• 沒有找到結果。

Payoff of Stock

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "Payoff of Stock"

Copied!
57
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Cash Dividends

• Exchange-traded stock options are not cash dividend-protected (or simply protected).

– The option contract is not adjusted for cash dividends.

• The stock price falls by an amount roughly equal to the amount of the cash dividend as it goes ex-dividend.

• Cash dividends are detrimental for calls.

• The opposite is true for puts.

(2)

Stock Splits and Stock Dividends

• Options are adjusted for stock splits.

• After an n-for-m stock split, m shares become n shares.

• Accordingly, the strike price is only m/n times its

previous value, and the number of shares covered by one contract becomes n/m times its previous value.

• Exchange-traded stock options are adjusted for stock dividends.

• We assume options are unprotected.

(3)

Example

• Consider an option to buy 100 shares of a company for

$50 per share.

• A 2-for-1 split changes the term to a strike price of $25 per share for 200 shares.

(4)

Short Selling

• Short selling (or simply shorting) involves selling an asset that is not owned with the intention of buying it back later.

– If you short 1,000 XYZ shares, the broker borrows them from another client to sell them in the market.

– This action generates proceeds for the investor.

– The investor can close out the short position by buying 1,000 XYZ shares.

– Clearly, the investor profits if the stock price falls.

• Not all assets can be shorted.

(5)

Payoff of Stock

20 40 60 80 Price

Long a stock

20 40 60 80 Payoff

20 40 60 80 Price

Short a stock

-80 -60 -40 -20

Payoff

(6)

Covered Position: Hedge

• A hedge combines an option with its underlying stock in such a way that one protects the other against loss.

• Covered call: A long position in stock with a short call.a – It is “covered” because the stock can be delivered to

the buyer of the call if the call is exercised.

• Protective put: A long position in stock with a long put.

• Both strategies break even only if the stock price rises, so they are bullish.

aA short position has a payoff opposite in sign to that of a long position.

(7)

85 90 95 100 105 110Stock price Protective put

-2.5 2.5 5 7.5 10 12.5

Profit

85 90 95 100 105 110Stock price Covered call

-12 -10 -8 -6 -4 -2 2 Profit

Solid lines are profits of the portfolio one month before

maturity, assuming the portfolio is set up when S = 95 then.

(8)

Covered Position: Spread

• A spread consists of options of the same type and on the same underlying asset but with different strike prices or expiration dates.

• We use XL, XM, and XH to denote the strike prices with

XL < XM < XH.

(9)

Covered Position: Spread (continued)

• A bull call spread consists of a long XL call and a short XH call with the same expiration date.

– The initial investment is CL − CH.

– The maximum profit is (XH − XL) − (CL − CH).

∗ When both are exercised at expiration.

– The maximum loss is CL − CH.

∗ When neither is exercised at expiration.

– If we buy (XH − XL)−1 units of the bull call spread and XH − XL → 0, a (Heaviside) step function

emerges as the payoff.

(10)

85 90 95 100 105 110Stock price Bull spread (call)

-4 -2 2 4 Profit

(11)

Covered Position: Spread (continued)

• Writing an XH put and buying an XL put with identical expiration date creates the bull put spread.

• A bear spread amounts to selling a bull spread.

• It profits from declining stock prices.

• Three calls or three puts with different strike prices and the same expiration date create a butterfly spread.

– The spread is long one XL call, long one XH call, and short two XM calls.

(12)

85 90 95 100 105 110Stock price Butterfly

-1 1 2 3 Profit

Note: The aspect ratio of the plot is far from 1.

(13)

Covered Position: Spread (continued)

• A butterfly spread pays a positive amount at expiration only if the asset price falls between XL and XH.

• Take a position in (XM − XL)−1 units of the butterfly spread.

• When XH − XL → 0, it approximates a state contingent claim,a which pays $1 only when the state S = XM

happens.b

aAlternatively, Arrow security.

bSee Exercise 7.4.5 of the textbook.

(14)

Covered Position: Spread (concluded)

• The price of a state contingent claim is called a state price.

• The state price equals

2C

∂X2 .

– Recall that C is the call’s price.a

• In fact, the FV of ∂2C/∂X2 is the probability (density) of the stock price ST = X at option’s maturity.b

aOne can also use the put (see Exercise 9.3.6 of the textbook).

bBreeden and Litzenberger (1978).

(15)

Covered Position: Combination

• A combination consists of options of different types on the same underlying asset.

– These options must be either all bought or all written.

• Straddle: A long call and a long put with the same strike price and expiration date.

– Since it profits from high volatility, a person who buys a straddle is said to be long volatility.

– Selling a straddle benefits from low volatility.

(16)

85 90 95 100 105 110Stock price Straddle

-5 -2.5 2.5 5 7.5 10 Profit

(17)

Covered Position: Combination (concluded)

• Strangle: Identical to a straddle except that the call’s strike price is higher than the put’s.

(18)

85 90 95 100 105 110Stock price Strangle

-2 2 4 6 8 10 Profit

(19)

Arbitrage in Option Pricing

(20)

All general laws are attended with inconveniences, when applied to particular cases.

— David Hume (1711–1776)

(21)

Arbitrage

• The no-arbitrage principle says there is no free lunch.

• It supplies the argument for option pricing.

• A riskless arbitrage opportunity is one that, without any initial investment, generates nonnegative returns under all circumstances and positive returns under some.

• In an efficient market, such opportunities do not exist (for long).

(22)

Portfolio Dominance Principle

• Consider two portfolios A and B.

• A should be more valuable than B if A’s payoff is at least as good as B’s under all circumstances and better under some.

(23)

Two Simple Corollaries

• A portfolio yielding a zero return in every possible scenario must have a zero PV.

– Short the portfolio if its PV is positive.

– Buy it if its PV is negative.

– In both cases, a free lunch is created.

• Two portfolios that yield the same return in every possible scenario must have the same price.a

aAristotle, “those who are equal should have everything alike.”

(24)

The PV Formula (p. 35) Justified

Theorem 1 For a certain cash flow C1, C2, . . . , Cn, P =

n i=1

Cid(i).

• Suppose the price P < P .

• Short the n zeros that match the security’s n cash flows.

• The proceeds are P dollars.

(25)

6 6 6 6 -

C1 C2 C3

· · · Cn

? ? ? ?

C1 C2 C3

· · ·

Cn

6

P P?

 security

 zeros

(26)

The Proof (concluded)

• Then use P of the proceeds to buy the security.

• The cash inflows of the security will offset exactly the obligations of the zeros.

• A riskless profit of P − P dollars has been realized now.

• If P > P , just reverse the trades.

(27)

One More Example

Theorem 2 A put or a call must have a nonnegative value.

• Suppose otherwise and the option has a negative price.

• Buy the option for a positive cash flow now.

• It will end up with a nonnegative amount at expiration.

• So an arbitrage profit is realized now.

(28)

Relative Option Prices

• These relations hold regardless of the model for stock prices.

• Assume, among other things, that there are no

transactions costs or margin requirements, borrowing and lending are available at the riskless interest rate, interest rates are nonnegative, and there are no

arbitrage opportunities.

• Let the current time be time zero.

• PV(x) stands for the PV of x dollars at expiration.

• Hence PV(x) = xd(τ) where τ is the time to

(29)

Put-Call Parity

a

C = P + S − PV(X). (27)

• Consider the portfolio of:

– One short European call;

– One long European put;

– One share of stock;

– A loan of PV(X).

• All options are assumed to carry the same strike price X and time to expiration, τ .

• The initial cash flow is therefore

(30)

The Proof (continued)

• At expiration, if the stock price Sτ ≤ X, the put will be worth X − Sτ and the call will expire worthless.

• The loan is now X.

• The net future cash flow is zero:

0 + (X − Sτ) + Sτ − X = 0.

• On the other hand, if Sτ > X, the call will be worth Sτ − X and the put will expire worthless.

• The net future cash flow is again zero:

−(Sτ − X) + 0 + Sτ − X = 0.

(31)

The Proof (concluded)

• The net future cash flow is zero in either case.

• The no-arbitrage principle (p. 203) implies that the initial investment to set up the portfolio must be nil as well.

(32)

Consequences of Put-Call Parity

• There is only one kind of European option (p. 209).

– The other can be replicated from it in combination with stock and riskless lending or borrowing.

– Combinations such as this create synthetic securities.

• S = C − P + PV(X): A stock is equivalent to a portfolio containing a long call, a short put, and lending PV(X).

• C − P = S − PV(X): A long call and a short put

amount to a long position in stock and borrowing the PV of the strike price (buying stock on margin).

(33)

Intrinsic Value

Lemma 3 An American call or a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock is never worth less than its intrinsic value.

• An American call cannot be worth less than its intrinsic value.a

• For European options, the put-call parity implies C = (S − X) + (X − PV(X)) + P ≥ S − X.

• Recall C ≥ 0 (p. 207).

• It follows that C ≥ max(S − X, 0), the intrinsic value.

(34)

Intrinsic Value (concluded)

A European put on a non-dividend-paying stock may be worth less than its intrinsic value.

Lemma 4 For European puts, P ≥ max(PV(X) − S, 0).

• Prove it with the put-call parity.a

• Can explain the right figure on p. 180 why P < X − S when S is small.

aSee Lemma 8.3.2 of the textbook.

(35)

Early Exercise of American Calls

European calls and American calls are identical when the underlying stock pays no dividends.

Theorem 5 (Merton (1973)) An American call on a non-dividend-paying stock should not be exercised before expiration.

• By Exercise 8.3.2 of the text, C ≥ max(S − PV(X), 0).

• If the call is exercised, the value is S − X.

• But

max(S − PV(X), 0) ≥ S − X.

(36)

Remarks

• The above theorem does not mean American calls should be kept until maturity.

• What it does imply is that when early exercise is being considered, a better alternative is to sell it.

• Early exercise may become optimal for American calls on a dividend-paying stock, however.

– Stock price declines as the stock goes ex-dividend.

– And recall that we assume options are unprotected.

(37)

Early Exercise of American Calls: Dividend Case

Surprisingly, an American call should be exercised only at a few dates.a

Theorem 6 An American call will only be exercised at expiration or just before an ex-dividend date.

In contrast, it might be optimal to exercise an American put even if the underlying stock does not pay dividends.

aSee Theorem 8.4.2 of the textbook.

(38)

A General Result

a

Theorem 7 (Cox and Rubinstein (1985)) Any

piecewise linear payoff function can be replicated using a portfolio of calls and puts.

Corollary 8 Any sufficiently well-behaved payoff function can be approximated by a portfolio of calls and puts.

aSee Exercise 8.3.6 of the textbook.

(39)

Convexity of Option Prices

a

Lemma 9 For three otherwise identical calls or puts with strike prices X1 < X2 < X3,

CX2 ≤ ωCX1 + (1 − ω) CX3

PX2 ≤ ωPX1 + (1 − ω) PX3

Here

ω ≡ (X3 − X2)/(X3 − X1).

(Equivalently, X2 = ωX1 + (1 − ω) X3.)

aSee Lemma 8.5.1 of the textbook.

(40)

Option on a Portfolio vs. Portfolio of Options

• Consider a portfolio of non-dividend-paying assets with weights ωi.

• Let Ci denote the price of a European call on asset i with strike price Xi.

• All options expire on the same date.

(41)

Option on a Portfolio vs. Portfolio of Options (concluded)

An option on a portfolio is cheaper than a portfolio of options.a

Theorem 10 The call on the portfolio with a strike price

X ≡ 

i

ωiXi has a value at most 

i

ωiCi. The same holds for European puts.

(42)

Option Pricing Models

(43)

If the world of sense does not fit mathematics, so much the worse for the world of sense.

— Bertrand Russell (1872–1970)

Black insisted that anything one could do with a mouse could be done better with macro redefinitions of particular keys on the keyboard.

— Emanuel Derman, My Life as a Quant (2004)

(44)

The Setting

• The no-arbitrage principle is insufficient to pin down the exact option value.

• Need a model of probabilistic behavior of stock prices.

• One major obstacle is that it seems a risk-adjusted interest rate is needed to discount the option’s payoff.

• Breakthrough came in 1973 when Black (1938–1995) and Scholes with help from Merton published their celebrated option pricing model.a

– Known as the Black-Scholes option pricing model.

aThe results were obtained as early as June 1969. Merton and Scholes

(45)

Terms and Approach

• C: call value.

• P : put value.

• X: strike price

• S: stock price

• ˆr > 0: the continuously compounded riskless rate per period.

• R ≡ eˆr: gross return.

• Start from the discrete-time binomial model.

(46)

Binomial Option Pricing Model (BOPM)

• Time is discrete and measured in periods.

• If the current stock price is S, it can go to Su with probability q and Sd with probability 1 − q, where 0 < q < 1 and d < u.

– In fact, d < R < u must hold to rule out arbitrage.a

• Six pieces of information will suffice to determine the option value based on arbitrage considerations:

S, u, d, X, ˆr, and the number of periods to expiration.

aSee Exercise 9.2.1 of the textbook.

(47)

S

Su q

1 q

Sd

(48)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period

• The expiration date is only one period from now.

• Cu is the call price at time 1 if the stock price moves to Su.

• Cd is the call price at time 1 if the stock price moves to Sd.

• Clearly,

Cu = max(0, Su − X), Cd = max(0, Sd − X).

(49)

C

Cu= max( 0, Su X ) q

1 q

Cd = max( 0, Sd X )

(50)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period (continued)

• Set up a portfolio of h shares of stock and B dollars in riskless bonds.

– This costs hS + B.

– We call h the hedge ratio or delta.

• The value of this portfolio at time one is hSu + RB, up move,

hSd + RB, down move.

(51)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period (continued)

• Choose h and B such that the portfolio replicates the payoff of the call,

hSu + RB = Cu, hSd + RB = Cd.

(52)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period (concluded)

• Solve the above equations to obtain h = Cu − Cd

Su − Sd ≥ 0, (28)

B = uCd − dCu

(u − d) R . (29)

• By the no-arbitrage principle, the European call should cost the same as the equivalent portfolio,a

C = hS + B.

• As uCd − dCu < 0, the equivalent portfolio is a levered long position in stocks.

(53)

American Call Pricing in One Period

• Have to consider immediate exercise.

• C = max(hS + B, S − X).

– When hS + B ≥ S − X, the call should not be exercised immediately.

– When hS + B < S − X, the option should be exercised immediately.

• For non-dividend-paying stocks, early exercise is not optimal by Theorem 5 (p. 215).

• So

(54)

Put Pricing in One Period

• Puts can be similarly priced.

• The delta for the put is (Pu − Pd)/(Su − Sd) ≤ 0, where Pu = max(0, X − Su),

Pd = max(0, X − Sd).

• Let B = uP(u−d) Rd−dPu.

• The European put is worth hS + B.

• The American put is worth max(hS + B, X − S).

– Early exercise is always possible with American puts.

(55)

Risk

• Surprisingly, the option value is independent of q.a

• Hence it is independent of the expected gross return of the stock, qSu + (1 − q) Sd.

• It therefore does not directly depend on investors’ risk preferences.

• The option value depends on the sizes of price changes, u and d, which the investors must agree upon.

• Then the set of possible stock prices is the same whatever q is.

aMore precisely, not directly dependent on q. Thanks to a lively class

(56)

Pseudo Probability

• After substitution and rearrangement,

hS + B =

R−d u−d



Cu +

u−R u−d

 Cd

R .

• Rewrite it as

hS + B = pCu + (1 − p) Cd

R ,

where

p ≡ R − d

u − d . (30)

• As 0 < p < 1, it may be interpreted as a probability.

(57)

Risk-Neutral Probability

• The expected rate of return for the stock is equal to the riskless rate ˆr under p as

pSu + (1 − p) Sd = RS. (31)

• The expected rates of return of all securities must be the riskless rate when investors are risk-neutral.

• For this reason, p is called the risk-neutral probability.

• The value of an option is the expectation of its

discounted future payoff in a risk-neutral economy.

• So the rate used for discounting the FV is the riskless

參考文獻

相關文件

• The XYZ.com bonds are equivalent to a default-free zero-coupon bond with $X par value plus n written European puts on Merck at a strike price of $30.. – By the

Lemma 2 An American call or a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock is never worth less than its intrinsic value.. • An American call cannot be worth less than its

• The XYZ.com bonds are equivalent to a default-free zero-coupon bond with $X par value plus n written European puts on Merck at a strike price of $30.. – By the

• A call gives its holder the right to buy a number of the underlying asset by paying a strike price.. • A put gives its holder the right to sell a number of the underlying asset

• The existence of different implied volatilities for options on the same underlying asset shows the Black-Scholes model cannot be literally true.

Note: Automatic variables are allocated within the stack frames.

 If I buy a call option from you, I am paying you a certain amount of money in return for the right to force you to sell me a share of the stock, if I want it, at the strike price,

Data larger than memory but smaller than disk Design algorithms so that disk access is less frequent An example (Yu et al., 2010): a decomposition method to load a block at a time