• 沒有找到結果。

4.2 Merger Profitability and Partial Privatization

4.2.4 Incentives for Mergers

In an international mixed oligopoly market, there exist one domestic public firm with partial privatization, one domestic private firm and several private foreign firms. Public firm has more incentives to merge because of social welfare improving, namely, social welfare

after merging is better than both the social welfare of pre-merger and of direct privatization.

Lemma 4.2: Post-merger social welfare is the best; the social welfare of no privatization is worst.

Therefore, public firm have to please to merge and when domestic firm’s readiness to merge.

For domestic private owner who would like to merge with the public firm, only if, the fraction of that private owner owns profits of the mixed firm after merging, ( )

a b

M M

δ π +π , is higher enough than the profit obtained by domestic private firm before merging, πb. Therefore, for any mN there exist δΓ∈(0,1)which denotes the value of the degree of privatization such that ( )

a b

With the proceeding of privatization, domestic private owner choose to merge with public firm when δ δ> Γ.18

18 See the proof of proposition 2 in Méndez-Naya (2008).

Proposition 4.2: In an international differentiated mixed oligopoly, domestic private firm decide to merge with public firm when ( )

a b

The ambiguous comparison is subject to both the differentiated degree of commodity and numbers of foreign private firm.

Proposition 4.2 is illustrated in Fig 4.2.

-1

Fig 4.2. Private Firm’s Incentives to Merge Region I and III represent δ δ− Γ >0, that is, ( )

a

M M

b b

δ π +π >π . In other words, the nature of commodity and number of foreign firm could influence private owner’s incentives to merge. When products are substitutes, the private owner chooses to merge in region I.

Identically, when products are complementary, the private owner chooses to merge in region III. In general, more foreign private firms competing in the domestic market will promote private owner’s merging decision. The degree of substitution of commodity which is too higher or lower would not influence private owner’s decision. Higher degree of complement

γ II I m

III

δ δ Γ=0

δ δ Γ =0

of commodity promotes private owner’s merging decision.

Proposition 4.3: In general, more foreign private firms and higher degree of complement of commodity will promote private owner’s merging decision. The degree of substitution of commodity which is too higher or lower cannot be incentives for private owner to merge.

4.3 Concluding Remarks

This chapter considered that there exist one domestic public firm, one domestic private firm and several private foreign firms in an international mixed oligopoly market. To be more efficient, the public firm allowed for partial privatization and through a program with two distinct measures, privatizing directly, or deciding to merge with domestic private firm.

Under the utility assumption of differentiated commodity in Häckner (2000), we found whether public firm merger with domestic private firm or not, the optimal privatization policy is monotonic in the differentiated degree of character of commodities; the degree of privatization is monotonically increasing with the more the number of foreign private firm entry.

Moreover, there exist some incentives for domestic firm to choose to merge. For public firm, the incentives are explicit because of welfare improving. For private owner, generally, more foreign private firms and higher degree of complement of commodity will promote private owner’s merging decision. The degree of substitution of commodity which is too higher or lower cannot be incentives for private owner to merge.

CHAPTER FIVE: CONCLUSIONS

The government has more policy choices. We considered the issues of public policy-environmental taxation, equity control on foreign competitors, and merger for partial privatization-in an international mixed oligopoly. Based on the studies of environmental taxation in Lai (2004) and Ohori (2006), welfare model in Fjell and Pal (1996), partial privatization with differentiated commodity in Fujiwara (2007) and merger profitability in Méndez-Naya (2008), we extended the past results to be more completed by apt models.

For environmental taxation, using the simple linear demand model, part of our findings are consistent with what has been shown in Lai (2004) and Ohori (2006), even though they considered all firms producing homogeneous goods. In an international oligopoly market wherein the environmental damage is associated with consumption, the order of optimal environmental tax parallels the results of the duopoly model irrespective of the properties of the goods. In addition, we have shown that when the domestic market increases its openings, the tariff reduction does not always bring positive effects on the environment in mixed oligopoly; but, in pure oligopoly with homogeneous goods, the tariff reduction is bad for the environment.

For equity control, we considered in an international oligopoly market with a homogeneous good, one partially privatized domestic public firm competes with n domestic private firms and m foreign private firms. To protect domestic firms in this single market, the government determines the proportion of domestic equity on foreign competitors.

We have shown that stringent control of domestic equity on foreign firms increases private firms’ outputs, profits, market price and social welfare, but decreases public firm’s output.

Furthermore, along with the stringent control on the domestic equity of foreign firms, the government should increase the degree of privatization. In an opening market, intensive competition from private firms in general will enhance the degree of privatization.

Comparing our results with the result in Fjell and Pal (1996), we found that the effect of the number of foreign firms on public firm’s profit is ambiguous. Public firm’s profit increases if and only if the number of foreign private firms is small relative to the number of domestic private firms; social welfare increases if and only if the number of foreign private firms is large relative to the number of domestic private firms.

For merger for partial privatization, we considered that there exist one domestic public firm, one domestic private firm and several private foreign firms in an international mixed oligopoly market. To be more efficient, the public firm allowed for partial privatization and through a program with two distinct measures, privatizing directly, or deciding to merge with domestic private firm. Under the utility assumption of differentiated commodity in Häckner (2000), we found whether public firm merger with domestic private firm or not, the optimal privatization policy is monotonic in the differentiated degree of character of commodities; the degree of privatization is monotonically increasing with the more the number of foreign private firm entry.

Moreover, there exist some incentives for domestic firm to choose to merge. For public firm, the incentives are explicit because of welfare improving. For private owner, generally, more foreign private firms and higher degree of complement of commodity will promote private owner’s merging decision. The degree of substitution of commodity which is too higher or lower cannot be incentives for private owner to merge.

REFERENCES

Anderson, K., 1992, The Standard Welfare Economics of Policies Affecting Trade and the Environment, in The Greening of World Trade Issue by K. Anderson and R.

Blackhurst, Eds., Harvester Wheatsheaf: New York, 25-48.

Bárcena-Ruiz, J.C., and M.B. Garzón, 2003, Mixed Duopoly, Merger and Multi-product Firms, Journal of Economics, 80(11), 27–42.

Beladi, H. and C.C. Chao, 2006, Mixed Ownership, Unemployment, and Welfare for a Developing Economy, Review of Development Economics, 10(4), 604-611.

Bön, D., 1997, Privatization and Development, Review of Development Economics, 1(3), 337-354.

Chakrabarti, A. and J.S. Heywood, 2004, Foreign Investment, Vertical Integration, and Local Equity Requirements, Economica, 71, 559-574.

Chao, C.C. and E.S.H. Yu, 2000, Domestic Equity Controls of Multinational Enterprises, The Manchester School, 68, 321−330.

Chao, C.C. and E.S.H. Yu, 2006, Partial Privatization, Foreign Competition, and Optimum Tariff, Review of International Economics, 14(1), 87-92.

Chao, C.C. and E.S.H. Yu, 2007, Trade Liberalization, Foreign Ownership, and Environment in a Small Open Economy, International Review of Economics and Finance, 16, 471-477.

Chang, W.W., 2005, Optimal Trade and Privatization Policies in an International Duopoly with Cost Asymmetry, Journal of International trade and Economic Development, 14, 19-42.

Coloma, G.., 2006, Mergers and Acquisitions in Mixed Oligopoly Markets, International Journal of Business and Economics, 5(2), 147-159.

Creane, A., and C. Davidson, 2004, Multidivisional Firms, Internal Competition, and the Merger Paradox, Canadian Journal of Economics, 37(4), 951–977

Cremer, H., M. Marchand, and J. F. Thisse, 1989, The Public Firm as an Instrument for Regulating an Oligopolistic Market, Oxford Economic Papers, 41, 283-301.

Dadpay, A. and J.S. Heywood, 2006, Mixed Oligopoly in a Single International Market, Australian Economic Papers, 45(4), 269-280.

De Fraja, G.. and F. Delbono, 1989, Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly, Oxford Economic Papers, 41, 302-311.

Escrihuela-Villar, M., and R. Faulí-Oller, 2008, Mergers in Asymmetric Stackelberg markets, Spanish Economic Review, forthcoming.

Faulí-Oller, R., 2002, Mergers between Asymmetric Firms: Profitability and Welfare, Manchaster School, 70(1), 77–87.

Fershtman, C., 1990, The Interdependence between Ownership Status and Market Structure:

The Case of Privatization, Economica, vol. 57, pp. 319-328.

Fjell, K., and J. Heywood, 2002, Public Stackelberg Leadership in a Mixed Oligopoly with Foreign Firm, Australian Economic Papers, 41, 267-281.

Fjell, K. and J.S. Heywood, 2004, Mixed Oligopoly, Subsidization and the Order of Firm’s Move: The Relevance of Privatization, Economics Letters, 83, 411-416.

Fjell, K. and D. Pal, 1996, A Mixed Oligopoly in the Presence of Foreign Private Firms, Canadian Journal of Economics, 29, 737-743.

Fujiwara, K., 2007, Partial Privatization in a Differentiated Mixed Oligopoly, Journal of Economics, 92(1), 51–65.

González-Maestre, M.A., and J. López-Cuñat, 2001, Delegation and Mergers in Oligopoly, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19(8), 1263–1279.

Häckner, J., 2000, A Note on Price and Quantity Competition in Differentiated Oligopolies, Journal of Economic Theory, 93, 233-239.

Heywood, J.S. and M. McGinty, 2008, Leading and Merging: Convex Costs, Stackelberg, and the Merger Paradox, Southern Economic Journal, 74(3), 879-893.

Hill, J. K. and J.A. Mendez, 1992, Equity Control of Multinational Firms by Less Developed Countries: A General Equilibrium Analysis, The Manchester School, 60, 53−63.

Hindriks, J. and D. Claude, 2006, Strategic Privatization and Regulation Policy in Mixed Markets, The Icfai Journal of Managerial Economics, 4(1), 7-26.

Huck, S. and K. Konard, 2004, Merger Profitability and Trade Policy, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(1), 107-122.

Krutilla, K., 1991, Environmental Regulation in an Open Economy, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 20, 127-142.

Lai, Y. B., 2004, Trade Liberalization, Consumption Externalities and the Environment, Economics Bulletin, 17(5), 1-9.

Lai, Y. B., and C. H. Hu, 2005, Trade Liberalization and Transboundary Pollution, Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, 7, 1-14.

Lee, S.H. and H.S. Hwang, 2003, Partial Ownership for the Public Firm and Competition, The Japanese Economic Review, 54(3), 324-335.

Matsumura, T., 1998, Partial Privatization in Mixed Duopoly, Journal of Public Economics, 70, 473-483.

Matsumura, T., and O. Kanda, 2005, Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets, Journal of Economics, 84(1), 27–48.

Méndez-Naya, J., 2008, Merger Profitability in Mixed Oligopoly, Journal of Economics, forthcoming.

Metcalfe, M. R., and J. C. Beghin, 1997, Piecemeal Reform of Trade and Environmental Policy When Consumption Also Pollutes, Working paper, North Carolina State

University.

Norbäck, P-J and L. Persson, 2005, Privatization Policy in an International Oligopoly, Economica, 72, 635-653.

Norman, G., L. Pepall, and D. Richards, 2005, Product Differentiation, Cost-reducing Mergers, and Consumer Welfare, Canadian Journal of Economics, 38(4), 1204-1223.

Ohori, S., 2006, Trade Liberalization, Consumption Externalities and the Environment: A Mixed Duopoly Approach, Economics Bulletin, 17(5), 1-9.

Ottaviano, G., T. Tabuchi, and J. Thisse, 2002, Agglomeration and Trade Revisited, International Economic Review, 43, 409-436.

Pal, D., and M. D. White, 1998, Mixed Oligopoly, Privatization, and Strategic Trade Policy, Southern Economic Journal, 65, 264-281.

Pepall, L., D. Richards, and G. Norman, 1999, Industrial Organization: Contemporary Theory and Practice. Cincinnati: South-Western College Publishing

Sepahvand, M. and R. Cornes, 2007, Ownership versus Timing of the Game, Australian Economic Papers, 46(4), 305-314.

Serizawa, N., 2000, Optimal Trade Policy in an International Mixed Oligopoly, Seoul Journal of Economics, 13(2), 107-122.

Singh, N., and X. Vives, 1984, Price and Quantity Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly, RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 546-554.

Vives, X., 2001, Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Walz, U., and D. Wellisch, 1997, Is Free Trade in the Interest of Exporting Countries when There is Ecological Dumping? Journal of Public Economics, 66, 275-291.

Wang, L.F.S., Y.C. Wang, and T.L. Chen, 2007, Trade Liberalization and Environmental Tax in Differentiated Oligopoly with Consumption Externalities, Economics Bulletin, 17(8), 1-9.

Zhao, L.X., 2000, Decentralization and Trade Pricing Under Oligopoly, Southern Economic Journal, 67(2), 414-426.

Ziss, S., 2001, Horizontal Mergers and Delegation, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 471-492.

APPENDIX A

A.1 Pure Oligopoly with Homogeneous Goods

Under the Cournot-Nash assumption, we obtain the following first-order conditions,

0 0 0

p c− − +t p q′ = , and (A.1.1)

f i 0

p c− − − +t τ p q′ = , 1, 2,...,i= n. (A.1.2)

Having obtained the results, we then differentiate social welfare equation with respect to t ,

The optimal environmental tax,

*

A.2 Mixed Oligopoly with Homogeneous Goods

Under the Cournot-Nash assumption, we obtain the following first-order conditions,

0

Then differentiating social welfare equation with respect to t , it yields

0

The optimal environmental tax,

( 0 )

1

M n c cf r

t = +θ n

+ . (A.2.4)

APPENDIX B

We follow Lai’s (2004) basic set-up but assume the linear inverse demand function is

0

= − −

. Differentiating domestic and foreign firms’ total profits with respect to their own output, we obtain the following first-order conditions,

0 0

Then, the outputs are given by

0 0

The optimal environmental tax is

If all firms produce homogeneous goods, letτ =1, the optimal output and environmental tax are

APPENDIX C

Consider in an international oligopoly market, one domestic public firm (firm 0), n private firms (firm i ; i=1, 2,...,n) and m foreign private firm (firm j ; j=1, 2,...,m) compete. The public firm does not proceed to privatize, e.g. θ =0. All private firms simultaneously maximize their own profits to choose their quantity, while the privatized public firm maximizes social welfare, equation (1), to choose its quantity. We then obtain

* Then the effects of equity control,

*

The effects of an open-door policy

If the public firm competes only with foreign private firms (n=0), then entry by a new foreign firm always increases welfare,

* 2

相關文件