• 沒有找到結果。

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "Toward the Black-Scholes Formula"

Copied!
74
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula

• The binomial model seems to suffer from two unrealistic assumptions.

– The stock price takes on only two values in a period.

– Trading occurs at discrete points in time.

• As n increases, the stock price ranges over ever larger numbers of possible values, and trading takes place nearly continuously.

• Any proper calibration of the model parameters makes the BOPM converge to the continuous-time model.

• We now skim through the proof.

(2)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• Let τ denote the time to expiration of the option measured in years.

• Let r be the continuously compounded annual rate.

• With n periods during the option’s life, each period represents a time interval of τ /n.

• Need to adjust the period-based u, d, and interest rate ˆ

r to match the empirical results as n goes to infinity.

• First, ˆr = rτ /n.

– The period gross return R = erˆ.

(3)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• Use b

µ ≡ 1 n E

·

ln Sτ S

¸

and bσ2 1

n Var

·

ln Sτ S

¸

to denote, resp., the expected value and variance of the continuously compounded rate of return per period.

• Under the BOPM, it is not hard to show that b

µ = q ln(u/d) + ln d, b

σ2 = q(1 − q) ln2(u/d).

(4)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• Assume the stock’s true continuously compounded rate of return over τ years has mean µτ and variance σ2τ .

– Call σ the stock’s (annualized) volatility.

• The BOPM converges to the distribution only if nbµ = n(q ln(u/d) + ln d) → µτ, nbσ2 = nq(1 − q) ln2(u/d) → σ2τ.

• Impose ud = 1 to make nodes at the same horizontal level of the tree have identical price (review p. 239).

(5)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• The above requirements can be satisfied by u = eσ

τ /n, d = e−σ

τ /n, q = 1

2 + 1 2

µ σ

rτ

n . (24)

• With Eqs. (24),

nbµ = µτ, nbσ2 =

·

1 − ³ µ σ

´2 τ n

¸

σ2τ → σ2τ.

(6)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• The no-arbitrage inequalities d < R < u may not hold under Eqs. (24) on p. 248.

– If this happens, the risk-neutral probability may lie outside [ 0, 1 ].a

• The problem disappears when n satisfies eσ

τ /n > erτ /n,

or when n > r2τ /σ2 (check it).

– So it goes away if n is large enough.

– Other solutions will be presented later.

(7)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• What is the limiting probabilistic distribution of the continuously compounded rate of return ln(Sτ/S)?

• The central limit theorem says ln(Sτ/S) converges to the normal distribution with mean µτ and variance σ2τ .

• So ln Sτ approaches the normal distribution with mean µτ + ln S and variance σ2τ .

• Sτ has a lognormal distribution in the limit.

(8)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

Lemma 7 The continuously compounded rate of return ln(Sτ/S) approaches the normal distribution with mean (r − σ2/2) τ and variance σ2τ in a risk-neutral economy.

• Let q equal the risk-neutral probability p ≡ (erτ /n − d)/(u − d).

• Let n → ∞.

(9)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• By Lemma 7 (p. 251) and Eq. (18) on p. 151, the expected stock price at expiration in a risk-neutral economy is Se.

• The stock’s expected annual rate of returna is thus the riskless rate r.

aIn the sense of (1/τ ) ln E[ Sτ/S ] (arithmetic average rate of return) not (1/τ )E[ ln(Sτ/S) ] (geometric average rate of return).

(10)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (concluded)

a

Theorem 8 (The Black-Scholes Formula) C = SN (x) − Xe−rτN (x − σ√

τ ), P = Xe−rτN (−x + σ√

τ ) − SN (−x), where

x ≡ ln(S/X) + ¡

r + σ2/2¢ τ σ√

τ .

aOn a United flight from San Francisco to Tokyo on March 7, 2010, a real-estate manager mentioned this formula to me!

(11)

BOPM and Black-Scholes Model

• The Black-Scholes formula needs five parameters: S, X, σ, τ , and r.

• Binomial tree algorithms take six inputs: S, X, u, d, ˆr, and n.

• The connections are u = eσ

τ /n, d = e−σ

τ /n, ˆr = rτ /n.

• The binomial tree algorithms converge reasonably fast.

• Oscillations can be dealt with by the judicious choices of u and d (see text).

(12)

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 n

11.5 12 12.5 13

Call value

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 n

15.1 15.2 15.3 15.4 15.5

Call value

• S = 100, X = 100 (left), and X = 95 (right).

• The error is O(1/n).a

aChang and Palmer (2007).

(13)

Implied Volatility

• Volatility is the sole parameter not directly observable.

• The Black-Scholes formula can be used to compute the market’s opinion of the volatility.

– Solve for σ given the option price, S, X, τ , and r with numerical methods.

– How about American options?

• This volatility is called the implied volatility.

• Implied volatility is often preferred to historical volatility in practice.a

aIt is like driving a car with your eyes on the rearview mirror?

(14)

Problems; the Smile

• Options written on the same underlying asset usually do not produce the same implied volatility.

• A typical pattern is a “smile” in relation to the strike price.

– The implied volatility is lowest for at-the-money options.

– It becomes higher the further the option is in- or out-of-the-money.

• Other patterns have also been observed.

(15)

Problems; the Smile (concluded)

• To address this issue, volatilities are often combined to produce a composite implied volatility.

• This practice is not sound theoretically.

• The existence of different implied volatilities for options on the same underlying asset shows the Black-Scholes model cannot be literally true.

(16)

Trading Days and Calendar Days

• Interest accrues based on the calendar day.

• But σ is usually calculated based on trading days only.

– Stock price seems to have lower volatilities when the exchange is closed.a

• How to incorporate these two different ways of day

count into the Black-Scholes formula and binomial tree algorithms?

aFama (1965); French (1980); French and Roll (1986).

(17)

Trading Days and Calendar Days (concluded)

• Think of σ as measuring the volatility of stock price one year from now (regardless of what happens in between).

• Suppose a year has 260 trading days.

• A quick and dirty way is to replace σ witha σ

s 365 260

number of trading days to expiration number of calendar days to expiration .

• How about binomial tree algorithms?

aFrench (1984).

(18)

Binomial Tree Algorithms for American Puts

• Early exercise has to be considered.

• The binomial tree algorithm starts with the terminal payoffs

max(0, X − Sujdn−j) and applies backward induction.

• At each intermediate node, it checks for early exercise by comparing the payoff if exercised with the

continuation value.

(19)

Bermudan Options

• Some American options can be exercised only at discrete time points instead of continuously.

• They are called Bermudan options.

• Their pricing algorithm is identical to that for American options.

• The only exception is early exercise is considered for only those nodes when early exercise is permitted.

(20)

Options on a Stock That Pays Dividends

• Early exercise must be considered.

• Proportional dividend payout model is tractable (see text).

– The dividend amount is a constant proportion of the prevailing stock price.

• In general, the corporate dividend policy is a complex issue.

(21)

Known Dividends

• Constant dividends introduce complications.

• Use D to denote the amount of the dividend.

• Suppose an ex-dividend date falls in the first period.

• At the end of that period, the possible stock prices are Su − D and Sd − D.

• Follow the stock price one more period.

• The number of possible stock prices is not three but four: (Su − D) u, (Su − D) d, (Sd − D) u, (Sd − D) d.

– The binomial tree no longer combines.

(22)

(Su − D) u

% Su − D

% &

(Su − D) d S

(Sd − D) u

& %

Sd − D

&

(Sd − D) d

(23)

An Ad-Hoc Approximation

• Use the Black-Scholes formula with the stock price reduced by the PV of the dividends (Roll, 1977).

• This essentially decomposes the stock price into a riskless one paying known dividends and a risky one.

• The riskless component at any time is the PV of future dividends during the life of the option.

– σ equal to the volatility of the process followed by the risky component.

• The stock price, between two adjacent ex-dividend dates, follows the same lognormal distribution.

(24)

An Ad-Hoc Approximation (concluded)

• Start with the current stock price minus the PV of future dividends before expiration.

• Develop the binomial tree for the new stock price as if there were no dividends.

• Then add to each stock price on the tree the PV of all future dividends before expiration.

• American option prices can be computed as before on this tree of stock prices.

(25)

An Ad-Hoc Approximation vs. P. 265 (Step 1)

S − D/R

*

j

(S − D/R)u

*

j

(S − D/R)d

*

j

(S − D/R)u2

(S − D/R)ud

(S − D/R)d2

(26)

An Ad-Hoc Approximation vs. P. 265 (Step 2)

(S − D/R) + D/R = S

*

j

(S − D/R)u

*

j

(S − D/R)d

*

j

(S − D/R)u2

(S − D/R)ud

(S − D/R)d2

(27)

An Ad-Hoc Approximation vs. P. 265

a

• The trees are different.

• The stock prices at maturity are also different.

– (Su − D) u, (Su − D) d, (Sd − D) u, (Sd − D) d (p. 265).

– (S − D/R)u2, (S − D/R)ud, (S − D/R)d2 (ad hoc).

• Note that (Su − D) u > (S − D/R)u2 and (Sd − D) d < (S − D/R)d2 as d < R < u.

aContributed by Mr. Yang, Jui-Chung (D97723002) on March 18, 2009.

(28)

An Ad-Hoc Approximation vs. P. 265 (concluded)

• So the ad hoc approximation has a smaller dynamic range.

• This explains why in practice the volatility is usually increased when using the ad hoc approximation.

(29)

A General Approach

a

• A new tree structure.

• No approximation assumptions are made.

• A mathematical proof that the tree can always be constructed.

• The actual performance is quadratic except in pathological cases (see 621ff).

• Other approaches include adjusting σ and approximating the known dividend with a dividend yield.

aDai (R86526008, D8852600) and Lyuu (2004).

(30)

Continuous Dividend Yields

• Dividends are paid continuously.

– Approximates a broad-based stock market portfolio.

• The payment of a continuous dividend yield at rate q reduces the growth rate of the stock price by q.

– A stock that grows from S to Sτ with a continuous dividend yield of q would grow from S to Sτe without the dividends.

• A European option has the same value as one on a stock with price Se−qτ that pays no dividends.

(31)

Continuous Dividend Yields (continued)

• The Black-Scholes formulas hold with S replaced by Se−qτ:a

C = Se−qτN (x) − Xe−rτN (x − σ√

τ ), (25) P = Xe−rτN (−x + σ√

τ ) − Se−qτN (−x),

(250) where

x ≡ ln(S/X) + ¡

r − q + σ2/2¢ τ σ√

τ .

• Formulas (25) and (25’) remain valid as long as the dividend yield is predictable.

(32)

Continuous Dividend Yields (continued)

• To run binomial tree algorithms, replace u with ue−q∆t and d with de−q∆t, where ∆t ≡ τ /n.

– The reason: The stock price grows at an expected rate of r − q in a risk-neutral economy.

• Other than the changes, binomial tree algorithms stay the same.

– In particular, p should use the original u and d.a

aContributed by Ms. Wang, Chuan-Ju (F95922018) on May 2, 2007.

(33)

Continuous Dividend Yields (concluded)

• Alternatively, pick the risk-neutral probability as e(r−q) ∆t − d

u − d , (26)

where ∆t ≡ τ /n.

– The reason: The stock price grows at an expected rate of r − q in a risk-neutral economy.

• The u and d remain unchanged.

• Other than the change in Eq. (26), binomial tree algorithms stay the same.

(34)

Sensitivity Analysis of Options

(35)

Cleopatra’s nose, had it been shorter, the whole face of the world would have been changed.

— Blaise Pascal (1623–1662)

(36)

Sensitivity Measures (“The Greeks”)

• How the value of a security changes relative to changes in a given parameter is key to hedging.

– Duration, for instance.

• Let x ≡ ln(S/X)+(r+σ2/2) τ σ

τ (recall p. 253).

• Note that

N0(y) = e−y2/2

√2π > 0,

the density function of standard normal distribution.

(37)

Delta

• Defined as ∆ ≡ ∂f /∂S.

– f is the price of the derivative.

– S is the price of the underlying asset.

• The delta of a portfolio of derivatives on the same underlying asset is the sum of their individual deltas.

– Elementary calculus.

• The delta used in the BOPM is the discrete analog.

(38)

Delta (concluded)

• The delta of a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock equals

∂C

∂S = N (x) > 0.

• The delta of a European put equals

∂P

∂S = N (x) − 1 < 0.

• The delta of a long stock is 1.

(39)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) 0

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

Delta (call)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) -1

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0

Delta (put)

0 20 40 60 80

Stock price 0

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

Delta (call)

0 20 40 60 80

Stock price -1

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0

Delta (put)

Solid curves: at-the-money options.

Dashed curves: out-of-the-money calls or in-the-money puts.

(40)

Delta Neutrality

• A position with a total delta equal to 0 is delta-neutral.

– A delta-neutral portfolio is immune to small price changes in the underlying asset.

• Creating one serves for hedging purposes.

– A portfolio consisting of a call and −∆ shares of stock is delta-neutral.

– Short ∆ shares of stock to hedge a long call.

• In general, hedge a position in a security with delta ∆1 by shorting ∆ /∆ units of a security with delta ∆ .

(41)

Theta (Time Decay)

• Defined as the rate of change of a security’s value with respect to time, or Θ ≡ −∂f /∂τ = ∂f /∂t.

• For a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock, Θ = −SN0(x) σ

2

τ − rXe−rτN (x − σ√

τ ) < 0.

– The call loses value with the passage of time.

• For a European put, Θ = −SN0(x) σ

2

τ + rXe−rτN (−x + σ√ τ ).

– Can be negative or positive.

(42)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) -60

-50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0

Theta (call)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) -50

-40 -30 -20 -10 0

Theta (put)

0 20 40 60 80

Stock price -6

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0

Theta (call)

0 20 40 60 80

Stock price -2

-1 0 1 2 3

Theta (put)

Dotted curve: in-the-money call or out-of-the-money put.

(43)

Gamma

• Defined as the rate of change of its delta with respect to the price of the underlying asset, or Γ ≡ ∂2Π/∂S2.

• Measures how sensitive delta is to changes in the price of the underlying asset.

• In practice, a portfolio with a high gamma needs be rebalanced more often to maintain delta neutrality.

• Roughly, delta ∼ duration, and gamma ∼ convexity.

• The gamma of a European call or put on a non-dividend-paying stock is

N0(x)/(Sσ√

τ ) > 0.

(44)

0 20 40 60 80 Stock price

0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04

Gamma (call/put)

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) 0

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5

Gamma (call/put)

Dotted lines: in-the-money call or out-of-the-money put.

Solid lines: at-the-money option.

Dashed lines: out-of-the-money call or in-the-money put.

(45)

Vega

a

(Lambda, Kappa, Sigma)

• Defined as the rate of change of its value with respect to the volatility of the underlying asset Λ ≡ ∂Π/∂σ.

• Volatility often changes over time.

• A security with a high vega is very sensitive to small changes or estimation error in volatility.

• The vega of a European call or put on a non-dividend-paying stock is S√

τ N0(x) > 0.

– So higher volatility increases option value.

aVega is not Greek.

(46)

0 20 40 60 80 Stock price

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Vega (call/put)

50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) 0

2.5 5 7.5 10 12.5 15 17.5

Vega (call/put)

Dotted curve: in-the-money call or out-of-the-money put.

Solid curves: at-the-money option.

Dashed curve: out-of-the-money call or in-the-money put.

(47)

Rho

• Defined as the rate of change in its value with respect to interest rates ρ ≡ ∂Π/∂r.

• The rho of a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock is

Xτ e−rτN (x − σ√

τ ) > 0.

• The rho of a European put on a non-dividend-paying stock is

−Xτ e−rτN (−x + σ√

τ ) < 0.

(48)

50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) 0

5 10 15 20 25 30 35

Rho (call)

50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Time to expiration (days) -30

-25 -20 -15 -10 -5 0

Rho (put)

0 20 40 60 80

Stock price 0

5 10 15 20 25

Rho (call)

0 20 40 60 80

Stock price -25

-20 -15 -10 -5 0

Rho (put)

Dotted curves: in-the-money call or out-of-the-money put.

(49)

Numerical Greeks

• Needed when closed-form formulas do not exist.

• Take delta as an example.

• A standard method computes the finite difference, f (S + ∆S) − f (S − ∆S)

2∆S .

• The computation time roughly doubles that for evaluating the derivative security itself.

(50)

An Alternative Numerical Delta

a

• Use intermediate results of the binomial tree algorithm.

• When the algorithm reaches the end of the first period, fu and fd are computed.

• These values correspond to derivative values at stock prices Su and Sd, respectively.

• Delta is approximated by

fu − fd Su − Sd.

• Almost zero extra computational effort.

(51)

S/(ud)

S/d

S/u

Su/d

S

Sd/u

Su

Sd Suu/d

Sdd/u

Suuu/d

Suu

S

Sdd

Sddd/u

(52)

Numerical Gamma

• At the stock price (Suu + Sud)/2, delta is approximately (fuu − fud)/(Suu − Sud).

• At the stock price (Sud + Sdd)/2, delta is approximately (fud − fdd)/(Sud − Sdd).

• Gamma is the rate of change in deltas between (Suu + Sud)/2 and (Sud + Sdd)/2, that is,

fuu−fud

Suu−Sud Sud−Sddfud−fdd (Suu − Sdd)/2 .

(53)

Finite Difference Fails for Numerical Gamma

• Numerical differentiation gives

f (S + ∆S) − 2f (S) + f (S − ∆S)

(∆S)2 .

• It does not work (see text).

• But why did the binomial tree version work?

(54)

Other Numerical Greeks

• The theta can be computed as fud − f

2(τ /n) .

– In fact, the theta of a European option can be derived from delta and gamma (p. 527).

• For vega and rho, there is no alternative but to run the binomial tree algorithm twice.

(55)

Extensions of Options Theory

(56)

As I never learnt mathematics, so I have had to think.

— Joan Robinson (1903–1983)

(57)

Pricing Corporate Securities

a

• Interpret the underlying asset as the total value of the firm.

• The option pricing methodology can be applied to pricing corporate securities.

• Assume:

– A firm can finance payouts by the sale of assets.

– If a promised payment to an obligation other than stock is missed, the claim holders take ownership of the firm and the stockholders get nothing.

aBlack and Scholes (1973).

(58)

Risky Zero-Coupon Bonds and Stock

• Consider XYZ.com.

• Capital structure:

– n shares of its own common stock, S.

– Zero-coupon bonds with an aggregate par value of X.

• What is the value of the bonds, B?

• What is the value of the XYZ.com stock?

(59)

Risky Zero-Coupon Bonds and Stock (continued)

• On the bonds’ maturity date, suppose the total value of the firm V is less than the bondholders’ claim X.

• Then the firm declares bankruptcy, and the stock becomes worthless.

• If V > X, then the bondholders obtain X and the stockholders V − X.

V ≤ X V > X

Bonds V X

Stock 0 V − X

(60)

Risky Zero-Coupon Bonds and Stock (continued)

• The stock is a call on the total value of the firm with a strike price of X and an expiration date equal to the bonds’.

– This call provides the limited liability for the stockholders.

• The bonds are a covered call on the total value of the firm.

• Let V stand for the total value of the firm.

• Let C stand for a call on V .

(61)

Risky Zero-Coupon Bonds and Stock (continued)

• Thus nS = C and B = V − C.

• Knowing C amounts to knowing how the value of the firm is divided between stockholders and bondholders.

• Whatever the value of C, the total value of the stock and bonds at maturity remains V .

• The relative size of debt and equity is irrelevant to the firm’s current value V .

(62)

Risky Zero-Coupon Bonds and Stock (continued)

• From Theorem 8 (p. 253) and the put-call parity, nS = V N (x) − Xe−rτN (x − σ√

τ ), B = V N (−x) + Xe−rτN (x − σ√

τ ).

– Above,

x ≡ ln(V /X) + (r + σ2/2)τ σ√

τ .

• The continuously compounded yield to maturity of the firm’s bond is

ln(X/B) .

(63)

Risky Zero-Coupon Bonds and Stock (concluded)

• Define the credit spread or default premium as the yield difference between risky and riskless bonds,

ln(X/B)

τ − r

= −1 τ ln

µ

N (−z) + 1

ω N (z − σ√ τ )

. – ω ≡ Xe−rτ/V .

– z ≡ (ln ω)/(σ√

τ ) + (1/2) σ√

τ = −x + σ√ τ . – Note that ω is the debt-to-total-value ratio.

(64)

A Numerical Example

• XYZ.com’s assets consist of 1,000 shares of Merck as of March 20, 1995.

– Merck’s market value per share is $44.5.

• XYZ.com’s securities consist of 1,000 shares of common stock and 30 zero-coupon bonds maturing on July 21, 1995.

• Each bond promises to pay $1,000 at maturity.

• n = 1000, V = 44.5 × n = 44500, and X = 30 × 1000 = 30000.

(65)

—Call— —Put—

Option Strike Exp. Vol. Last Vol. Last Merck 30 Jul 328 151/4 . . . . . .

441/2 35 Jul 150 91/2 10 1/16

441/2 40 Apr 887 43/4 136 1/16

441/2 40 Jul 220 51/2 297 1/4

441/2 40 Oct 58 6 10 1/2

441/2 45 Apr 3050 7/8 100 11/8

441/2 45 May 462 13/8 50 13/8

441/2 45 Jul 883 115/16 147 13/4

441/2 45 Oct 367 23/4 188 21/16

(66)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• The Merck option relevant for pricing is the July call with a strike price of X/n = 30 dollars.

• Such a call is selling for $15.25.

• So XYZ.com’s stock is worth 15.25 × n = 15250 dollars.

• The entire bond issue is worth

B = 44500 − 15250 = 29250 dollars.

– Or $975 per bond.

(67)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• The XYZ.com bonds are equivalent to a default-free zero-coupon bond with $X par value plus n written European puts on Merck at a strike price of $30.

– By the put-call parity.

• The difference between B and the price of the default-free bond is the value of these puts.

• The next table shows the total market values of the XYZ.com stock and bonds under various debt amounts X.

(68)

Promised payment Current market Current market Current total to bondholders value of bonds value of stock value of firm

X B nS V

30,000 29,250.0 15,250.0 44,500

35,000 35,000.0 9,500.0 44,500

40,000 39,000.0 5,500.0 44,500

45,000 42,562.5 1,937.5 44,500

(69)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• Suppose the promised payment to bondholders is

$45,000.

• Then the relevant option is the July call with a strike price of 45000/n = 45 dollars.

• Since that option is selling for $115/16, the market value of the XYZ.com stock is (1 + 15/16) × n = 1937.5

dollars.

• The market value of the stock decreases as the debt-equity ratio increases.

(70)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• There are conflicts between stockholders and bondholders.

• An option’s terms cannot be changed after issuance.

• But a firm can change its capital structure.

• There lies one key difference between options and corporate securities.

– Parameters such volatility, dividend, and strike price are under partial control of the stockholders.

(71)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• Suppose XYZ.com issues 15 more bonds with the same terms to buy back stock.

• The total debt is now X = 45,000 dollars.

• The table on p. 311 says the total market value of the bonds should be $42,562.5.

• The new bondholders pay 42562.5 × (15/45) = 14187.5 dollars.

• The remaining stock is worth $1,937.5.

(72)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• The stockholders therefore gain

14187.5 + 1937.5 − 15250 = 875 dollars.

• The original bondholders lose an equal amount, 29250 − 30

45 × 42562.5 = 875. (27)

(73)

A Numerical Example (continued)

• Suppose the stockholders sell (1/3) × n Merck shares to fund a $14,833.3 cash dividend.

• They now have $14,833.3 in cash plus a call on (2/3) × n Merck shares.

• The strike price remains X = 30000.

• This is equivalent to owning 2/3 of a call on n Merck shares with a total strike price of $45,000.

• n such calls are worth $1,937.5 (p. 311).

• So the total market value of the XYZ.com stock is (2/3) × 1937.5 = 1291.67 dollars.

(74)

A Numerical Example (concluded)

• The market value of the XYZ.com bonds is hence (2/3) × n × 44.5 − 1291.67 = 28375 dollars.

• Hence the stockholders gain

14833.3 + 1291.67 − 15250 ≈ 875 dollars.

• The bondholders watch their value drop from $29,250 to

$28,375, a loss of $875.

參考文獻

相關文件

• P u is the price of the i-period zero-coupon bond one period from now if the short rate makes an up move. • P d is the price of the i-period zero-coupon bond one period from now

• The weight is the probability that the stock price hits the diagonal for the first time at that node...

• The binomial interest rate tree can be used to calculate the yield volatility of zero-coupon bonds.. • Consider an n-period

• The XYZ.com bonds are equivalent to a default-free zero-coupon bond with $X par value plus n written European puts on Merck at a strike price of $30. – By the

• The XYZ.com bonds are equivalent to a default-free zero-coupon bond with $X par value plus n written European puts on Merck at a strike price of $30.. – By the

• Now suppose the settlement date for a bond selling at par (i.e., the quoted price is equal to the par value) falls between two coupon payment dates. • Then its yield to maturity

– at a premium (above its par value) when its coupon rate c is above the market interest rate r;. – at par (at its par value) when its coupon rate is equal to the market

– at a premium (above its par value) when its coupon rate c is above the market interest rate r;. – at par (at its par value) when its coupon rate is equal to the market