• 沒有找到結果。

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

22

and the output will not start to increase until the fifth period, then gradually rise until the policy is realized. After the policy is revealed, the output will rise at a faster pace.

5.4 Case 4: The tariff reduction is realized unexpectedly (news is unrealized or is realized at the size higher or lower than expectation)

There can be various frictions during the negotiation which may delay the process or even result in the failure. Therefore, we simulate various scenarios: (1) Negotiation fails and thus the government cannot meet people’s expectation. The result is listed in figure 6. (2) Although the contract is signed in the end, but the magnitude of tariff decrement is much lower than household’s expectation. The result is listed in figure 7. The results are quite intuitive. When the news is just announced, the two scenarios follow the same path, but move differently when the outcome of negotiation is realized. In the first case, the output does not rise above zero. Thus, the economy suffers the negative impact of news, but does not get any benefits. In the second case, the economic expansion is weaker if the realized tariff reduction is smaller than expectation, compared to that under the full realization.

6. Conclusion

This paper analyzes the effect on macroeconomic variables when the government announces the news on a tariff decrement since the negotiation of FTA starts. With a small-open-economy DSGE model, we examine various cases that the outcome of negotiation is consistent with people’s expectation. The news may affect people’s behavior by changing their expectation. We focus on the short run effects, to analyze the period between announcement and implement. The results show that the news does not generate positive effect, but negative in the

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

23

short run, because people tend to postpone their consumption and investment when the tariff reduction leads to lower import prices. The positive effect of tariff reduction will not occur until the tariff reduction is realized as expected. If the negotiation takes longer or the realized tariff reduction is smaller than expectation, the negative effect may last longer, followed by smaller or zero positive effects. The aggregate effects of tariff news in long run may affect the welfare.

To evaluate its effects on the welfare, this model can be extended into one which focuses on welfare comparison. Another interesting issue remains for the future research is to examine the tariff news in an extended three country model to take into account the effects of the free trade agreement between two countries on the third country which is not included.

Brock, P. L., 1986. “Permanent and Temporary Tariff Reductions”. Unpublished Working Paper.

Beaudry, P., Portier, F., 2006. “Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations”. The American Economic Review, Vol.96, No. 4, pp.1293–1307.

Beaudry, P., Portier, F., 2007. “When can changes in expectations cause business cycle fluctuations in neo-classical settings ? ”. Journal of Economic Theory, Vol.135, pp.458 – 477.

Calvo, G., 1983. “Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework”. Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol.12, pp.383–398.

Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M., 1999. “The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective”. Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 37, pp.1661–1707.

Eichengreen, B.J., 1981. “A dynamic model of tariffs, output, and employment under flexible exchange rate”. Journal of International Economics, Vol.11, pp.341–359.

Fender, J. and Yip, C., 2000. “Tariffs and exchange rate dynamics redux”. Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol 19, pp.633–655.

Fujiwara, I., Hirose, Y. and Shintani, M., 2011. “Can news be a major source of aggregate fluctuations? A Bayesian DSGE approach”. Journal of Money, Credit & Banking, Vol.43(1), pp.1(28).

Gali, J., Monacelli, T., 2000. “Optimal monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy”. Working Paper, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Boston College.

Ganelli, G., Tervala, J., 2015. “Value of WTO trade agreements in a New Keynesian Model”.

International Monetary Fund WP/15/37.

Guido L., 2011. “News and aggregate demand shocks”. Annual review of economic, pp.537–557.

Guo, J.T., Sirbu, A,I. and Weder, M., 2015. “News about aggregate demand and the business cycle”. Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol.72, pp.83(14).

Hooper, P., Marquez, J., 1995. “Exchange rates, prices, and external adjustment in the United States and Japan”. In: Kenen, P. (Ed.), Understanding Interdependence. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp.107–168.

Hwang, Y.N., Turnovsky, S.J., 2013. “Exchange rate pass-through and the effects of tariffs on economic performance and welfare”. Journal of International Money and Finance.

Jaimovich, N., Rebelo, S., 2009. “Can news about the future drive the business cycle?”.

American Economic Review, Vol.99:4, pp.1097–1118.

Konan, D.E., Maskus, K.E., 2000. “Joint trade liberalization and tax reform in a small open economy: the case of Egypt”. Journal of Development Economics, Vol.61, pp.365–392.

College Dublin and IMF.

Lopez, S. D., 2000. Work in progress, Bank of Spain.

Martins, J., Scarpetta, S., Pilat, D., 1996. “Mark-up pricing, market structure and the business cycle”. OECD Economic Studies, Vol 27, pp.71–105.

Mundell, R., 1961. “Flexible exchange rates and employment policy”. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, Vol.27, pp.509–517.

Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K., 1995. “Exchange rate dynamics redux”. Journal of Political Economy, Vol.103, pp.624-660.

Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K., 2000. “ New directions for stochastic open economy models”.

Journal of International Economics, Vol.50, pp.117-153.

Wang. P., 2012. “Understanding expectation-driven fluctuations: a labor-market approach”.

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 44, No. 2-3 Pigou, A.C., (1926), “Industrial Fluctuations”, MacMillan, London.

Reitz, S., Slopek, Q.D., 2005. “Macroeconomic effects of tariffs: Insights from a New Open Economy Macroeconomics Model”. Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, Vol. 141 (2), pp.285–311.

Kollmann, R., 2001a. “The exchange rate in a dynamic-optimizing business cycle model with nominal rigidities: a quantitative investigation”. Journal of International Economics, Vol.55, pp.243–262.

Kollmann, R., 2002. “Monetary policy rules in the open economy: effects on welfare and business cycles”. Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol.49, pp.989–1015.

Rotemberg, J., Woodford, M., 1997. “An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy”. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol.12, pp.297–346.

Sen, P., Turnovsky, S.J., 1989. “Tariffs, capital accumulation, and the current account in a small open economy”. International Economic Review, Vol.30, pp.811–831.

Sims, C., 2000. “Second order accurate solution of discrete time dynamic equilibrium models”.

Working paper, Economics Department, Princeton University.

Stéphane, A., Paul G. and Shen G., 2013. “Nominal rigidities, monetary policy and pigou cycles “. The Economic Journal, Vol.123, pp.455–473.

Taylor, J., 1993a. “Discretion versus policy rules in practice”. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39, pp.195–214.

Taylor, J., 1993b. “Macroeconomic Policy in a World Economy”. Norton, New York.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

26

Table

Table 1: The implication of various realization of tariff news (We only discuss the situation of enter FTA, so t is always greater than zero)

Different combination of shocks Implications

t 0

  t 0 Anticipated tariff adjustment

t 0

  t 0 Expectation full realized

t 0

  0t  t Expectation partially realized

t 0

  t  t Expectation not realized at all

t 0

  t 0 Adjustment more than expectation

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

27

Table 2: Calibrated Parameter

Parameter Value Description

r 0.01 Capital return

1 1.01 Subjective discount factor

m 0.3 Share of import goods use in final goods production

d 1m Share of domestic goods use in final goods production

0.6 Price elasticities of aggregate import

0.6 Price elasticities of aggregate export

v 6 Price-marginal markup composition

0.75 Probability of price resetting

0.0019 Capital mobility

0.24 Technology parameter for labor share

0.025 Depreciation rate

15 Capital adjustment cost

X * 0.27 Export demand multiplier

0.17 Import tariff

* 0.17 Export tariff

e 1 Nominal exchange rate

A 0.9 Lasting degree of last period of TFP

A 0.01 Volatility of TFP

* 0.8 Lasting degree of last period of world price

* 0.005 Volatility of world price

i 0.75 Lasting degree of last period of world interest rate

i 0.004 Volatility of world interest rate Inflation 1 Price growth factor

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

28

Figure

12

Figure 1: Unanticipated tariff shock in period 4 (decrease by 0.05)

12 The figures of impose response function here are measure in the level deviation from the steady state. To see the percentage change, the number should be multiplied by 100.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

29

Figure 2: Anticipated tariff news shock (decrease 0.05 after 4 period)

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

30

Figure 3: Anticipated tariff news shock (decrease 0.05 after 1 period)

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

31

Figure 4: Anticipated tariff news shock (decrease 0.05 after 8 period)

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

32

Figure 5: Anticipated tariff news shock (realize at one year postponed)

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

33

Figure 6: Anticipated tariff news shock (unrealized)

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

34

Figure 7: Anticipated tariff news shock lower expectation (news: decrease 0.05 after 4 period, real: 0.03)

Appendix A: Value function

To let coding in dynare be possible, we have to transfer the form summation into the form of value. To associate with the conversion of real variables later, the computation combines both conversion of real variables and value function can refer as following

 

Multiplying both side with denominator, as substitute the t td, into original form

 

Converting into real variables (dividing with P ) t

 

Setting the value function, we can rename LHS as value function m(.)and RHS asn(t),

 

of value functions

  

Appendix B: Converting into real variables

First of all, we have to summarize our model, and we can solve 40 endogenous variables with 40 equations.

Equations (11.-19.) are already in terms of real variables.

And for the conversion into real variables, we let

d

Equations in terms of real variables can be expressed as following

1. . 1

Appendix C: Solving the steady state

In order describe the path of steady state, we have to obtain the initial value which we assume the economy is in steady state.

First, we assume

* * * * 1 *

1, , , d m x 1, f 1, 1, 0

q        i i i A b b

                  ,

as what we discuss in chapter 3.9.

Then we can derived the steady state as following 1. mc

相關文件