• 沒有找到結果。

Evaluating multi-criteria ratings of financial investment options

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Evaluating multi-criteria ratings of financial investment options"

Copied!
13
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Evaluating multi-criteria ratings of

financial investment options

Andrew N.K. Chen

a

, Shin-Yun Wang

b,

, Po-Lung Yu

c

a

Accounting and Information Systems, University of Kansas, 1300 Sunnyside Ave, Lawrence, KS 66045-7585, United States b

Department of Finance, National Dong Hwa University, No. 1, Sec. 2, Da Hsueh Rd., Shoufeng, Hualien 97401, Taiwan cInstitute of Information Management, National Chiao Tung University, Hsin Chu, Taiwan

a r t i c l e i n f o

a b s t r a c t

Article history: Received 14 May 2013

Received in revised form 12 December 2013 Accepted 13 December 2013

Available online 31 December 2013

In the financial market, most available rating information is based on multi-criteria and published by myriad agents or companies. Given a multi-criteria rating report on a finite number of assets (e.g., stocks, bonds, mutual funds), we can construct sets of ordered classes. If ratings from a published report have useful and valid information value as claimed, the average performances of assets within classes are expected to show some monotonic property. A set of hypotheses and empirical tests based on Value Line Mutual Fund Survey are provided to illustrate our proposed method. Implications and future research opportunities are also discussed.

© 2013 Published by Elsevier Inc. Keywords:

Multiple criterion ratings Information quality Implied ordered classes

1. Introduction

Investors (e.g., individuals, portfolio and fund managers, investment bank managers) who make investment decisions often encounter numerous ratings and reports of investment options including stocks, bonds, mutual funds, and derivatives. These investors often naively trust and use whatever available or familiar information to support their decision making without systematically judging the quality of information and the validity of intended interpretation of information. They simply assume that these ratings are of good quality and treat them as de facto legitimate. Paradoxically, these ratings often are estimated with different approaches but rarely proven or validated objectively in a systematic way.

After the 2008 financial crisis, the value and validity of published ratings (e.g., credit, bond) have been widely criticized and questioned. A growing voice of the need for more scrutiny of these ratings has gained stronger attention. Some contend that credit rating agencies have made errors of judgment in rating debt (e.g., particularly in assigning AAA ratings to structured debt where many cases have subsequently been downgraded or defaulted) (Carlo & Michelle, 2008). For example, credit rating agencies such as Moody's, Standard & Poor's, and Fitch Ratings still maintained at least“A” ratings on AIG and Lehman Brothers right before its bankruptcy and acceptance of government's bailouts respectively. Other people argue that credit rating agencies are plagued by conflicts of interest that might inhibit them from providing accurate and honest ratings. For example, many banks in the U.S. that were closed by the FDIC in 2010 actually achieved passing grades or even an A + grade from the Better Business Bureau (BBB) beforehand. In the wake of recent financial crisis, which tarnishes the credibility of rating agencies, it is more important than ever to verify whether these ratings are valid and trustworthy and can provide quality information to their users. Under the notion that good decisions are based on good information, we conjecture that good investment decisions need to be supported by quality rating information.

If the use of these published ratings is intended for helping investors to make good investment decisions, objective evaluations and evidences should be put forward to justify that these ratings do provide meaningful and useful information (i.e., information quality) and are adequate and appropriate for investors' intended inferences and actions (i.e., validity). We conjecture that a

⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +886 3 8633136; fax: +886 3 8633130. E-mail address:gracew@mail.ndhu.edu.tw(S.-Y. Wang).

1059-0560/$– see front matter © 2013 Published by Elsevier Inc.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2013.12.003

Contents lists available atScienceDirect

International Review of Economics and Finance

j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / i r e f

(2)

rating can be better perceived as useful and valid when there is an objective measurement shows what is rated by the rating actually has consistently good performance over a period of time. Therefore, in this study we propose a method to identify information quality and verify validity of these ratings with a sound mathematical foundation. We set to present our method as an effective tool for assisting investors to make more informed and better investments. A set of hypotheses and empirical tests based on Value Line Mutual Fund Survey are provided to illustrate our proposed method. Through the illustration, a sequential statistical series are also constructed to measure the extent of information quality provided by the Value Line Rating.

This study intends to address the quality of the information provided by the multi-criteria ratings by proposing a method to identify information quality and verify validity of these ratings with a sound mathematical foundation. With the use of our proposed method we can objectively evaluate these ratings and seek to answer the following questions:

Do these ratings provide useful information for investors to make investment decisions?Can we trust these ratings and their intended interpretation and use for investors in making investment decisions?

We discuss the research background for this study in the following section. InSection 3, we demonstrate the rationale and methods to systematically construct the ordered classes of ratings. We then develop our hypotheses under suitable assumptions

inSection 4. InSection 5, an empirical study based on Value Line Mutual Fund Survey was conducted to illustrate how to construct

the ordered classes and was used to test our hypotheses. The information quality, depending on dominance relations and time, is also assessed. We conclude this study and offer remarks inSection 6.

2. Research background 2.1. Financial rating

The literature on the ratings of financial performance is abundant. Some scholars created Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and related models to rate the performance of a given set of financial assets/portfolios (Chiang, Kozhevnikov, & Wisen, 2005; Fama &

French, 1993, 1996; Jensen, 1968, 1969; Lee, Wu, & Wei, 1990; Lehmann & Modest, 1987). Others studied the persistence of

performance rating (Blake & Morey, 2000; Brown & Goetzmann, 1995; Goetzmann & Ibbotson, 1994; Grinblatt & Titman, 1992). Recently, stochastic dominance and DEA (Data Envelopment Analysis) have also been employed to study the rating, benchmarking and efficiency of the performance (Kopa & Post, 2009; Kuosmanen, 2004; Levy, 1998; Post, 2003). These studies tend to focus on how to rate the financial assets or portfolios over a set of known performance criteria. The derived results have been used to construct rating systems or methods, and to reward portfolio managers. Nonetheless, these studies rarely put effort on verifying the implied usefulness and validity of those ratings. Therefore, an objective measurement method should be developed to evaluate whether what is rated by these ratings actually has consistently good performance over a period of time. This method can be applied to almost all ratings supplied by rating industry and scholars in financial applications as well as other areas.

2.2. Information quality theory

Good information is needed for good decisions. One of the important functions of decision support is to gather information and uncover the quality ones for deriving good decisions. For example, leisure and business travelers who search ideal hotels often depend on certain rankings or“stars” of different aspects of hotels. Similarly, professional sports teams who try to identify prospective players count on rankings of a range of athletes' abilities from various scouting reports. Students choose and apply to colleges usually rely on some publications of rankings on various criteria of these colleges. However, a common problem for these scenarios is that there is no objective means or clear guidance on judging which rankings actually provide useful information and are trustworthy for decision making.

AsO'Reilly (1982)stated that there is a direct relationship between the quality of information used by a decision maker and

decision making performance. In general sense, there is support for the notion that good information leads to good decision making (e.g.,Ge, 2009). In finance literature, only a handful of recent studies explicitly consider the impact of information quality (e.g.,Ai, 2010; Brevik & d'Addona, 2010; Veronesi, 2000). We can consider information quality as the degree of usefulness or the “fitness of use” (Juran, 1992) for information users.Redman (2001)suggested that information is of high quality if it is fit for its intended uses in operations, decision-making, and planning.Wang (1998)also defined information quality as the characteristic of information to be of high value to its users.Eppler (2003)adopts both definitions of quality– meeting the customer expectations and meeting the activity requirements– acknowledging the important duality of quality: subjective (meeting the expectations) vs. objective (meeting the requirements). Therefore, for assisting investors to make good investment decisions, published ratings need to provide quality information. In the context of evaluating ratings, it is necessary to develop a mechanism which can assess and verify information quality of these ratings.

2.3. Theory of validity

According to Merriam-Webster, the term“validity” refers to the degree to which the conclusions (interpretations) derived from the results of any assessment are“well-grounded or justifiable; being at once relevant and meaningful.” In the well-established field of educational measurement, validity is in general defined as an integrated evaluative judgment of the degree to which empirical 47 A.N.K. Chen et al. / International Review of Economics and Finance 31 (2014) 46–58

(3)

evidence and theoretical rationales support the adequacy and appropriateness of inferences and actions based on test scores or other modes of assessment (Messick, 1989, p. 13).Cook and Beckman (2006)pointed out that validity is not a property of the instrument, but of the instrument's scores and their intended interpretations. What needs to be valid is the meaning or interpretation of the score; as well as any implications for action that this meaning entails (Cronbach, 1971). The term score is used generically in its broadest sense to mean any coding or summarization of observed consistencies or performance regularities of any assessment device including tests and portfolios (Messick, 1995). In this study we do not question how publishers derive their rating scores but focus on investigating the meaningfulness and usefulness of these ratings.

Our goal of this study is not to test theory of information quality or theory of validity but to provide a mechanism which can practically and objectively verify the usefulness of information and validity of intended inference and use of these ratings. By doing so, our method can support investors alike to identify good ratings from the available ones and ultimately make better investment decisions.

3. Implied ordered classes by multi-criteria ratings

Given a value function, we can construct ordered isovalue curves. In the same vein, given a rating based on multi-criteria (e.g., expected return, risk, growth persistence) over a set of assets (e.g., mutual funds, stocks, bonds), we can construct a number of ordered classes over the set of assets. If the rating does provide quality information, the average performance of the ordered classes over a period of time should show certain monotonic property (increasing or decreasing) which is similar to that of the value for the isovalue curves for a value function. Otherwise, the rating can be assessed as lack of validity of intended interpretation and usage.

To facilitate our presentation, we use Value Line Mutual Fund ratings for illustration. Value Line offers rating on more than two thousand mutual funds according to three criteria: overall ranking, risk, and 5-year growth persistence. A rating ranges from 1 to 5 for each criterion, and a smaller number represents a better rating. Thus, a mutual fund with rating (2, 2, 3) is better than one with rating (3, 4, 5). We summarize our notations inAppendix Aand present our method as follows.

We have n assets (stocks, bonds or funds) in a space X = {1,…, n}. According to the criteria C = {1, …, l}, we have rating information y = (r1,… rl) for an asset where yi= riis the rating of the ith criterion. Let f(x), x∈ X be the rating vector for asset x,

with fi(x), an integer, being the rating of ith criterion for asset x. Assume that for all i, 1≤ fi(x)≤ M, and that a smaller number

represents a better rating. In the case of Value Line's rating, M = 5. Many other ratings use number of stars or alphabetic ordering (e.g., AA, ABB) which can be easily transformed into numerical integer ordering. We have the rating space defined as Y = {f(x) | x∈ X}. Note that Y is the collection of all possible rating combinations. There may be several assets which are associated with the same y vector and yx= f(x)∈ Y. Let us first define some dominance relations over Y.

3.1. Dominance ordered classes

We first introduce definitions to allow us to construct ordered classes containing rating vector(s) for a giving rating space as follows. Concerning these classes, we'd conjecture and later empirically test that certain amount of performance homogeneity over time of a class of assets can show some monotonic difference when compared with other classes.

Definition 1. Given yx1; yx2 of Y, we say that yx1dominates yx2, denoted by yx1≤yx2, if yx1≠yx2and for each i = 1,…,l, yx1

i ≤y x2

i .

We denote yix= fi(x) which is the rating of ith criterion for asset x. Intuitively, the definition yx1 dominates yx2 ðyx1≤yx2Þ,

means that there is at least one rating criterion i of yx1is strictly better (smaller) than that of yx2while yx1is better than or equal to yx2for other rating criteria.

Clearly, if yx1≤yx2 and yx2≤yx3 then yx1≤yx3. Thus, the dominance relation“≤”over Y defined inDefinition 1is transitive. If rating information in vector y is valid and in good quality, and yx1≤yx2, we can expect that the performance of assets with rating yx1to be better than that of those with rating yx2.

Definition 2. Given yx1; yx2∈Y, we say that yx1strictly dominates yx2, denoted by yx1byx2, if yx1≠yx2and yx1

i by x2

i for all i = 1,…,l.

The strict dominance relation over Y inDefinition 2,“b”, is also transitive. Again, if rating information in vector y is valid and in good quality, and yx1byx2, we can expect that the performance of assets with rating yx1to be better than that of those with rating yx2. Example 1. Let a rating vector y = (r1, r2) with r1for the expected return rating and r2for risk rating. There exists a rating space Y

associated with 12 assets and Y = {(1,2),(1,3),(1,5),(2,5),(3,1),(3,4),(3,5),(4,1),(4,2),(5,2),(5,3),(5,5)} (Fig. 1). We notice that (1,2)≤ (1,3) ≤ (3,4) ≤ (3,5), and (1,2) b (3,4), (1,3) b (3,5). It is not true that (1,2) b (1,3) or (3,4) b (3,5).

Definition 3. Given Y, a “non-dominated class” of rating vector(s) is defined as

N(≤) = {yx∈ Y|no y⁎ ∈ Y with y⁎ ≤ yx}; and a“dominated class” of rating vector(s) can be defined as D(≤) = Y\N(≤).

Let N1(≤) = N(≤), D1(≤) = D(≤). For k = 2, 3, … where k denotes the kth “class”, we define Nk(≤) = {yx∈ Dk− 1(≤)| no

(4)

With respect to, Dk− 1(≤), Nk(≤) is the set of all non-dominated rating vectors (i.e., none of Dk− 1(≤) can dominate any point

of Nk(≤)), and Dk(≤) is the set of all dominated points (i.e., any rating vector of Dk(≤) is dominated by at least one rating vector of

Nk(≤)). Thus Nk(≤) and Dk(≤) form a partition of Dk− 1(≤). That is, Dk− 1(≤) = Nk(≤) ∪ Dk(≤) and Nk(≤) ∩ Dk(≤) = ϕ. For

this reason we call Nk(≤) the kth class of non-dominated set and Dk(≤) the kth class of dominated set.

4 1 2 3 5 1 4 2 5 3 r1 r2 (1, 2) (1, 3) (1, 5) (2, 5) (3, 5) (3, 4) (3, 1) (4, 1) (4, 2) (5, 2) (5, 3) (5, 5)

Fig. 1. The rating space ofExample 1.

4 1 2 3 5 1 4 2 5 3 r1 r2

Fig. 2. The non-dominated classes (inIllustration 1) derived fromExample 1.

49 A.N.K. Chen et al. / International Review of Economics and Finance 31 (2014) 46–58

(5)

Illustration 1. FromExample 1 and Definition 3, we derive the following classes (seeFig. 2): N1ð Þ ¼ 3; 1≤ fð Þ; 1; 2ð Þg; N2ð Þ ¼ 4; 1≤ fð Þ; 1; 3ð Þg; N3ð Þ ¼ 4; 2≤ fð Þ; 3; 4ð Þ; 1; 5ð Þg; N4ð Þ ¼ 5; 2≤ fð Þ; 2; 5ð Þg; N5ð Þ ¼ 5; 3≤ fð Þ; 3; 5ð Þg; N6ð Þ ¼ 5; 5≤ fð Þg D1ð Þ ¼ 1; 3≤ fð Þ; 1; 5ð Þ; 2; 5ð Þ; 3; 4ð Þ; 3; 5ð Þ; 4; 1ð Þ; 4; 2ð Þ; 5; 2ð Þ; 5; 3ð Þ; 5; 5ð Þg; D2ð Þ ¼ 1; 5≤ fð Þ; 2; 5ð Þ; 3; 4ð Þ; 3; 5ð Þ; 4; 2ð Þ; 5; 2ð Þ; 5; 3ð Þ; 5; 5ð Þg; D3ð Þ ¼ 2; 5≤ fð Þ; 3; 5ð Þ; 5; 2ð Þ; 5; 3ð Þ; 5; 5ð Þg; D4ð Þ ¼ 3; 5≤ fð Þ; 5; 3ð Þ; 5; 5ð Þg; D5ð Þ ¼ 5; 5≤ fð Þg; D6ð Þ ¼ ϕ:≤ Proposition 1. (i) If yx2∈N k0ð Þ and 1 ≤ k b k≤

', then there exists yx1∈N

kð Þ such that y≤ x1dominates yx2 (i.e., yx1≤yx2).

(ii) If k≠ k', then N

k0ð Þ∩N≤ kð Þ ¼.≤

(iii) There exists m≥ 1, such that Y ¼ ∪m

k¼1Nkð Þ.≤

(iv) (iv) Dk(≤) ⊃ Dk + 1(≤) and Dkð Þ⊃D≤ k0ð Þ, if k b k≤

'

with k, k'∈ {1,…,m}. Proof.

(i) By definition, as kb k'

, yx2∈D

kð Þ. Thus y≤ x2 is dominated by some yx1 in Nk(≤).

(ii) Suppose that kb k', then N

k0ð Þ⊂D≤ kð Þ. As D≤ k(≤) ∩ Nk(≤) =,

(iii) As Y consists of finite number of points, all points of Y will be contained by some Nk(≤), k = 1,…,m, and m is finite.

(iv) By definition, for k = 1,…, m, Dk(≤) = Nk + 1(≤) ∪ Dk + 1(≤). Thus Dk + 1(≤) ⊂ Dk(≤).

Theorem 1. {N1(≤), N2(≤),…,Nm(≤)} forms a decomposition of Y and all non-dominated classes are mutually exclusive.

Proof. FromProposition 1-(ii) and (iii).

Proposition 1-(i) essentially says that if kb k', then N

k(≤) collectively dominates Nk0ð Þ in the sense that for each y≤ x∈N

k0ð Þ≤

there is yx

∈Nkð Þ such that y≤ x



≤yx. Thus we could reasonably expect that the average performance of N

k(≤) to be better than

that of Nk0ð Þ if k b k≤ '. We explore this further in the next section as testing hypothesis.

Similar to the dominance (≤) andDefinition 3, we define the case of“strict dominance (b)” inAppendix BwithProposition B

and Theorem Bwhich are comparable toProposition 1 and Theorem 1respectively.

ComparingIllustration 1 to Illustration BinAppendix B, we notice that the numbers of ordered classes in {Nk(≤)} and {Dk(≤)}

are larger than those in {Nk(b)} and {Dk(b)} respectively. Thus it implies that the dominance relation of “≤” has a larger

discrimination power than the strict dominance relation of“b”. 4. Models and hypotheses

With the concepts and definitions introduced inSection 3 and Appendix B, we first build basic models and show derived properties of these models, and in turn introduce a sequence of hypotheses which will be tested with empirical data.

Recall that y = (r1,…rl) and yix= fi(x), which is the rating of ith criterion for asset x. We define a value function which reflects

the impact of rating yiat time t as follow:

V yði; tÞ ¼ αtþ

Xl i¼1

βityiþ εt ð1Þ

αtandεtare independent of yiand reflect the general fluctuation (expected and unpredictable ones respectively) of the market.

∑l

i¼1βityireflects the collective impact of given ratings.

Ifβit= 0, the rating yihas no impact. When rating yiis“the smaller the better”, we expect that V yð x1; tÞNV yð x2; tÞ t, if yx1byx2.

This property will hold if eachβitb 0, i = 1,⋯,l. In addition, Eq.(1)can be used as a linear regression equation to statistically

(6)

Since V(yi,t) can be nonlinear in y and t and we only know that a smaller yiis better, we need to rely on the following

underlying concepts for our use of the value function.

Definition 5. V(y,t) is increasing in the “dominance (≤)” case; that is, V yð x1; tÞNV yð x2; tÞ wherever yx1≤yx2and yx1≠yx2(i.e., yx1 dominates yx2(Definition 1)).

V(y,t) is increasing in“strictly dominance (b)” case; that is, V yð x1; tÞNV yð x2; tÞ wherever yx1byx2 and yx1≠yx2 (i.e., yx1strictly dominates yx2(Definition 2)).

We note that if V(y,t) is increasing in“≤” then it is also increasing in “b”; however, the reverse may not hold true. For instance, let yx1¼ 2; 1ð Þ; yx2¼ 2; 3ð Þ, and yx3¼ 3; 3ð Þ. If V(y,t) is increasing in “≤”, then V yð x1; tÞNV yð x2; tÞNV yð x3; tÞ is true. However, if V(y,t) is increasing only in“b”, V yð x1; tÞNV yð x3; tÞ is true but and it may not be true for V yð x1; tÞNV yð x2; tÞ or V yðx2; tÞNV yð x3; tÞ. This inference echoes our earlier comment on that the strict dominance relation of“b” has a smaller discrimination power than the dominance relation of“≤”.

Condition 1. V(y,t) is increasing in“dominance (≤)”. Condition 2. V(y,t) is increasing in“strictly dominance (b)”.

In the following we show that, under an additive assumption (Condition 3), if Condition 1 (Condition 2 respectively) is met, then a good investment portfolio should not contain any asset from D(≤) (D(b) respectively). That is, a good investment portfolio must be consisted of assets from N(≤) (N(b) respectively). Recall that we have n assets, X = {1, …, n} under consideration. A portfolio is a vector of n assets P = (x1,…, xn). xpis the proportion of the investment put in the asset p; p = 1,…, n assets. Note

that xp≥ 0 and ∑

n

p¼1xp¼ 1.

Condition 3. Collective rating of a criterion i of all asset in portfolio P is calculated as Pi¼ ∑ n

p¼1xpfið Þp

That is, the collective rating of a criterion i of all asset in portfolio P is the additive sum of the all rating fi(p) of its components

(assets) {p|p = 1,…, n} with weight xp.

Theorem 3. If Conditions 1 and 3 are met, then any portfolio P = (x1,…, xn) with xkN 0 and k ∈ D(≤) cannot be the best portfolio.

That is, we can find a portfolio P′ = (x1′,…,xn′) where P ≠ P′ and V(f(P′), t) N V(f(P), t).

Proof. As k∈ D(≤), we can find an asset r such that f(r) = yr≤ yk= f(k). Let P0be a portfolio such that x k

0= 0 (i.e., proportion

of asset k is zero); xr0= xr+ xk(i.e., proportion of asset r is the sum of the proportion of asset r and proportion of asset k in P);

and xi0= xi, if i≠ k, r (i.e., all other proportions of assets equal to those in P).

By additive assumption of Condition 3, we have P0 i ¼ ∑ n p¼1x 0 pfið Þ ¼ ∑p n p¼1xpfið Þ−xp kfið Þ þ xk kfið Þ ¼ Pr iþ xkðfið Þ−fr ið ÞkÞ: As xkN 0 and f(r) ≤ f(k), we have y0= f(x0)≤ f(xP) = yP.

By Condition 1, we have V(f(P0), t)N V(f(P), t). Thus P cannot be the best portfolio.

Corollary 1. If Conditions 1 and 3 are met, then a necessary condition for a portfolio P = (x1,…, xn) to be optimal is that whenever

xkN 0 and k ∈ N(≤).

Proof. It is directly from N(≤) = Y\D(≤) inDefinition 3.

Theorem 3 and Corollary 1justify a reasonable process of good investment; that is, we can identify“not-dominated class”

N(≤) first and then form the investment portfolio of assets from N(≤). On the other hand, the “dominated class” D(≤) can be ignored if Conditions 1 and 3 are met. Similar toTheorem 3 and Corollary 1, we derive the followings.

Theorem 4. If Conditions 2 and 3 are met, then any portfolio P = (x1,…, xn) with xkN 0 and k ∈ D(b) cannot be the best portfolio.

That is, we can find a portfolio P'= (x 1 ',…,x

n

') where P≠ P'and V(f(P'), t)N V(f(P), t).

Proof. Similar to that forTheorem 3.

Corollary 2. If Conditions 2 and 3 are met, then a necessary condition for a portfolio P = (x1,…, xn) to be optimal is that whenever

xkN 0 and k ∈ N(b).

Based onTheorems 3 and 4 and Proposition 1, we further intend to examine the usefulness of information and validity of intended inference and use of available ratings. That is, we'd like to verify whether a“rating” (f(x), x ∈ X) is reliable and credible, or has any value for investment decision making. For instance, the Value Line Mutual Fund Survey ratings postulate that the 51 A.N.K. Chen et al. / International Review of Economics and Finance 31 (2014) 46–58

(7)

smaller a rating is, the better for each valuation criteria, which implies that these ratings satisfy Condition 1, or at least Condition 2. Hence, with the use of our techniques to generate ordered classes from these ratings, we would expect that the average performance of Nk(≤) to be better than that of Nk + 1(≤), and that of Nk(b) to be much better than that of Nk + 1(b), whenever

these corresponding sets {Nk(≤), Nk + 1(≤), Nk(b) and Nk + 1(b)} are nonempty. Similarly, we would expect that the average

performance of Dk(≤) to be better than that of Dk + 1(≤), and that of Dk(b) to be better than that of Dk + 1(b), whenever the

corresponding sets are nonempty. If these expectations are proven wrong, we should be able to conclude that these ratings are not truly reliable or credible, and the rating information tend to have no value for investment decision making. Therefore, when Condition 1 is met, we hypothesize that:

H1a: The average performance of those assets in Nk(≤) is better than that of those in Dk(≤), k = 1,2,…, whenever the

corresponding sets are not empty.

H1b: For k = 1,2,…, the average performance of those assets in Nk(≤) is better than that of those in Nk + 1(≤), if Nk + 1(≤) is

not empty.

H1c: For k = 1,2,…, the average performance of those assets in Dk(≤) is better than that of those in Dk + 1(≤), if Dk + 1(≤) is

not empty.

When Condition 2 is met, we hypothesize that:

H2a: The average performance of those assets in Nk(b) is better than that of those in Dk(b), k = 1,2,…, whenever the

corresponding sets are not empty.

H2b: For k = 1,2,…, the average performance of those assets in Nk(b) is better than that of those in Nk + 1(b), if Nk(b) and

Nk + 1(b) are not empty.

H2c: For k = 1,2,…, the average performance of those assets in Dk(b) is better than that of those in Dk + 1(b), if Dk + 1(b) is not

empty.

5. Empirical study 5.1. Data

In order to illustrate the concepts introduced in the previous two sections and test our hypotheses, we used published data from the well known Value Line Mutual Fund Survey (henceforth called the“Survey”). For each mutual fund in the Survey, there was an integer rating ranging from 1 to 5 (i.e., M = 5) for each of the following three criteria (i.e., l = 3): (i) overall ranks, (ii) risk ranks, and (iii) 5-year growth persistence. For each criterion, the smaller the rating is, the better it is.

With the concept introduced inSection 3, we used rating data of the Survey published on August 22, 2006 to classify mutual funds into corresponding ordered classes: (i) N(≤) and D(≤) for testing Hypothesis 1, and (ii) N(b) and D(b) for testing Hypothesis 2. We also performed the same operations and analyses on Survey data published on two other dates (April 25, 2006 and December 26, 2006). In order to save space, we did not report these results which were similar to our major findings.

The year-to-date (YTD) rates of return provided by the Survey were used to measure the performance (corresponding to V(y,t)

ofSection 4). For consistency of comparison, any mutual funds which were not consistently shown in the Survey from April 25,

2006 to April 24, 2007 (which is the time horizon of our study) were removed. It resulted in 2027 mutual funds for our study. The Survey published ratings once in every three weeks. We noted that sometimes two consecutive rating and rate of return could be identical (e.g., December 26, 2006 and January 9, 2007).

We are interested in the posterior (after August 22, 2006) average rate of return of each class {Nk(≤)}, {Dk(≤)}, {Nk(b)} and

{Dk(b)} and derive them to test our Hypotheses. We report the corresponding results and discuss our findings as follows.

5.2. Dominance ordered classes and Hypothesis 1

WithDefinition 3, we classified the 2027 mutual funds into 24 classes: {(Nk(≤), Dk(≤))|k = 1, 2, …, 12}. The distribution of

the number of assets in each class is presented below.

k 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Nk(≤) 5 96 203 330 222 194 342 203 127 116 102 84

Dk(≤) 2022 1926 1723 1393 1171 977 635 432 305 189 87 3

The corresponding average YTD rates of return for each class from August 22, 2006 to April 24, 2007 (denoted by R(8/22/06),…, R(04/24/07) with 13 data points) are listed inTable 1. Note that the columns of R(8/22/06) and R(9/12/06) are identical because the Survey gave identical YTD rate of return. It is same for columns of R(12/26/06) and R(1/9/07). The indices of the last three rows show the frequency of falsification of H1a, H1b, and H1c respectively (i.e., the inequality of hypothesis is not supported) on corresponding dates. We further illustrate data fromTable 1inFig. 3which shows a“rough monotonic property” stated in Hypothesis 1 from August 22, 2006 to February 20, 2007 (i.e., the first 10 data points).

(8)

Table 1

The average YTD rates of returns of“dominance ordered classes (≤)”.

R(8/22/06) R(9/12/06) R(10/3/06) R(10/24/06) R(11/14/06) R(12/5/06) R(12/26/06) R(1/9/07) R(1/30/07) R(/2/20/07) R(3/13/07) R(/4/3/07) R(4/24/07) N1 0.0724 0.0724 0.0904 0.0998 0.0998 0.1188 0.1434 0.1434 0.1614 0.1614 0.0096 0.0150 0.0150 D1 0.0292 0.0292 0.0497 0.0617 0.0618 0.0916 0.1185 0.1185 0.1277 0.1278 0.0128 0.0103 0.0103 N2 0.0637 0.0637 0.0854 0.0933 0.0933 0.1205 0.1454 0.1454 0.1650 0.1660 0.0090 0.0119 0.0123 D2 0.0275 0.0275 0.0479 0.0602 0.0602 0.0902 0.1172 0.1172 0.1258 0.1259 0.0130 0.0102 0.0102 N3 0.0663 0.0663 0.0885 0.0973 0.0973 0.1271 0.1550 0.1550 0.1736 0.1735 0.0130 0.0147 0.0148 D3 0.0230 0.0230 0.0431 0.0558 0.0558 0.0858 0.1127 0.1127 0.1202 0.1203 0.0130 0.0097 0.0097 N4 0.0479 0.0479 0.0677 0.0783 0.0783 0.1078 0.1356 0.1356 0.1455 0.1476 0.0130 0.0122 0.0123 D4 0.0170 0.0170 0.0373 0.0504 0.0505 0.0806 0.1073 0.1073 0.1142 0.1138 0.0130 0.0091 0.0091 N5 0.0552 0.0552 0.0741 0.0827 0.0825 0.1150 0.1479 0.1479 0.1680 0.1666 0.0092 0.0075 0.0076 D5 0.0098 0.0098 0.0304 0.0443 0.0444 0.0741 0.0996 0.0996 0.1040 0.1038 0.0137 0.0094 0.0093 N6 0.0351 0.0351 0.0516 0.0635 0.0639 0.0922 0.1153 0.1153 0.1259 0.1234 0.0104 0.0082 0.0082 D6 0.0048 0.0048 0.0261 0.0405 0.0405 0.0705 0.0965 0.0965 0.0996 0.0999 0.0144 0.0096 0.0096 N7 0.0230 0.0230 0.0420 0.0589 0.0589 0.0874 0.1094 0.1094 0.1169 0.1179 0.0125 0.0077 0.0077 D7 −0.0050 −0.0050 0.0176 0.0307 0.0306 0.0614 0.0896 0.0896 0.0903 0.0902 0.0153 0.0107 0.0106 N8 0.0346 0.0346 0.0547 0.0556 0.0556 0.0894 0.1251 0.1251 0.1247 0.1244 0.0123 0.0128 0.0126 D8 −0.0237 −0.0237 0.0001 0.0190 0.0189 0.0483 0.0729 0.0729 0.0741 0.0741 0.0168 0.0097 0.0096 N9 −0.0025 −0.0025 0.0200 0.0366 0.0354 0.0674 0.0897 0.0897 0.0942 0.0944 0.0165 0.0082 0.0077 D9 −0.0325 −0.0325 −0.0081 0.0116 0.0120 0.0403 0.0658 0.0658 0.0657 0.0656 0.0168 0.0103 0.0104 N10 −0.0177 −0.0177 0.0046 0.0219 0.0228 0.0492 0.0741 0.0741 0.0733 0.0753 0.0158 0.0144 0.0144 D10 −0.0415 −0.0415 −0.0160 0.0054 0.0054 0.0349 0.0608 0.0608 0.0611 0.0597 0.0174 0.0078 0.0080 N11 −0.0427 −0.0427 −0.0193 0.0003 0.0003 0.0317 0.0599 0.0599 0.0606 0.0581 0.0180 0.0118 0.0120 D11 −0.0401 −0.0401 −0.0120 0.0113 0.0113 0.0386 0.0618 0.0618 0.0616 0.0616 0.0168 0.0031 0.0033 N12 −0.0389 −0.0389 −0.0111 0.0123 0.0123 0.0397 0.0627 0.0627 0.0629 0.0629 0.0168 0.0036 0.0038 D12 −0.0747 −0.0747 −0.0380 −0.0167 −0.0167 0.0087 0.0360 0.0360 0.0247 0.0247 0.0167 −0.0113 −0.0113

(i) # of times falsified H1a 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 8 4 4

(ii) # of times falsified H1b 4 4 4 3 3 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4

(iii) # of times falsified H1c 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 6 4 4

53 A.N.K. Chen et al. / International Review of Economics and Finance 31 (2014) 46 – 58

(9)

In this subsection, we denote Nktand Dktas the average YTD rates of return at time t for the mutual funds of Nk(≤) and Dk(≤)

respectively.

For H1a, it is expected that NktNDktfor all t (i.e., 13 dates from August 22, 2006 to April 24, 2007). In addition, in our study we

derive 12 classes (i.e., k = 1, 2,…, 12) so that there are 12 comparisons for each time t and each set (N(≤) and D(≤)). For the data points from August 22, 2006 to February 20, 2007 (i.e., the first 10 columns) listed inTable 1, we can see that H1a holds for all comparisons but one. Therefore, during this time horizon, the hypothesis is largely supported where the data shows a support of 11/12 (11 out of 12 comparisons) which is significantly better than a random selection would show (6/12). It is also interesting to note that after t = February 20, 2007, the data do not support this hypothesis.

For H1b, it is expected that Nðk−1ÞtNNktfor all t. There are 11 comparisons (k = 2, 3,…, 12) between N(≤) classes. For the data

points from August 22, 2006 to February 20, 2007 (i.e., the first 10 columns) listed inTable 1, we can see that H1b is falsified between 3 to 5 times. Therefore, during this time horizon, the hypothesis is not supported where the data shows a support of only from 6/11 to 7/11which is not significantly better than a random selection 1/2.

For H1c, it is expected that Dðk−1ÞtNDktfor all t. Similarly, there are 11 comparisons (k = 2, 3,…, 12) between D(≤) classes.

From the first 10 data points inTable 1, we can see that H1c is falsified only once. Therefore, during this time horizon, the hypothesis is largely supported where the data shows a support of 10/11 which is significantly better than a random selection would show (1/2). Again, it is interesting to note that after t = February 20, 2007, the data do not support this hypothesis.

5.3. Strictly dominance ordered classes and Hypothesis 2

With theDefinition BinAppendix B, we classified the 2027 mutual funds into four classes: {(Nk(b), Dk(b))|k = 1, 2}. The

number of distribution of each class is as follows.

k 1 2

Nk(b) 1346 653

Dk(b) 681 28

There are only four classes because it is much harder to have“strict dominance” than to have “dominance”. The corresponding average YTD rates of return for each class from August 22, 2006 to April 24, 2007 (denoted by R(8/22/06),…, R(04/24/07) with 13 data points) are listed inTable 2. The indices of the last three rows show the frequency of falsification of H2a, H2b, and H2c respectively (i.e., the inequality of hypothesis is not supported) on corresponding dates. We illustrate data fromTable 2inFig. 4

which again shows a“rough monotonic property” stated in Hypothesis 2 from the first 10 data points.

In this subsection, we denote Nktand Dktas the average YTD rates of return at time t for the mutual funds of Nk(b) and Dk(b)

respectively.

For H2a, it is expected that NktNDktfor all t. For the data points from August 22, 2006 to February 20, 2007 (i.e., the first 10

columns) listed inTable 2, we can see that H2a holds for all comparisons. However, after t = February 20, 2007, the data do not support this hypothesis.

-0.1 -0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 /07)

YTD Rates of Returns

Time

N1 D1 N2 D2 N3 D3 N4 D4 N5 D5 N6 D6

N7 D7 N8 D8 N9 D9 N10 D10 N11 D11 N12 D12

(10)

For H2b, it is expected that N1tNN2tfor all t. This hypothesis is fully supported with the data points from August 22, 2006 to

February 20, 2007 but is not supported with the data points after February 20, 2007.

For H2c, it is expected that D1tND2tfor all t. Similarly, there are 11 comparisons (k = 2, 3,…, 12) between D(≤) classes. This

hypothesis is fully supported with the data points throughout August 22, 2006 and February 20, 2007. 5.4. Discussions and implications

With respect to YTD rates of return, we summarize the results of hypothesis testing inTable 3. In addition, we also performed the same operations and analyses on Survey data published on two other dates (April 25, 2006 and December 26, 2006). In order to save space, we did not report these results which were similar to our major findings.

Base on the dominance ordered class“≤”, H1a and H1c (but not H1b) are largely supported for a certain period of time (about one half year). After that, Hypothesis 1 is not supported. This suggests that ratings (e.g., published by the Survey on August 22, 2006) can offer useful and valid information value for interested investors by considering specific circumstances. With our introduced technique which classifies assets into different non-dominated classes and dominated classes based on specific published ratings, investors can expect to make better decisions with respect to rate of return. For example, our results from testing H1a suggest that investors should invest in assets belonging to a non-dominated class instead of those in corresponding dominated class. Our results from testing H1c suggest that among dominated classes investors should invest in assets belonging to a lower-ordered class (i.e., the smaller k of kth class) instead of those in higher-ordered class. It is also interesting to point out that investors should be cautious with the use of rating information which is not timely and current (e.g., more than one half year based on our results).

Considering the strictly dominance ordered class“b”, Hypothesis 2 is fully supported for a certain period of time (about one half year). After that, only H2c is supported. This suggests that with our introduced technique which classifies assets into different strictly non-dominated classes and strictly dominated classes based on specific published ratings, investors can expect to make better decisions with respect to rate of return. Our results from testing H2a suggest that investors can invest in assets belonging to a strictly non-dominated class instead of those in corresponding strictly dominated class. Our results from testing H2b (and H2c) suggest that among strictly non-dominated classes (and strictly dominated classes) investors can invest in assets belonging to a lower-ordered class instead of those in higher-ordered class.

Strict dominance requires that the rating in each criterion be strictly dominated and thus fewer mutual funds could be strictly dominated. As a result, the number of classes of {Nk(b), Dk(b)} are much less than that of the corresponding {Nk(≤), Dk(≤)}. In

other words, the classification based on“b” cannot be as fine as that based on “≤”; in turn, we conjecture earlier that the strict dominance relation of“b” has a smaller discrimination power than the dominance relation of “≤”. However, the flip side of this reasoning is that strict dominance classes (once got classified) are better differentiated between each other since it is harder to derive“strict dominance” than just “dominance”. Our results show that for dominance based on “≤”, the Survey are only largely consistent with some corresponding hypotheses, and that for strict dominance based on“b”, the Survey are fully consistent with all corresponding hypotheses.

6. Conclusions

In this study, we consider information quality as the characteristic of information to be of high value to its users. From the financial investment decision-making perspective, investors need to rely on the support of quality information to make good investment decisions. We propose a method to identify information quality and verify validity of published rating reports with a sound mathematical foundation.

In the financial market, most available rating information is based on multi-criteria and published by myriad agents or companies. Many investors who naively rely on these ratings and are unaware of their quality may result in poor investment decisions and be prone to mistakes. Using our method to systematically analyze published ratings and follow the implications from this study to objectively evaluate these ratings would be not only computationally feasible but also a useful task. By doing so, investors can be informed whether these ratings actually provide useful information and whether they can trust these ratings and intended interpretation for the use of making investment decisions. In turn, informed investors (e.g., individuals, portfolio and Table 2

The average YTD rates of returns of“strictly dominance ordered classes (b)”.

R(8/22/06) R(9/12/06) R(10/3/06) R(10/24/06) R(11/14/06)

N1 0.0450 0.0450 0.0648 0.0746 0.0746

D1 −0.0016 −0.0016 0.0202 0.0367 0.0366

N2 −0.0007 −0.0007 0.0209 0.0375 0.0374

D2 −0.0205 −0.0205 0.0042 0.0180 0.0180

(i) # of times falsified H2a 0 0 0 0 0

(ii) # of times falsified H2b 0 0 0 0 0

(iii) # of times falsified H2c 0 0 0 0 0

(continued on next page) 55 A.N.K. Chen et al. / International Review of Economics and Finance 31 (2014) 46–58

(11)

fund managers, investment bank managers) can subsequently rely on identified“trustworthy” ratings and target asset(s) in non-dominated or good classes in general to invest and expect relatively better returns.

Following our method and given a multi-criteria rating report (e.g., Value Line, Standard & Poor's) on a finite number of assets (e.g., stocks, bonds, mutual funds), we can construct four sets of ordered classes class: {Nk(≤)}, {Dk(≤)}, {Nk(b)} and {Dk(b)}. If

ratings from a published report have useful and valid information value as claimed, the average performances of assets within classes (e.g., Nk(≤) within {Nk(≤)|k = 1,2,…},) are expected to show some monotonic property in k. We systematically describe

the rationale and methods to construct the above-mentioned four sets of ordered classes (Section 3) and construct hypotheses

(Section 4) to describe the expected monotonic properties.

For illustrations, we use Value Line Mutual Fund Survey's rating on August 22, 2006 (also April 25, 2006 and December 26, 2006, though not reported) to derive the corresponding four sets of ordered classes and test the corresponding hypotheses. We found that the usefulness and validity of published ratings depend on (1) the degree of consistency with the expected monotonic property and the length of time duration, and (2) the type of dominance (“≤” or “b”). As the dominance of “b” is more strict than that of“≤”, the classification based on “≤” is sharper than that based on “b”. Thus given the same length of time duration, the consistence in“≤” is more difficult but more valuable than that in “b”.

It is worth noting that in this study one of the rating criteria is risk rank and we use realized average rate of returns to represent the performance of a class of assets. It is commonly recognized that assets with lower risk (volatility) usually realize lower returns on average. However, one of the reasons that we chose Value Line data for our empirical testing is that its safety criterion is the risk-adjusted performance. It is calculated by dividing an asset's three-year total return by the standard deviation of its return and is commonly known as the Sharpe ratio. In addition, it is not always true that lower risk of an asset leads to lower performance since the judgment of risk itself can depend on the risk attitude of investors. Therefore, we believe that using Value Line data for current study is appropriate to derive our findings. At the same time, further study with using other empirical data and finding relationships between volatility and expected payoff of assets can be pursued.

Another type of ordered classes (i.e., negative dominance classes) can also be constructed by using our technique. Especially, when the size of a rating space becomes large (i.e., many assets to be considered), the classification outcomes of dominance ordered classes and negative dominance ordered classes can be different. Therefore, it can be useful to construct and examine both types of ordered classes with our technique and it might be interesting to further study whether there exist any relationships of these classes as well as the implications derived from these classes.

-0.04 -0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 11/14/06) R(12/5/06) R(12/26/06) R(1/9/07) R(1/30/07) R(2/20/07) R(3/13/07) R(4/3/07) R(4/24/07)

YTD Rates of Returns

Time

N1 D1 N2 D2

Fig. 4. The YTD rates of returns of strictly non-dominated classes and strictly dominated classes (b). Table 2

The average YTD rates of returns of“strictly dominance ordered classes (b)”.

R(12/5/06) R(12/26/06) R(1/9/07) R(1/30/07) R(/2/20/07) R(3/13/07) R(/4/3/07) R(4/24/07) 0.1045 0.1324 0.1324 0.1441 0.1444 0.0112 0.0100 0.0100 0.0663 0.0914 0.0914 0.0954 0.0952 0.0159 0.0110 0.0109 0.0673 0.0923 0.0923 0.0968 0.0966 0.0160 0.0110 0.0110 0.0445 0.0686 0.0686 0.0619 0.0619 0.0145 0.0097 0.0097 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Table 2(continued)

(12)

To further extend our classification method, we can explore many other dominance cones, varying from“b” to a half space. For example, V(y,t), as defined in Formula (1), withβitb 0, i = 1,…,l is increasing in a cone Λ ¼ ðh1; …; hlÞ ∑

i hiβitN0g    which is a half space and much larger than that of“≤” or “b”. A careful study of information contents of ratings in terms of varying dominance cones could further refine our evaluation of these ratings. For further discussion of this extension, please see ofYu

(Chapters 7 and 10, 1985).

With current study as a base and a first step, future testing of our hypotheses can be conducted with (1) ratings published by many agencies other than the Value Line, (2) ratings of various financial assets other than mutual funds, (3) ratings published in shorter and/or longer time intervals, (4) ratings published longer time ago or more recently, and (6) ratings collected in longer time horizon. We believe that these extended empirical investigations can potentially offer more detailed and insightful results for financial investors.

Future studies can arrange and examine different combination and/or number of criteria of ratings. With the use of our proposed method, we can then discover the“right” criteria to be included in ratings for an asset to be evaluated so that more useful and reliable investment aids can be extracted. In addition, by doing so, our method not only can identify“poor” existing assets that investor should avoid but also can timely detect inferior upcoming or new assets and weep them out for investors.

Our method can also be applied with other multi-criteria ranking practices. For example, it can be used for evaluating ratings from hotel rating agents (e.g., AAA, hotels.com, and tripadvisor) by tracking hotel performance (e.g., occupancy rate, customer satisfaction). In this fashion, evidence can be provided that specific hotel rating agents consistently provide useful information for travelers to choose ideal places to stay by relying on their ratings of hotels. Other practices can be considered are sports scouting, university admission, professor evaluation, and college choices with corresponding performance measurements.

Appendix A. Summary of notations

Notation Meaning

X Asset space, x∈ X, x = 1, …, n assets C Criteria space, i∈ C, i = 1, …, l criteria y Rating vector, y = (r1,… rl) ri The rating of ith criterion in C yi yi= ri

Y Rating space, Y = {f(x)|x∈ X} f(x) Rating vector for asset x

fi(x) The rating of ith criterion for asset x; fi(x) is an integer and 1≤ fi(x)≤ M; M is the largest number of a ranking for a criterion; 1 is the best rating and M is the worst rating.

yx yx

= f(x) yix yix= fi(x)

N(≤) Non-dominated class— a set (class) of rating vectors that do not have all rating criteria that are worse than or equal to those of compared rating vectors D(≤) Dominated class— a set (class) of rating vectors that are dominated by N(≤); i.e., all rating criteria in any vector in D(≤) that are always worse

than or equal to those of at least one vector in N(≤)

Nk(≤) The kth class of N(≤); N1(≤) is the class that is not dominated by any other class

Dk(≤) The kth class of D(≤); D1(≤) is the class that is dominated by N1(≤); D2(≤) is the class that is dominated by both N1(≤) and N2(≤); and so forth N(b) Strictly non-dominated class— a set (class) of rating vectors that do not have all rating criteria that are strictly worse than those of compared

rating vectors

D(b) Strictly dominated class— a set (class) of rating vectors that are strictly dominated by N(b); i.e., all rating criteria in any vector in D(b) that are always strictly worse than those of at least one vector in N(b)

Nk(b) The kth class of N(b); N1(b) is the class that is not strictly dominated by any other class

Dk(b) The kth class of D(b); D1(b) is the class that is strictly dominated by N1(b); D2(b) is the class that is strictly dominated by both N1(b) and N2(b); and so forth V(yi,t)

Value function reflecting rating vector y at time t, V yði; tÞ ¼ αtþ ∑ l i¼1βityiþ εt P

Portfolio vector of n assets; P = (x1,…, xn);∑ n

p¼1xp¼ 1 where xpis the portion of the investment put in the asset p; p = 1,…, n assets Pi

Collective rating of a criterion i of all asset in portfolio P; Pi¼ ∑ n p¼1xpfið Þp Table 3

Summary of hypothesis testing.

Data points 8/22/2006–2/20/2007 3/13/2007–4/24/2007

(Survey dates) (First 10 dates) (Last 3 dates)

Hypothesis 1 (≤) H1a is largely supported Not supported

H1b is not supported Not supported

H1c is largely supported Not supported

Hypothesis 2 (b) H2a is fully supported Not supported

H2b is fully supported Not supported

H2c is fully supported Supported

57 A.N.K. Chen et al. / International Review of Economics and Finance 31 (2014) 46–58

(13)

Appendix B. Strict dominance ordered classes

Definition B. Given Y, a “strictly non-dominated class” of rating vector(s) is defined as N(b) = {yx∈ Y|no y⁎ ∈ Y with y⁎ b yx}; and a

“strictly dominated class” of rating vector(s) can be defined as D(b) = Y\N(b). Let N1(b) = N(b), D1(b) = D(b). For k = 2, 3, …

where k denotes the kth“class”, we define Nk(b) = {yx∈ Dk− 1(≤)| no y⁎ ∈ Dk− 1(b) with y⁎ b yx}; Dk(b) = Dk− 1(b)\Nk(b).

Illustration B. Given Y as inExample 1, we have N1(b) = {(1,2), (1,3), (1,5), (3,1), (4,1)}, N2(b) = {(2,5), (3,4), (3,5), (4,2),

(5,2)}, N3(b) = {(5,5), (5,3)} (see Fig. B1 below).

Proposition B. (i) If yx2∈N

k′ð Þ and 1 ≤ k b kb

', then there exists yx1∈N

kð Þ such that yb x1 strictly dominates yx2 (i.e., yx1byx2).

(ii) If k≠ k'

, then Nk0ð Þ∩Nb kð Þ ¼.b (iii) There exists m≥ 1, such that Y ¼ ∪m

k¼1Nkð Þ.b

(iv) Dk(b) ⊃ Dk + 1(b) and Dkð Þ⊃Db k0ð Þ, if k b kb 'with k, k'∈ {1,…,m}.

Theorem B. {N1(b), N2(b),…,Nm(b)} forms a decomposition of Y and all strictly non-dominated classes are mutually exclusive

(proof is fromProposition B-(ii) and (iii)). From (i), it essentially says that if kb k', then N

k(b) collectively dominates Nk0ð Þ in the sense that for each yb x∈N

k0ð Þ there isb

yx

∈Nk0ð Þ such that yb x

strictly dominates yx(i.e., yx

byx). Thus we could reasonably expect that the average performance of N

k(b)

to be better than that of Nk0ð Þ if k b kb '.

Fig. B1. The strictly non-dominated classes derived fromExample 1. References

Ai, H. (2010).Information quality and long-run risk: Asset pricing implications. Journal of Finance, 65(4), 1333–1367.

Blake, C. R., & Morey, M. R. (2000).Morningstar ratings and mutual fund performance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 35(3), 451–483.

Brevik, F., & d'Addona, S. (2010).Information quality and stock returns revisited. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(6), 1419–1446.

Brown, S. J., & Goetzmann, W. N. (1995).Performance persistence. Journal of Finance, 50(2), 679–698.

Carlo, R. W., & Michelle, H. W. (2008).The credit crunch and credit rating agencies: Are they really striving towards more transparency? Journal of Securities Compliance, 1(4), 322–336.

Chiang, K. C. H., Kozhevnikov, K., & Wisen, C. H. (2005).Ranking properties of Morningstar risk-adjusted ratings. Journal of Investing, 14(1), 90–98.

Cook, D. A., & Beckman, T. J. (2006).Current concepts in validity and reliability for psychometric instruments: Theory and application. The American Journal of Medicine, 119, 166.e7–166.e16.

Cronbach, L. J. (1971).Test validation. In R. L. Thorndike (Ed.), Educational measurement (pp. 443–507) (2nd ed.). Washington, DC: American Council on Education.

Eppler, M. (2003).Managing information quality: Increasing the value of information in knowledge-intensive products and processes. Berlin, Germany: Springer-Verlag.

Fama, E., & French, K. (1993).Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 3–56.

Fama, E., & French, K. (1996).Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies. Journal of Finance, 51, 55–84.

Ge, Mouzhi (2009).Information quality assessment and effects on inventory decision-making. (PhD thesis). Dublin City University.

Goetzmann, W. N., & Ibbotson, R. G. (1994).Do winners repeat? Journal of Portfolio Management, 20(2), 9–18.

Grinblatt, M., & Titman, S. (1992).The persistence of mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance, 47(5), 1977–1984.

Jensen, M. (1968).The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945–1964. Journal of Finance, 23, 389–416.

Jensen, M. (1969).Risk, the pricing of capital assets, and the evaluation of investment portfolios. Journal of Business, 42, 167–247.

Juran, J. (1992).Juran on quality by design. New York: The Free Press.

Kopa, M., & Post, T. (2009).A portfolio optimality test based on the first-order stochastic dominance criterion. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44(5), 1103–1124.

Kuosmanen, T. (2004).Efficient diversification according to stochastic dominance criteria. Management Science, 50(10), 1390–1406.

Lee, C. F., Wu, C., & Wei, K. C. J. (1990).The heterogeneous investment horizon and the capital asset pricing model: Theory and implications. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 25(3), 361–376.

Lehmann, B. N., & Modest, D. (1987).Mutual fund performance evaluation: A comparison of benchmarks and a benchmark of comparisons. Journal of Finance, 21, 233–265.

Levy, H. (1998).Stochastic dominance: Investment decision making under uncertainty. Studies in Risk and Uncertainty. Boston, Dordrecht and London: Kluwer Academic.

Messick, S. (1989).Validity. In R. L. Linn (Ed.), Educational measurement (pp. 13–103) (3rd ed.). New York American Council on Education and Macmillan.

Messick, S. (1995).Validity of psychological assessment. American Psychologist, 50(9), 741–749.

O'Reilly, C. A. (1982).Variations in decision makers' use of information sources: The impact of quality and accessibility of information. The Academy of Management Journal, 25(4), 756–771.

Post, T. (2003).Empirical tests for stochastic dominance efficiency. Journal of Finance, 58(5), 1905–1931.

Redman, T. (2001).Data quality: The field guide, 2001. Newton, Massachusetts: Digital Press.

Veronesi, P. (2000).How does information quality affect stock returns? Journal of Finance, 55(2), 807–837.

Wang, R. Y. (1998).A product perspective on total data quality management. Communications of the ACM, 41(2), 58–65.

數據

Fig. 1. The rating space of Example 1 .
Fig. 3. The YTD rates of returns of non-dominated classes and dominated classes (≤).
Fig. 4. The YTD rates of returns of strictly non-dominated classes and strictly dominated classes (b).Table 2

參考文獻

相關文件

¾ For investment and holding companies, stock, commodity and bullion brokers, and miscellaneous financial services, manpower requirement is projected to increase from 62 500 in 2001

The above information is for discussion and reference only and should not be treated as investment

 Warrants are an instrument which gives investors the right – but not the obligation – to buy or sell the underlying assets at a pre- set price on or before a specified date.

Financial Analysis (i) Calculate ratios and comment on a company’s profitability, liquidity, solvency, management efficiency and return on investment: mark-up, inventory

Improve macro-average F-measure: 0.333 → 0.511 Five-fold cross validation for better thresholds Threshold T j = average of five thresholds. Tuning threshold significantly

Efficient training relies on designing optimization algorithms by incorporating the problem structure Many issues about multi-core and distributed linear classification still need to

CAST: Using neural networks to improve trading systems based on technical analysis by means of the RSI financial indicator. Performance of technical analysis in growth and small

CAST: Using neural networks to improve trading systems based on technical analysis by means of the RSI financial indicator. Performance of technical analysis in growth and small