• 沒有找到結果。

標的物不可交易下的選擇權評價(1/3)

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "標的物不可交易下的選擇權評價(1/3)"

Copied!
10
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

行政院國家科學委員會專題研究計畫 期中進度報告

標的物不可交易下的選擇權評價(1/3)

計畫類別: 個別型計畫 計畫編號: NSC92-2416-H-002-018- 執行期間: 92 年 08 月 01 日至 93 年 07 月 31 日 執行單位: 國立臺灣大學國際企業學系暨研究所 計畫主持人: 洪茂蔚 報告類型: 精簡報告 處理方式: 本計畫可公開查詢

中 華 民 國 93 年 5 月 26 日

(2)

™íÓ.ª>q-í²ÏžÇg (1

/3)

Valuation of Options When Underlying

Assets are Non-tradable(1

/3)

Abstract

One of the most difficult features of pricing weather derivatives is that the mar-ket is incomplete. This project presents a new method for pricing weather deriva-tives in an incomplete market. The proposed method has two advantages shown in only a few of the models discussed in other weather-related articles. First, the method for pricing assets in an incomplete market is used to overcome the non-tradable feature of the underlying assets of the weather derivatives in which the no-arbitrage method breaks down. Second, an efficient analytical method is incor-porated into the proposed model to make the Asian-type payout of weather deriva-tives much easier to evaluate than by any other numerical methods.

(3)

1

Introduction

Weather derivatives represent probably one of the most rapidly growing fields in derivatives research. More researchers are now focusing on the field of weather derivatives and have presented various kinds of assumptions and methods for pric-ing weather derivatives. Cao and Wei (1999) used a Lucas equilibrium framework approach to evaluate weather derivatives and found that a zero market price of risk should be associated with weather derivatives. Pirrong and Jermakyan (1999) pro-posed a mesh-based method to integrate valuation and risk management for power and weather derivatives. Alaton (2000) constructed a model for pricing weather derivatives with a payout that depends on temperature, and uses historical data to establish a stochastic process that describes the evolution of temperature. Davis (2001) used “marginal substitution value” or the “shadow price” method of math-ematical economics to investigate the pricing of weather derivatives.

Pricing weather derivatives raises two difficulties. First, the underlying assets of weather derivatives, such as temperature, humidity, rainfall and snowfall are non-tradable entities, and the non-tradability of these underlying assets prevent the creation of a risk-neutral portfolio through a delta hedging strategy. Meth-ods constructed under the assumption of an incomplete market will be applied to compensate for this drawback. Second, weather derivative contracts, such as HDDs (Heating Degree Days) or CDDs (Cooling Degree Days), exhibit accumu-lative, geometric Brownian motion. The sum of geometric Brownian motions does not follow a geometric Brownian motion distribution. Pricing an option whose underlying asset follows the accumulation of geometric Brownian motions be-comes a type of Asian option which is known to be more complex than ordinary European-type options, making such weather derivatives difficult to price. The literature includes several methods such as the closed-form expression of Geman and Yor (1993) and Milesky and Posner (1998), the numerical methods of

(4)

bull and Wakeman (1991), Levy and Turnbull (1992) and Vorst (1992, 1996), and the Monte Carlo simulation method.

The purpose of this project is to address these difficulties. In a recent article, Cochrane and Sa´a-Requejo (2000) proposed the “discount factor” asset pricing method to evaluate uncertain payoffs. This type of valuation lies between the rigidity of model-based pricing and the looseness of no-arbitrage pricing. This method is suitable when preference-free approaches break down, such as non-trade or thin non-trade circumstances. By additionally restricting the discount factor by both the positivity constraint and the volatility constraint, the boundaries of the asset price have a smaller range than the boundaries of the general arbitrage; such bounds are called “good-deal bounds.” Since an exact solution for options that underlie non-tradable assets cannot be found, support is thus drawn from Cochrane and Sa´a-Requejo (2000) to find “good-deal bounds” for the weather derivatives. The idea of Geman and Yor (1993) is exploited because their formula is a more efficient analytical tool compared to that of other Asian option pricing methods, thus making the proposed weather derivative pricing formula a quasi-explicit one. The proposed formula has a closed form expression and can be used as easily as the Black and Scholes formula to price weather derivatives.

2

The Model

This section proposes a method to price call options, which is built on the assumption of market incompleteness and is applied in the weather market. How-ever, before this method can be applied to call options used in the weather market, the option payoffs of HDD and CDD must be introduced.

(5)

hdd(t)= max(κ − Υt, 0) (1)

cdd(t)= max(Υt−κ, 0) (2)

where

1. κ is reference temperature, usually set at 65oF (or 18oC).

2. Υt is the temperature on day t and is defined as the average value of the

maximum and the minimum temperatures of day t, Υt = Υ

(max)

t

(min)

t 2

A call option contract used in the weather market is often the accumulation of daily HDDs or CDDs over a specific period. Other kinds of monthly contracts may be the accumulation of daily temperature minus the exercise price specified by the trading parties.

Hn = n X t=1 hdd(t) (3) Cn = n X t=1 cdd(t) (4)

Consequently, the payoff of a call option is defined as follows:

HDD(T )= ξ max(Hn− K, 0) (5)

CDD(T )= ξ max(Cn− K, 0) (6)

(6)

where ξ is the nominal dollar amount.

Now that the basic payoff of a weather contract is defined, the call option can be priced using the proposed method. Let the temperatureΥt follow a geometric

Brownian motion. Given the original measure P, it can be expressed as follows:

dΥt

Υt

= µΥdt+ σΥBdBPt + σΥZdZ P

t . (7)

dΥtis expressed as the sum of two separate geometric Brownian motion processes

that divide the non-traded basis asset Υt into one hedgeable part and one

non-hedgable part. The hedgeable part is hedged using a proxy asset (St) to price it.

All price information on the hedgeable part of dΥt can be found by pricing dSt.

This proxy asset can be defined as follows:

dSt

St

= µsdt+ σsdBPt. (8)

To find a closed-form analytic solution for the call option used in the weather market, the accumulation ofΥtis expressed in continuous time and the average of

Υt between time t0and time t is defined as Wn(t):

Wn(t)= 1 t Z t t0 Υsds. (9)

The concept of a pricing kernel, Mt, will be used to price weather derivatives.

According to this pricing mechanism, the relationship between the price Coption,t

and the payoff Max(Wn(T ) − K, 0) for a call option will be described by the

(7)

Coption,t = ξEtP[

MT

Mt

max(Wn(T ) − K, 0)], (10)

where Wn(T ) is either the accumulation of the daily HDDs as in Eq. (3) or daily

CDDs as in Eq. (4) on the day of expiration. Restated, the exercise price K is subtracted from the terminal value of the accumulated daily index Wn(T ) and then

discounted back by MTMt to derive the price of the call option. In Equation (10),

ξ represents dollars per unit and it is always a constant in the proposed model.

For simplicity in calculation, we set it to 1 throughout the remaining part of this article.

Imposing the volatility constraint and positivity constraints on the stochastic dis-count factor enables the lower bound of the call option to be derived by solving the following minimization problem:

Coption,t = min M Et " MT Mt max(ST− K, 0) # , (11) st Wn(t)= EtP Mu Mt Wn(u) ! ; Mu > 0 ; 1 dtE P t dM2 M2 ≤ A 2, t ≤ u ≤ T, (12)

where A is the volatility constraint. Similarly, the upper bound of the call op-tion can be derived by solving the corresponding maximizaop-tion problem. These bounds are called the “good-deal” bounds for the call option.

The pricing kernel in this economy is

dMt Mt = −rdt − hsdBtP± q A2− h2 sdZ P t .

Hence, the lower bound of the call option that is priced when the market is incom-plete can be represented as follows:

(8)

Coption,t = EPt[MT Mt max(Wn(T ) − K, 0)] (13) = EP t [e −r(T −t)−1 2A 2(T −t)−hsBP T −t− √ A2−h2 sZPT −tmax(W n(T ) − K, 0)].

Equation (13) can be expressed as follows:

Coption,t = EtQ[e−r(T −t)max(Wn(T ) − K, 0)] (14)

where dΥtafter changing the measure, satisfies

dΥt Υt = µΥdt+ σΥBdBPt + σΥZdZ P t = (µΥ−σΥzhs−σΥZ q A2− h2 s)dt+ σΥBdB Q t + σΥZdZ Q t .

The payoff of Asian option Wn(T ) with strike price K, maturity T , and

averag-ing period [t0, T ] in Eq. (14) can be rewritten as follows:

Coption,t = e−r(T −t)EQt [max(Wn(T ) − K, 0)] (15)

where Wn(T )= T −t10

RT

t0 Υudu.

It can be shown that the payoff of the Asian option can be expressed as

Coption,t = EtQ[e−r(T −t)max(Wn(T ) − K, 0)] = e−r(T −t) T − t0 4Υt σ2 Υ c(δ)(h, q),

(9)

where σ2 Υ = σ2ΥB+ σ2ΥZ η =         hΥ− hs(ρ − a s A2 h2 s − 1p1 − ρ2)         σΥ ρ = corr dΥΥ,dS S ! = σσΥB Υ a=              +1 upper bound -1 lower bound δ = 2(rσ+ η)2 Υ − 1 h= σ 2 Υ 4 (T − t) q= σ 2Kˆ 4 = σ2( ˜K − ˜W n(t))t = σ2 4Υt [K(T − t0) − Z t t0 Υudu]. When q < 0, c(δ)(h, q) = 1 2(1+ δ)[e 2(1+δ)h− 1] − q. When q > 0, Z ∞ 0 e−λhc(δ)(h, q)dh= R 2q1 0 e −ttµ−δ2 −2(1 − 2qt)µ+δ2 +1dt λ(λ − 2 − 2δ)Γ(µ−δ2 − 1) , where µ= √

2λ+ δ2 andΓ(·) is the gamma function.

3

Conclusion

A new method is proposed to price weather derivatives. The proposed model explained in this article can function in an incomplete market and overcome the

(10)

difficulty of determining the payoff functions of weather derivatives over a strike period. This feature, a characteristic of Asian-style derivatives, was once thought to raise a complex problem for any pricing model. The fact that the proposed model also has a closed form solution facilitating pricing, it is easier to use than other simulation pricing methods, such as the Monte Carlo method.

參考文獻

相關文件

Lemma 2 An American call or a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock is never worth less than its intrinsic value.. • An American call cannot be worth less than its

• A knock-in option comes into existence if a certain barrier is reached.. • A down-and-in option is a call knock-in option that comes into existence only when the barrier is

[r]

• A call gives its holder the right to buy a number of the underlying asset by paying a strike price.. • A put gives its holder the right to sell a number of the underlying asset

• A put gives its holder the right to sell a number of the underlying asset for the strike price.. • An embedded option has to be traded along with the

• Use the Black-Scholes formula with the stock price reduced by the PV of the dividends.. • This essentially decomposes the stock price into a riskless one paying known dividends and

The bivariate binomial values with 270 time steps are compared with the values generated by Hilliard and Schwartz [1996], the Hull-White stochastic volatility model [1987], and

• The existence of different implied volatilities for options on the same underlying asset shows the Black-Scholes model cannot be literally true.