)

doctrines. Agricultural production, financial interests, commercial profit, even gambling: all these activities involved proliferation, that is, the generation of something from nothing.28 This was explained in terms of the intervention of buddhas and kami in the economic processes. The divinities were at the center of all productive and commercial activities: they generated the crops, and to them the first produce was returned; they generated interests, and they enabled objects to be exchanged for profit; they even controlled the fortune of gamblers. In other words, the intellectual framework of medieval Japanese economy maintained that buddhas and kami bring wealth to this world by intervening directly in the generation of surplus (added value), in agriculture and in any other commercial and man- ufacturing activities. Part of the surplus they generated was supposed to be returned to them in order to keep the cycle of general economy functioning. In the realm of economics, as well as in the realm of religion, small investments (rice grains) could yield enormous profits when controlled by the deities.

Wealth is described in medieval Japan as the result of the inter- action with the Invisible World of gods and spirits—as retribution from some deity for good actions and moral behavior. According to the same logic, the deities would punish immoral behavior with poverty; immoral people would either remain poor or lose their wealth. Wealth was also understood as ‘worldly benefits’ (genze riyaku 現世利益) in general: long life to the emperor, peace in the realm, regular seasons, bountiful harvests—in other words, political and social order, economic welfare, and good health.

An effective way to understand the status and features of wealth in the medieval Japanese imaginary more in depth is through an analysis of narratives such as setsuwa 説話, otogizōshi 御伽草子, and painted scrolls (emakimono 絵巻物), which were composed by intellectuals and priests and were widely used in sermons and performances of

28 In medieval Europe too, the generation of wealth out of nothing was a major subject of wonder and religious discussion. Particularly interesting in this respect is the way in which the Church defined and treated usury; see Le Goff, Your Money of Your Life.

(13)

a religious nature. The interest of these sources lies in their broad appeal and diffusion, and in the fact that they were produced and circulated for many centuries, thus describing a rather constant epis- teme; changes in the understanding of economic practices began to emerge in the Tokugawa period, as we will discuss below.

Stories about wealth as karmic retribution for good deeds already appear in the very first collection of Buddhist narratives composed in Japan, the Nihon ryōiki 日本霊異記 (early ninth century); those narratives follow closely textual precedents from China and India, in turn based on Indian Mahayana literature, in which good deeds generate good karmic seeds and are rewarded with material benefits in this life and spiritual blessings in the next.29 However, medieval stories expand the range of divinities involved in wealth bestowal and importantly shift their focus on local kami and hybrid Buddho-Shin- to gods. This shift had momentous consequences, because it marked the adoption by Buddhist institutions of originally non-Buddhist entities in the definition of economic activities, also as a way to con- trol and theorize secular practices as part of a general economy of the sacred (see the Concluding Remarks).

A well-known story is presented in the Shigisan engi 信貴山縁起, a painted scroll (emakimono) with texts composed in the thirteenth century, which describes three adventures of the priest Myōren 妙蓮

on Mt. Shigi 信貴山—the location of the Chōgosonshiji 朝護孫子 temple—in Kawachi province near present-day Osaka. The first scroll is particularly relevant for our discussion here. The emaki is without text, but the narrative content of the images can be recon- structed from stories appearing, among other sources, in the Uji shūi monogatari 宇治拾遺物語 (early thirteenth century).30 Here I refer to this version, a story entitled ‘Shinano no kuni no hijiri no koto’ 濃国ノ聖ノ事 (About a hijiri from the Shinano province).31 Myōren, a priest from Shinano (present-day Nagano prefecture in central Japan), after his ordination at the Tōdaiji 東大寺 in Nara, began to

29 See Nakamura, Miraculous Stories from the Buddhist Tradition.

30 Among the latter, see Shigisan engi.

31 In Uji shūi monogatari, Kohon setsuwa-shū, 196–202.

(14)

practice austerities and worship Bishamonten 毘沙門天 on Mt. Shigi.

Every day, the priest sent his bowl flying to the house of a wealthy villager of humble origins to collect alms.32 One day, the family of the wealthy villager did not give alms as usual; instead, they threw the bowl in the storehouse (kura ) and locked it inside. Then, the storehouse came flying to Mt. Shigi near where Myōren was praying.

The wealthy villager went to the mountain to ask for the restitution of his wealth. The priest kept the building and some rice from it, and returned the rest by using again his magic bowl.

A later version, the tale ‘Shigisan’ in the collection Shōyoshō 聖誉 (1547), adds the story of how the rich villager initially acquired his wealth and ends with its complete loss. The ‘wealthy Yamazaki’

(Yamazaki chōja 山崎長者), as this figure is called in this story, was a person of humble origin who succeeded in becoming rich thanks to the intervention of the Buddhist divinity Bishamonten (Sk. Vaiśrava- na), which in medieval Japan was often envisioned as a protector of economic success. Yamazaki began by accumulating religious virtue (toku ) by putting alms into the flying bowl belonging to the priest Myōren of Mt. Shigi; in retribution, Bishamonten intervened and gave him wealth. Here, the unstated implication was that Yamazaki, in order to preserve his newly acquired wealth, should have contin- ued to give alms; the day he stopped, the magic bowl would take away his entire wealth (the storehouse). In other words, wealth is never eternal and stable, in line with the Buddhist worldview based on impermanence.

32 This story is not completely preposterous. The Shugendō 修験道 tradition has a ritual that is supposed to make a bowl fly (hihachi-hō 飛鉢法), in order to bring alms to a practitioner. This ritual has a scriptural basis in the Nyoi hōju tenrin himitsu genshin jōbutsu konrin juō kyō (chapter ‘Hōhatsu-bon’) This sutra is a typical Tantric text, describing esoteric rituals enabling the practitioner to control agents of the invisible world, in particular the dragon kings, in order to acquire worldly benefits (‘wealth’ broadly understood) and Buddhahood in the present life. This story also suggests that yamabushi may have been involved in the production and circulation of this type of narratives about the cycle of reli- gious giving and secular wealth.

(15)

Indeed, many years later, Yamazaki’s descendants, tired of giving alms every day to the priest, gave him black rice and fish as a sign of contempt. The priest threw away this food and washed his bowl in a river. As a consequence, the storehouse of Yamazaki’s descendants flew away to Mt. Shigi; the chōja’s family lost everything and became poor again. A similar story, included in the Kohon setsuwashū 古本説 話集 (early twelfth century), describes what happened to the wealthy Indian Ruci, who lost everything when he insulted the gods.33 In the story of Yamazaki, the affront was made directly to the monk Myōren, but that amounted to an insult to Bishamonten as well.

According to these stories, the accumulation and preservation of wealth require a continuous and incessant effort on the part of the wealthy—not only the individuals (chōja) but also, and crucially, their families. As a sort of contract between one family and a deity, it should never be violated—the penalty being the complete loss of wealth and return to poverty.

However, the question remains as to how wealth is actually ac- cumulated in the first place. Other stories tell us that, first of all, it is necessary to free the house from the ‘gods of poverty’ (binbōgami

貧乏神) and let the gods of good fortune (fuku no kami 福の神) in; only then can the protagonist begin to accumulate wealth. An example of this way of thinking is the otogizōshi ‘Umezu no chōja monogatari’ 梅津の長者の物語 (The Story of the rich man from Umezu), written between the end of the Muromachi and the begin- ning of the Edo periods (late sixteenth–early seventeenth centuries).

Sakon-no-jō Tominaga and his wife, who live in the village of Umezu, are very poor but honest and generous. They have deep faith in the god of wealth Ebisu Saburō 夷三郎 and pray that he free them from the ‘gods of poverty’ and give them wealth. One day Tominaga meets a nun who was lost on the road, and kindly directs her in the right direction. The nun gives him ten coins (sen

). Taking it as a gift from Ebisu, he gives the coins to his wife and tells her to buy rice cakes (mochi ) to celebrate. On her way home from the market, the wife meets an old man (okina ); moved by

33 Kohon setsuwashū, vol. 2: 96–103.

(16)

compassion by the destitute and hungry old man, she gives him the rice cakes she had bought. The old man tells her: ‘I will repay you soon’ and leaves. That night, the husband and wife have a revelatory dream. The old man appears to them in his real form as the god Ebisu Saburō in person and tells them that he is going to give them wealth. First, however, he must rid their house of the gods of pover- ty that plague it. The story continues describing the battle between Ebisu and his allies (Inari 稲荷, Bishamonten, and their retinue) and the gods of poverty. At the end of a victorious battle, Ebisu tells husband and wife that, as a retribution for their honesty and faith, he will protect them. All together they held a banquet, attended also by the other gods of fortune (Daikokuten 大黒天, Jurōjin 寿老 , Fukurokuju 福禄寿, Hotei 布袋). The good deities later defeat a band of robbers who try to assault the new rich couple. Eventually, the two protagonists become servants of an aristocratic family.

In other cases, the divinities can decide to give wealth to someone just as retribution for a simple act of kindness, without the need to engage in battles with other divine entities. A variant of the previous story, diffused all over Japan, involves the bodhisattva Jizō 地蔵. On New Year’s Eve, a poor old couple goes to the market to sell straw hats (kasa ); it is a cold winter day, and it is snowing. Unfortunate- ly, they are not able to sell anything, and go back home without even the money to buy mochi (rice cakes) to celebrate the end of the year.

Along the way, the couple sees a set of six statues of Jizō. They think that the Jizō might be cold in that weather and decide to put the hats on the heads of the statues. Later, Jizō appears to the couple in their house and gives them pieces of gold as retribution for their kindness.

In this case, the old couple did not really give up on anything in favor of Jizō, as they had made the hats to sell them at the market so that they could buy mochi to celebrate the New Year; at the end of the market day, the hats remain unsold and are therefore without any immediate value. Still, their kindness and solicitude toward Jizō’s statues trigger the bodhisattva’s intervention.

As we can see in these stories, one can become rich only upon the intervention of divinities of good fortune. Nevertheless, wealth is usually described as a gift that rewards a long and continuing at- titude (honesty, devotion, kindness). Even though some stories tell

(17)

of deities giving a precious gift (gold or in other precious objects) to a poor person or family, still, that gift alone is not sufficient to accumulate and preserve wealth.

One story in particular describes in detail the dynamics of origi- nal accumulation—the ways in which wealth is produced and pre- served. It is the otogizōshi entitled Daikoku mai 大黒舞 (The Dance of the God Daikokuten), also known as ‘Daietsu monogatari’ 大悦 物語 (The Story of Daietsu), written between the late sixteenth and the early seventeenth century but based on a story appearing already in the Konjaku monogatarishū 今昔物語集 (early twelfth century).34 A certain Daietsunosuke from Yoshino in Yamato province was a deeply filial man. One day, during a pilgrimage to Kiyomizudera 水寺 in Kyoto, he saw the bodhisattva Kannon 観音 who told him:

‘You are very filial, and the gods want to give you good fortune and long life. I want to give you wealth as well. On your way back home, you will see one blade of rice straw (warashibe 藁蕊): pick it up!’ He does find it, but when he tries to pick it up, he has to fight an ogre (oni ) who tries to take it away from him. Daietsunosuke eventually succeeds in wrestling the straw away from the ogre. Later, Daietsunosuke exchanges that straw with people he encounters along the way for other objects: first, three pears, then three robes, then a horse, and finally three pieces of gold. Daietsunosuke is now rich. One day, his house is visited by the god Daikokuten, who gives him several gifts: a wish-fulfilling jewel (nyoi hōju 如意宝珠), a magic hammer (uchide no kozuchi, which when used produces everything one desires), and a hat that makes one invisible—concrete symbols of fortune and wealth in the pre-modern Japanese imaginary. Later in the story, the gods of fortune protect Daietsunosuke from the assault of a gang of robbers. In the end, Daetsunosuke marries a

‘princess’ (a noble lady), the daughter of a court minister; together they have many children and live prosperous.

34 Konjaku monogatarishū, fasc. 16 story no. 28.

(18)

35 See Rambelli, ‘Buddha’s Wrath’.

36 Komatsu, Fuku no kami to binbōgami, 6–10, 90.

Considerations

These stories assume poverty as the original economic condition for their protagonists, who are always poor at the beginning. In the stories, however, there is also an elusive realm of wealth and fortune on the background, associated with the aristocracy in the capital on the one hand and with the divinities in the invisible world on the other hand. The protagonists are only able to acquire wealth as a consequence of divine intervention, which invariably comes as retribution for their good behavior. As Komatsu Kazuhiko 小松和彦

explains, wealth or abundance (tomi ) is envisioned as a result of good fortune (fuku ), in turn generated by positive divine interven- tion. There is also a negative divine intervention (yaku or wazawai

災い), understood as a form of divine punishment (shinbatsu 神罰, tenbatsu 天罰 or butsubachi 仏罰) for evil behavior.35 In this sense, abundance and fortune are directly related to religious virtue (toku

) and merit-making (kudoku 功徳).36 In other words, when a poor person (hinja 貧者) accumulates religious merit (toku, kudoku), the deities intervene to bestow upon him (or, more rarely, her) good fortune (fuku), which results in wealth (tomi). At that point, the protagonist has become rich (chōja). According to these stories, then, merit-making generates economic profit; the language of religious virtue overlaps explicitly with that of economics. Wealth, however, is reversible. When the protagonists cease to accumulate religious merit, their wealth also disappears.

FIG. 1 Structure of Buddhist economy

→→→→ buddhas and kami ←←←←

poor (hinja) → merit (toku) → fortune (fuku) → wealth (tomi) → rich (chōja) ↑_________________________________________________↓

(19)

37 See Komatsu and Kurimoto, Keizai no tanjō; Komatsu, Fuku no kami to binbōgami.

38 Komatsu, Fuku no kami to binbōgami, 74–75.

39 See Miyata, ed., Shichifukujin shinkō jiten.

Wealth is also the result of religious purification,37 expressed in these stories as expelling the gods of poverty and demons who pre- vent the protagonists from becoming rich. Historical documents suggest that jinin and yoriudo 寄人 were responsible for this kind of wealth-producing purifications,38 envisioned as expelling the gods of poverty (binbōgami) to let the gods of fortune (fuku no kami) in. A number of divinities in Japanese religions specialize in the production of wealth. In addition to the seven gods of good fortune (shichifukujin 七福神: Daikokuten, Ebisu 恵比寿, Bishamonten, Benzaiten 弁財天, Fukurokuju, Jurōjin, Hotei), which appear as a set towards the end of the Muromachi period and became widely pop- ular during the Edo period, we also find Inari, Kannon, Jizō, and in some cases also Fudō Myōō 不動明王 and Matarajin 摩多羅神. The cult to these deities was actively encouraged by religious institutions, which since the Muromachi period organized popular festivals with performances, sermons, and rituals.39

Wealth had to be protected from enemies, described as ogres (oni) or robbers. Many stories seem to imply that wealth in fact belongs originally to the demons, as in the case of Daietsunosuke, who wrestles away the piece of straw from an oni. The protagonists of these stories can accumulate wealth only upon permission by certain deities, who want to reward them for their devotion and morality.

In this context, wealth is an ambiguous and potentially dangerous thing: a demonic feature ‘domesticated’ by Buddhist morality.

Another characteristic of wealth is that it rewards dominant and stereotypical ideas of morality and social behavior: faith and devotion in deities, filial piety, generosity, alms-giving, and pilgrimage to tem- ples and shrines—always by members of the lower strata of society.

At the same time, there was the idea that the upper strata of society were such because of their virtue and morality.

As Komatsu Kazuhiko notes, medieval literature offers virtually

(20)

40 Komatsu, Fuku no kami to binbōgami, 105.

41 Among religious institutions actively engaged in trade and capitalist ven- tures, the cases of the Ritsu sect first and Zen sects later are well known. Some temples deprived of land prospered by holding markets and levying fees on trade routes.

no example of peasants who became rich simply by cultivating their land—or, we may add, because of their entrepreneurship. Komatsu divides stories of enrichment into two main categories: those about finding gold, and those about increasing cultivated lands. However, while the former group deals with the prosperity of the protagonist who is already a chōja or becomes one, the latter group recounts stories of failure and final impoverishment.40 In other words, wealth is very often described as the result of non-agricultural, mercantile endeavors (trade and industry, with consequent accumulation of capital, expressed in gold, money, or rice); exchange is particularly important for the creation of value, seen here as economic surplus.

Significantly, wealth is also presented as a result of divine intervention and magical powers: Daietsunosuke’s increasingly profitable exchang- es that ultimately yield him three pieces of gold out of the original blade of straw, can be only the result of magic (or of a successful series of imbroglios against gullible people). We see the close connection between wealth and magical operations also in Daikokuten’s gifts to Daietsunosuke: in particular, the wish-fulfilling jewel and the magic hammer suggest the capacity to produce unlimited wealth, in the form of precious materials (gold) and precious objects produced out of nothing or through a transformation of ordinary, vile materials.

These stories seem to reflect the development of forms of proto- capitalism, especially from the late fourteenth and early fifteenth centuries onward. In some cases, religious institutions or religious groups were active promoters of such new mode of production and generation of wealth;41 in other cases, religious institutions were passive followers, attempting to give Buddhist meaning to processes of wealth formation which, in some cases, seemed to go against the fundamental precepts of the religion. As particularly evident in ‘Dai- koku-mai’, wealth accumulated by the protagonist Daietsunosuke

(21)

42 Komatsu, Fuku no kami to binbōgami, 35.

results from a series of exchanges, which, while apparently governed by the logic of barter (based on reciprocity and mutual satisfaction of needs, and emphasizing the use-value of the goods exchanged), follow in fact a capitalistic logic of individual profit. While his trading part- ners seem to be happy with the barters they conclude, as they do need the objects Daietsunosuke offers them (and are willing to get rid of the objects they have as useless), Daietsunosuke is not interested in the use-value of the object he acquires; rather, his goal is pure profit, the accumulation of capital—wealth. In order to reach his goal, he is willing to exchange objects on the basis of an obviously unjust value:

after a series of exchanges, one piece of straw ultimately yields three pieces of gold! It is not surprising, then, that the story presents the straw as a potentially demonic thing wrestled away from an oni.

In other words, it seems that to the authors of these stories, and perhaps also to their audience, the actual mechanisms of wealth production were not clear at all. By emphasizing supernatural in- tervention and magic tricks, and by describing a world of fairy tales (with deities, demons, and princesses), the stories ignore, or willfully misrepresent, the social and economic processes at play. We can prob- ably see here the deeply conservative (if not explicitly reactionary) nature of this kind of narratives. This last point is also clear from another feature of these stories, namely, the fact that they envision the ultimate success of one’s wealth acquisition as their protagonists’

recognition by the imperial court, in particular in the form of a court title (Daietsunosuke marries an aristocratic woman), or with some type of affiliation with aristocratic circles (as with the old couple from Umezu). Elevation into the aristocracy was seen as a guarantee that newly acquired prosperity would last for several generations—

even though by the mid-Muromachi period, the aristocracy was generally impoverished and could not compete with the wealthiest merchants and the most powerful daimyō. The symbolic role of the aristocracy probably is an indication of the authorship of these sto- ries, which were composed, as Komatsu Kazuhiko suggests, by priests and impoverished nobles.42 On the other hand, we should also note

(22)

that many professional guilds exercised their activities protected by official court titles and affiliations; in this sense, at least, these stories also reflect one aspect of later medieval social and economic reality.

In all these stories, one also notices the apparent coexistence of two different economic modes: one is quasi-capitalist, and the other is one of subsistence tempered by magic. In the first mode, proper to temples and shrines and aristocratic families envisioned as centers of stable wealth, the accumulation of capital is done for the sake of its reproduction; this mode remains in the background of the stories and is never discussed in depth or problematized. The second mode is essentially non-capitalist: it presupposes a subsistence economy, in which the acquisition of wealth can only be explained through divine intervention as retribution of merit. If the protagonists of these sto- ries are able to keep up the mechanism of sacred economy (merit—

wealth—offerings—merit—wealth—offerings etc.), they will be able to join the ranks of quasi-capitalist social groups. If they fail to do so, they will return to the realm of subsistence and poverty. Even so, the quasi-capitalist mode tends to be temperate, at least according to our contemporary standards. For example, accumulation is potentially infinite, but infinite wealth is never sought for; wish-fulfilling jewels and magical hammers are almost never used, and when they are, it is always for limited goals. Indeed, the acquisition of infinite wealth is almost unthinkable in this context—a grotesque manifestation of greed, rather than the fulfillment of a divine promise. Instead, the goal in most stories seems to be the protagonists’ co-optation into the aristocracy and, therefore, into the realm of stable wealth. This gener- al attitude changed during the Tokugawa era, when merchants’ greed came to be emphasized and openly criticized (as we will see below).

Let us now consider more in detail the role of religious institu- tions in the production of wealth. The case of the ascetic Myōren in the Shigisan engi is interesting because it summarizes several aspects of religious intervention in the economic arena according to the medieval Japanese imaginary. In the first scroll (and in other versions of the story), Myōren is the agent behind the accumulation of wealth by the chōja. As such, he benefits from the latter’s wealth through the daily donations he receives. When the chōja’s family breaks the original contract, Myōren makes further profits from

(23)

the chōja’s storehouse. The other episodes of the painted scroll deal more directly with the symbolic capital accumulated by Myōren. The second story tells how Myōren has become famous at court because of the miracle of the flying bowl and is requested to perform a ritual to heal Emperor Daigo 醍醐天皇; he succeeds, and presumably gains further symbolic (and material) capital. Finally, the third story tells how, many years after the death of the ascetic, the remains of the storehouse flown to Mt. Shigi by Myōren’s bowl are still endowed with miraculous power, and those who collect a splinter of wood from what is left of the structure will acquire wealth.

Other stories present a less indirect, but still very concrete, inter- vention of religious institutions in the production of wealth: they describe rituals at temples and shrines and religious objects such as talismans and amulets sold in temples. In these cases, people’s hopes for wealth generated an economy of religious commodities (goods and services); moreover, wealth was always the result of religious faith and devotion, and the acceptance of religiously and politically autho- rized social norms. The role of religious institutions was thus very im- portant, ranging from providing background moral codes to specific ritual services to the circulation of symbolic capital and goods.

More theoretically, these stories present religious institutions as mediators in exchange processes taking place between the visible world and the invisible realm of divinities and spirits. Temples were like investment banks: they identify where to invest (a deity, a ritual, an object, etc.) and how much (the amount of the offering), manage the investments (through ritual activity), and distribute the profits (salvation and/or worldly benefits). We could summarize the process as follows: the donor gives offerings to a priest or a religious institu- tion, which in turn gives it to the buddhas or kami; in retribution, the divinities bestow wealth and success upon the donor. The donor has the obligation to give back part of his newly acquired wealth as a sign of gratitude; if he or she fails to do so, they will lose everything.

It is interesting to note that this process of generation of wealth as described in popular narratives is essentially similar to actual eco- nomic processes taking place at temples and shrines, especially those concerning interests on loans (jōbun) and fees, as discussed above.

(24)

43 There is an extensive literature on these figures in Japanese scholarship, and a growing information in other languages as well. My reconstruction here is mostly based on Amino, Nihon chūsei no hyakushō to shokunōmin, especially pages 259–333; and Kuroda, Jisha seiryoku, 159–64.

Wealth, Power, and Resistance

A significant portion of economic practices in medieval Japan was carried out by members of specific groups, known as jinin (lit.,

‘people of the kami’) and yoriudo or shuto 衆徒, the lower members of the religious hierarchy at shrines and temples, respectively, and by itinerant religious specialists such as yamabushi, hijiri, and oshi (or onshi).43

Yoriudo and jinin were typical figures created by medieval Bud- dho-Shinto institutions in order to support their attempt to impose some kind of hegemony over their vast and scattered land possessions and economic interests. Yoriudo and jinin usually came from the upper stratum of the peasantry (hyakushō 百姓). They entrusted their lands to religious institutions, and in exchange received several benefits: they controlled and supervised agricultural labor and pro- duction; were involved in transportation, commerce, and loans; and secured the capital necessary for building and rebuilding temples, sacred objects, and the performance of rituals. They were also tech- nicians, responsible for engineering works (dams, field terracing) that improved agricultural production. At times, they were also employed as a sort of police/military corps of temples and shrines. Thus, the jinin were responsible for economic developments in religious es- tates, and at the same time they were the defenders of the social and economic order.

The jinin were not only concerned with production, technology, art, or coercion; they also attempted to create social consent in the estates (shōen 荘園), as a way to ensure a higher docility and more efficiency in social control and economic production. For example, when a large religious institution from the Nara-Kyoto area acquired a new estate, jinin and/or yoriudo were dispatched there and built a new temple or worship hall (as a branch of the main temple in

(25)

44 See Satō, ‘Wrathful Deities and Saving Deities’.

the capital) and a new shrine (a branch of the temple’s protector’s shrine). Then, they explained to the residents the relation between their local deity and the new deities on the basis of the fundamen- tal principle of medieval Japanese Buddhism, according to which Japanese kami were local manifestations of specific buddhas and bodhisattvas (a principle known as honji suijaku 本地垂迹, lit. ‘orig- inal ground and its manifest traces’). The jinin also developed and organized public events and rituals, such as the ta-asobi 田遊び (‘rice- field plays’, festivals that took place in the countryside at New Year’s or during planting season). These new rituals were instrumental in the creation of a sense of community and hierarchy in the locale by connecting it with more general orders of significance: the region, the network of the main temple, Japan, and finally the entire cosmos. In this way, a cosmic order was superimposed to a local hierarchy (in a way not dissimilar from what already happened at court); by partici- pating in the ritual everyone knew their own position not only in the shōen but also in the entire cosmos.44

What I am suggesting here is that jinin and yoriudo (and hijiri, yamabushi, oshi, and other itinerant specialists) were the main protagonists of the attempt to establish a sort of Buddho-Shinto hegemony in medieval Japan; they could even be assimilated to what Antonio Gramsci called ‘organic intellectual’—people directly re- sponsible for establishing the hegemony of a certain ruling bloc. The jinin were not just imposing alien ideas and rituals of domination to newly acquired estates in far-flung locales. Themselves people from the low-middle classes, but at the same time unstable allied with major temples that were controlled by the aristocracy and the leading samurai families, the jinin were responsible for the negotiation of values among various social groups and interests which produced a veritable hegemony. They played an important role in the formation and development of economic ideas and practices in medieval Japan, mediating between doctrinal discourses (which usually do not pro- vide specific managerial instructions) and popular practices (such as the hatsuho system).

(26)

Religious institutions thus were the ultimate guarantors of economic profit and wealth, envisioned as manifestations of the be- nevolence of the deities and, therefore, signs of future salvation. At the same time, devout people were encouraged to provide economic support to religious institutions in exchange for wealth and salvation.

It was a full-fledged system of exchange, in which worldly wealth was exchanged for supernatural protection and benefits, which in turns generated additional worldly wealth. For example, in 1498 the resi- dents of the estate (shōen) of Ikaruga (Harima, in present-day Hyōgo prefecture), belonging to the Hōryūji, afflicted by an invasion of insects, asked the temple for help; the priests performed the Hyakuza Ninnō Lecture at the temple and distributed talismans in the shōen, and succeeded in eliminating the insects.45 Chōgen (1121–1206), the hijiri known for his successful fund-raising for the reconstruction of the Tōdaiji, wrote: ‘the temple performs rituals (kitō) for the estate, and the estate provides for the temple.’46 The mediating role of reli- gious institutions, which determines the status of all involved in the religious economy, is explained by a statement attributed to Suwa shrine, according to which its main deity, Suwa Daimyōjin, speaks through the priests (kannushi and ōhōri) who are its emissaries.47 Those who accept this vision of society receive positive retribution (wealth in certain cases and rebirth into paradise for all), whereas those who reject it will be punished by the deities in a terrible and cruel way. For example, Ban’a 鑁阿 (?–1207),48 a Shingon monk ded- icated to the organization of shōen estates and to religious activities against mappō 末法 (the End of the Dharma), told managers and peasants of the Ōta shōen in the province of Higo (present-day Naga- saki prefecture) that the cultivation of newly reclaimed lands and the payment of annual taxes to the temple were the best deeds to be per- formed in order to acquire merit; however, should they not obey the orders of the temple officers, they would receive punishment from all

45 Abe and Ōta, eds., Harima no kuni Ikaruga-shō shiryō, 24.

46 Kamakura ibun, vol. 2, no. 621, 45–46.

47 Azuma kagami, vol. 1, 247.

48 On Ban’a, see Mikkyō Daijiten, 1826 b–c.

(27)

buddhas, all kami, and even from the saint Kōbō Daishi.49 Chōgen again wrote in a document addressed in 1192 to the managers and peasants of a shōen belonging to the Tōdaiji that the enemies of the temple ‘will become lepers in the present life, and will fall into the Uninterrupted Hell in the next.’50 Monks performed official rituals of witchcraft and black magic (juso 呪詛) against those who did not comply with the economic or political rules of religious institu- tions.51 Again, it is interesting to note the extent to which economic practices and social ideology where connected to soteriology; it is also remarkable that the interlocking of these religious and economic discourses continued for centuries.

At this point we should ask ourselves what was the actual efficacy of the religious ideology connecting work, wealth, and salvation. Did everyone accept it at face value? Or do we see instances of rebellion and skepticism? Some people chose indeed to reject the religious/

economic ideology of the main temples. The various forms of re- fusal to worship the local deities, known as jingi fuhai 神祇不拝, an important feature of the system of domination of the shōen manors, as emphasized by Kuroda Toshio 黒田俊雄, Taira Masayuki 平雅之, and Satō Hiroo, were not animated only by a new form of spiritu- ality, but were challenging at the roots the system of domination of the main temples. Many land stewards (jitō), in particular, seemed to subscribe to the jingi fuhai positions: they openly questioned the sacredness of the temple lands and tried to capture the profits they generated.52

Many people in the provinces also seem to have questioned the association between wealth and virtue proposed by religious institu- tions. Several popular legends concerning the murder of strangers

49 Kamakura ibun vol. 2, no. 575, 3–5.

50 Kamakura ibun, vol. 2, no. 621, 45–46.

51 See Rambelli, ‘Buddha’s Wrath’.

52 On the phenomenon of jingi fuhai, see Rambelli, ‘“Just Behave as You Like”’; Kuroda Toshio, Nihon chūsei no kokka to shūkyō, especially pages 257–62;

and Satō Hiroo, Nihon chūsei no kokka to bukkyō, 89–109; Kami, hotoke, ōken no chūsei, 89–177; Kishōmon no seishinshi, 148–82.

(28)

visiting remote villages (a genre known as ijingoroshi 異人殺し), which flourished during the Edo period, have an economic meaning.53 They explain the sudden wealth of members of the village community as a result of the appropriation of gold and other valuables taken from murdered strangers. These strangers were often itinerant priests or yamabushi who brought to the isolated village Buddhist ideas and practices and different visions of society—visions that were in a way or another authorized by the bakufu and the religious institutions.

Murder stories reveal a spirit of resistance against the political and re- ligious establishments and the translocal economy they supported. In these narratives, wealth is often the result of interference from the out- side world, the consequence of a crime, something that disrupts the traditional life of the village. Furthermore, Carmen Blacker describes how traditional village society criticizes sudden wealth, often a feature of newcomers to the village, and ostracizes its holders, by attributing it to black magic such as the manipulation of foxes and badgers, who take away vital energy and wealth from the other villagers.54

A well-known story for the Edo period, entitled ‘Nakano chōja’

(The wealthy man from Nakano), exemplifies a number of these elements. A merchant became rich with his trade in horses, and gave most of his profits to the bodhisattva Kannon at Sensōji 浅草寺. As retribution, one day he found a big pot full of gold coins under the floor of his house. He became overly attached to that gold; he turned greedy and stingy, and gold kept accumulating. In order to protect his new wealth, he decided to bury the gold in the woods, then he killed all the servants who had helped him in order to keep secret the treasure’s location. However, one day, at the eve of his daughter’s long-awaited marriage ceremony, the girl is abducted by the spirits of the murdered servants, turns into a snake, and kills herself in a pond.

This story is an Edo period version of an earlier, Muromachi period narrative, inspired by a real person, Suzuki Kurō (1371–1440), known for his piety and generosity. The Edo period version focuses on the death of the protagonist’s daughter (apparently a real event)

53 Komatsu, Ijinron: Minzoku shakai no shinsei.

54 Blacker, The Catalpa Bow.

參考文獻

相關文件

The economy of Macao expanded by 21.1% in real terms in the third quarter of 2011, attributable to the increase in exports of services, private consumption expenditure and

In the second quarter of 2006, Macao’s economy rose 16.3% in real terms and 22.6% in nominal terms, accounting for a real growth of 17.7% and a nominal growth of 23.4% of the local

Yesterday he was absent from school because he had a coldD. Yesterday the weather was

Although Taiwan stipulates explicit regulations governing the requirements for organic production process, certification management, and the penalties for organic agricultural

6 《中論·觀因緣品》,《佛藏要籍選刊》第 9 冊,上海古籍出版社 1994 年版,第 1

To stimulate creativity, smart learning, critical thinking and logical reasoning in students, drama and arts play a pivotal role in the..

 Promote project learning, mathematical modeling, and problem-based learning to strengthen the ability to integrate and apply knowledge and skills, and make. calculated

Teachers may consider the school’s aims and conditions or even the language environment to select the most appropriate approach according to students’ need and ability; or develop