• 沒有找到結果。

Backward Induction on the RT Tree

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "Backward Induction on the RT Tree"

Copied!
81
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Backward Induction on the RT Tree

• After the RT tree is constructed, it can be used to price options by backward induction.

• Recall that each node keeps two variances h2max and h2min.

• We now increase that number to K equally spaced variances between h2max and h2min at each node.

• Besides the minimum and maximum variances, the other K − 2 variances in between are linearly interpolated.a

aLog-linear interpolation works better in practice (Lyuu & C. Wu (R90723065), 2005). Log-cubic interpolation works even better (C. Liu (R92922123), 2005).

(2)

Backward Induction on the RT Tree (continued)

• For example, if K = 3, then a variance of 10.5436 × 10−6

will be added between the maximum and minimum variances at node (2, 0) on p. 988.a

• In general, the kth variance at node (i, j) is h2min(i, j)+k h2max(i, j) − h2min(i, j)

K − 1 , k = 0, 1, . . . , K−1.

• Each interpolated variance’s jump parameter and branching probabilities can be computed as before.

aRepeated on p. 1008.

(3)

13.4809 13.4809

12.2883 12.2883

11.7170 11.7170

12.2846 10.5733

10.9645 10.9645

10.5697 10.5256

13.4644 10.1305

10.9600 10.9600

10.5215 10.5215

10.9603 10.1269

10.6042 09.7717

10.9553 10.9553

12.2700 10.5173

11.7005 10.1231

10.9511 10.9511

12.2662 10.5135

13.4438 10.9473

yt

4.60517 4.61564 4.62611 4.63658 4.64705 4.65752

4.59470

4.58423

4.57376 0.01047

1 1

2 2

1 1

1 1

2 2

1 1

2 1

2 1

1 1

(4)

Backward Induction on the RT Tree (concluded)

• Suppose a variance falls between two of the K variances during backward induction.

• Linear interpolation of the option prices corresponding to the two bracketing variances will be used as the

approximate option price.

• The above idea is reminiscent of the one in dealing with Asian options.a

aRecall p. 453.

(5)

Numerical Examples

• We next use the tree on p. 1008 to price a European call option with a strike price of 100 and expiring at date 3.

• Recall that the riskless interest rate is zero.

• Assume K = 2; hence there are no interpolated variances.

• The pricing tree is shown on p. 1011 with a call price of 0.66346.

– The branching probabilities needed in backward induction can be found on p. 1012.

(6)

5.37392 5.37392

3.19054 3.19054

3.19054 3.19054

2.11587 2.11587

1.20241 1.20241

1.05240 1.05240

1.05240 1.05240

0.66346 0.66346

0.52360 0.52360

0.26172 0.48366

0.00000 0.00000

0.13012 0.13012

0.14573 0.00000

0.00000 0.00000

0.00000 0.00000

0.00000 0.00000

0.00000 0.00000

St

100.00000 101.05240 102.11587 103.19054 104.27652 105.37392

98.95856

97.92797

96.90811

1 1

2 2

1 1

1 1

2 2

1 1

2 1

2 1

1 1

(7)

h2[i][j][0]

η[i][j][0]

rb[i][0]

10.9600 10.9600

10.9553 10.9553

10.5215 10.5215

10.9645 10.9645

10.9511 10.9511

12.2700 10.5173

10.9603 10.1269

10.5697 10.5256

12.2883 12.2883

13.4438 10.9473

12.2662 10.5135

11.7005 10.1231

10.6042 09.7717

13.4644 10.1305

12.2846 10.5733

11.7170 11.7170

13.4809 13.4809

h2[0][ ][ ]

1 1

1 1

1 1

2 2

1 1

2 1

2 1

1 1

2 2

η[0][ ][ ]

p[0][ ][ ][ ] 0

0

1

−1

3

−2

5

−3 rb[0][ ]

0.4974 0.4974 0.0000 0.0000 0.5026 0.5026

0.4972 0.4972 0.0004 0.0004 0.5024 0.5024 0.4775 0.4775 0.0400 0.0400 0.4825 0.4825 0.1237 0.1237 0.7499 0.7499 0.1264 0.1264

0.4970 0.4970 0.0008 0.0008 0.5022 0.5022 0.4773 0.1385 0.0404 0.7201 0.4823 0.1414 0.4596 0.1237 0.0760 0.7500 0.4644 0.1263 0.4777 0.4797 0.0396 0.0356 0.4827 0.4847 0.1387 0.1387 0.7197 0.7197 0.1416 0.1416

h2[1][ ][ ]

h2[2][ ][ ]

h2[3][ ][ ]

η[1][ ][ ]

η[2][ ][ ]

p[1][ ][ ][ ]

p[2][ ][ ][ ] rb[i][1]

h2[i][j][1]

η[i][j][1]

p[i][j][0][1] p[i][j][1][1]

p[i][j][0][0] p[i][j][1][0]

p[i][j][0][−1] p[i][j][1][−1]

rb[1][ ] rb[2][ ] rb[3][ ]

j

3 2 1 0

−1

−2

3 2 1 0

−1

−2 j

5 4 3 2

0

j

−3

−2

−1 1

(8)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• Let us derive some of the numbers on p. 1011.

• A gray line means the updated variance falls strictly between h2max and h2min.

• The option price for a terminal node at date 3 equals max(S3 − 100, 0), independent of the variance level.

• Now move on to nodes at date 2.

• The option price at node (2, 3) depends on those at nodes (3, 5), (3, 3), and (3, 1).

• It therefore equals

0.1387 × 5.37392 + 0.7197 × 3.19054 + 0.1416 × 1.05240 = 3.19054.

(9)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• Option prices for other nodes at date 2 can be computed similarly.

• For node (1, 1), the option price for both variances is

0.1237 × 3.19054 + 0.7499 × 1.05240 + 0.1264 × 0.14573 = 1.20241.

• Node (1, 0) is most interesting.

• We knew that a down move from it gives a variance of 0.000105609.

• This number falls between the minimum variance

0.000105173 and the maximum variance 0.0001227 at node (2,−1) on p. 1008.

(10)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• The option price corresponding to the minimum variance is 0 (p. 1011).

• The option price corresponding to the maximum variance is 0.14573.

• The equation

x × 0.000105173 + (1 − x) × 0.0001227 = 0.000105609 is satisfied by x = 0.9751.

• So the option for the down state is approximated by x × 0 + (1 − x) × 0.14573 = 0.00362.

(11)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• The up move leads to the state with option price 1.05240.

• The middle move leads to the state with option price 0.48366.

• The option price at node (1, 0) is finally calculated as

0.4775 × 1.05240 + 0.0400 × 0.48366 + 0.4825 × 0.00362 = 0.52360.

(12)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• A variance following an interpolated variance may exceed the maximum variance or be lower than the minimum variance.

• When this happens, the option price corresponding to the maximum or minimum variance will be used during backward induction.a

• This act tends to reduce the dynamic range of the variance, however.

aCakici & Topyan (2000).

(13)

Numerical Examples (concluded)

• Worse, an interpolated variance may choose a branch that goes into a node that is not reached in forward induction.a

• In this case, the algorithm fails.

• The RT algorithm does not have this problem.

– This is because all interpolated variances are involved in the forward-induction phase.

• It may be hard to calculate the implied β1 and β2 from option prices.b

aLyuu & C. Wu (R90723065) (2005).

bY. Chang (B89704039, R93922034) (2006).

(14)

Complexities of GARCH Models

a

• The RT algorithm explodes exponentially even for moderate n.b

• The mean-tracking tree of Lyuu and Wu (2005)

guarantees explosion not to happen for n not too large.

– That tree is similar to, but earlier than, the binomial-trinomial tree.c

– In fact, we can use the binomial-trinomial tree here, and everything goes through.d

aLyuu & C. Wu (R90723065) (2003, 2005).

bRecall p. 984.

cRecall pp. 763ff.

dContributed by Mr. Lu, Zheng-Liang (D00922011) on August 12, 2021.

(15)

Complexities of GARCH Models (continued)

• The next page summarizes the situations for many GARCH option pricing models other than NGARCH.

(16)

Complexities of GARCH Models (concluded)

a

Model Explosion Non-explosion

NGARCH β1 + β2n > 1 β1 + β2(

n + λ + c)2 ≤ 1 LGARCH β1 + β2n > 1 β1 + β2(

n + λ)2 ≤ 1 AGARCH β1 + β2n > 1 β1 + β2(

n + λ)2 ≤ 1 GJR-GARCH β1 + β2n > 1 β1 + (β2 + β3)(

n + λ)2 ≤ 1 TS-GARCH β1 + β2

n > 1 β1 + β2(λ +

n) ≤ 1 TGARCH β1 + β2

n > 1 β1 + (β2 + β3)(λ +

n) ≤ 1 Heston-Nandi β1 + β2(c − 12)2 > 1 β1 + β2c2 ≤ 1

& c ≤ 12

VGARCH β1 + (β2/4) > 1 β1 ≤ 1

aY. C. Chen (R95723051) (2008); Y. C. Chen (R95723051), Lyuu, &

Wen (D94922003) (2012).

(17)

Obtaining Profit and Loss of Delta Hedge

• Profit and loss of any hedging strategy should be

calculated under the real-world probability measure.a

• But hedging parameters such as delta should be computed under the risk-neutral measure.

• Say we want the distribution of profit and loss for the delta hedge under the GARCH model.

• If a tree is built for each sampled stock price to obtain the delta, the complexity will be astronomical.b

• How to do it efficiently?c

aRecall p. 712.

bAugustyniak, Badescu, & Guo (2021).

cLu (D00922011), Lyuu, & Yang (D09922005) (2021).

(18)

Introduction to Term Structure Modeling

(19)

The fox often ran to the hole by which they had come in, to find out if his body was still thin enough to slip through it.

— Grimm’s Fairy Tales

(20)

And the worst thing you can have is models and spreadsheets.

— Warren Buffet (2008, May 3) Renaissance is 100% model driven.a James Simons (2015, May 13, 37:09)

ahttps://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QNznD9hMEh0

(21)

Outline

• Use the binomial interest rate tree to model stochastic term structure.

– Illustrates the basic ideas underlying future models.

– Applications are generic in that pricing and hedging methodologies can be easily adapted to other models.

• Although the idea is similar to the earlier one used in option pricing, the current task is more complicated.

– The evolution of an entire term structure, not just a single stock price, is to be modeled.

– Interest rates of various maturities cannot evolve arbitrarily, or arbitrage profits may occur.

(22)

Goals

• A stochastic interest rate model performs two tasks.

– Provides a stochastic process that defines future term structures without arbitrage profits.

– “Consistent” with the observed term structures.

(23)

History

• The methodology was founded by Merton (1970).

• Modern interest rate modeling is often traced to 1977 when Vasicek and Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross developed simultaneously their influential models.

• Early models have fitting problems because they may not price today’s benchmark bonds correctly.

• An alternative approach pioneered by Ho and Lee (1986) makes fitting the market yield curve mandatory.

• Models based on such a paradigm are called arbitrage-free or no-arbitrage models.a

aSomewhat misleadingly.

(24)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree

• Goal is to construct a no-arbitrage interest rate tree consistent with the yields and/or yield volatilities of zero-coupon bonds of all maturities.

– This procedure is called calibration.a

• Pick a binomial tree model in which the logarithm of the future short rate obeys the binomial distribution.

– Like the CRR tree for pricing options.

• The limiting distribution of the short rate at any future time is hence lognormal.

aDerman (2004), “complexity without calibration is pointless.”

(25)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree (continued)

• A binomial tree of future short rates is constructed.

• Every short rate is followed by two short rates in the following period.

• In the figure on p. 1031, node A coincides with the start of period j during which the short rate r is in effect.

• At the conclusion of period j, a new short rate goes into effect for period j + 1.

(26)

r

* r

0.5

j rh

0.5 A

B

C

period j − 1 period j period j + 1 time j − 1 time j

(27)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree (continued)

• This may take one of two possible values:

– r: the “low” short-rate outcome at node B.

– rh: the “high” short-rate outcome at node C.

• Each branch has a 50% chance of occurring in a risk-neutral economy.

• We require that the paths combine as the binomial process unfolds.

• Tuckman (2002) attributes this model to Salomon Brothers.

(28)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree (continued)

• The short rate r can go to rh and r with equal

risk-neutral probability 1/2 in a period of length Δt.

• Hence the volatility of ln r after Δt time isa σ = 1

2

1

Δt ln

rh r



. (138)

• Above, σ is annualized, whereas r and rh are period based.

aSee Exercise 23.2.3 in text.

(29)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree (continued)

• Note that

rh

r = e

Δt.

• Thus greater volatility, hence uncertainty, leads to larger rh/r and wider ranges of possible short rates.

• The ratio rh/r may depend on time if the volatility is a function of time.

• Note that rh/r has nothing to do with the current short rate r if σ is independent of r.

(30)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree (continued)

• In general there are j possible rates for period j,a rj, rjvj, rjvj2, . . . , rjvjj−1,

where

vj = eΔ j

Δt (139)

is the multiplicative ratio for the rates in period j (see figure on next page).

• We shall call rj the baseline rates.

• The subscript j in σj above is meant to emphasize that the short rate volatility may be time dependent.

aNot j + 1.

(31)

Baseline rates

A C

B B

C

C

D

D D H2 D

H L2 2

H L3 3

H L3 32 H1

H3

(32)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree (concluded)

• In the limit, the short rate follows

r(t) = μ(t) eσ(t) W (t). (140) – The (percent) short rate volatility σ(t) is a

deterministic function of time.

• The expected value of r(t) equals μ(t) eσ(t)2(t/2).

• Hence a declining short rate volatility is usually imposed to preclude the short rate from assuming implausibly high values.

• Incidentally, this is how the binomial interest rate tree achieves mean reversion to some long-term mean.

(33)

Memory Issues

• Path independency: The term structure at any node is independent of the path taken to reach it.

• So only the baseline rates ri and the multiplicative ratios vi need to be stored in computer memory.

• This takes up only O(n) space.a

• Storing the whole tree would take up O(n2) space.

– Daily interest rate movements for 30 years require roughly (30 × 365)2/2 ≈ 6 × 107 double-precision floating-point numbers (half a gigabyte!).

aThroughout, n denotes the depth of the tree.

(34)

Set Things in Motion

• The abstract process is now in place.

• We need the yields to maturities of the riskless bonds that make up the benchmark yield curve and their volatilities.

• In the U.S., for example, the on-the-run yield curve

obtained by the most recently issued Treasury securities may be used as the benchmark curve.

(35)

Set Things in Motion (concluded)

• The term structure of (yield) volatilitiesa can be estimated from:

– Historical data (historical volatility).

– Or interest rate option prices such as cap prices (implied volatility).

• The binomial tree should be found that is consistent with both term structures.

• Here we focus on the term structure of interest rates.

aOr simply the volatility (term) structure.

(36)

Model Term Structures

• The model price is computed by backward induction.

• Refer back to the figure on p. 1031.

• Given that the values at nodes B and C are PB and PC, respectively, the value at node A is then

PB + PC

2(1 + r) + cash flow at node A.

• We compute the values column by column (see next page).

• This takes O(n2) time and O(n) space.

(37)

HL

A C

B

Cash flows:

B

C

C

D

D

D D

+

+ 2 2 H

1 2

2 1

= B

+ 2 2

HL

2 3

2 1

= B

H

HL2

+ 2 2

HL

3 4

2 1

?

2

D

21

22

23

24

(38)

Term Structure Dynamics

• An n-period zero-coupon bond’s price can be computed by assigning $1 to every node at time n and then

applying backward induction.

• Repeat this step for n = 1, 2, . . . to obtain the market discount function implied by the tree.

• The tree therefore determines a term structure.

• It also contains a term structure dynamics.

– Taking any node in the tree as the new root induces a binomial interest rate tree and a term structure.

(39)

Sample Term Structure

• We shall construct interest rate trees consistent with the sample term structure in the table below.

– This is calibration (the reverse of pricing).

• Assume the short rate volatility is such that v =Δ rh

r = 1.5, independent of time.

Period 1 2 3

Spot rate (%) 4 4.2 4.3

One-period forward rate (%) 4 4.4 4.5

Discount factor 0.96154 0.92101 0.88135

(40)

An Approximate Calibration Scheme

• Start with the implied one-period forward rates.

• Equate the expected short rate with the forward rate.a

• For the first period, the forward rate is today’s one-period spot rate.

• In general, let fj denote the forward rate in period j.

• This forward rate can be derived from the market discount function viab

fj = d(j)

d(j + 1) − 1.

aSee Exercise 5.6.6 in text for the motivation.

bSee Exercise 5.6.3 in text.

(41)

An Approximate Calibration Scheme (continued)

• As the ith short rate rjvji−1, 1 ≤ i ≤ j, occurs with probability 2−(j−1) j−1

i−1

, we set up

j i=1

2−(j−1)

j − 1 i − 1



rjvji−1 = fj.

• Thus

rj =

 2

1 + vj

j−1

fj. (141)

• This binomial interest rate tree is trivial to set up (implicitly), in O(n) time.

(42)

An Approximate Calibration Scheme (continued)

• The ensuing tree for the sample term structure appears in figure on the next page.

• For example, the price of the zero-coupon bond paying

$1 at the end of the third period is

1

4 × 1 1.04 ×

 1

1.0352 ×

 1

1.0288 + 1 1.0432



+ 1

1.0528 ×

 1

1.0432 + 1 1.0648



or 0.88155, which exceeds discount factor 0.88135.

• The tree is not calibrated.

(43)

4.0%

3.52%

2.88%

5.28%

4.32%

6.48%

Baseline rates

A C

B B

C

C

D

D

D

D

period 2 period 3 period 1

4.0% 4.4% 4.5%

Implied forward rates:

(44)

An Approximate Calibration Scheme (concluded)

• This bias is inherent: The tree overprices the bonds.a

• Suppose we replace the baseline rates rj by rjvj.

• Then the resulting tree underprices the bonds.b

• The true baseline rates are thus bounded between rj

and rjvj.

aSee Exercise 23.2.4 in text.

bLyuu & C. Wang (F95922018) (2009, 2011).

(45)

Issues in Calibration

• The model prices generated by the binomial interest rate tree should match the observed market prices.

• Perhaps the most crucial aspect of model building.

• Treat the backward induction for the model price of the m-period zero-coupon bond as computing some function f (rm) of the unknown baseline rate rm for period m.

• A root-finding method is applied to solve f(rm) = P for rm given the zero’s price P and r1, r2, . . . , rm−1.

• This procedure is carried out for m = 1, 2, . . . , n.

• It runs in O(n3) time.

(46)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree Calibration

• Calibration can be accomplished in O(n2) time by the use of forward induction.a

• The scheme records how much $1 at a node contributes to the model price.

• This number is called the state price.b

– It is the price of a state contingent claim that pays

$1 at that particular node (state) and 0 elsewhere.

• The column of state prices will be established by moving forward from time 0 to time n.

aJamshidian (1991).

bRecall p. 212. Alternative names are the Arrow-Debreu price and Green’s function.

(47)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree Calibration (continued)

• Suppose we are at time j and there are j + 1 nodes.

– P1, P2, . . . , Pj are the known state prices at the earlier time j − 1.

– The unknown baseline rate for period j is r = rΔ j. – The known multiplicative ratio is v = vΔ j.

– The rates for period j are thus r, rv, . . . , rvj−1.a

• By definition, j

i=1 Pi is the price of the (j − 1)-period zero-coupon bond.

• We want to find r based on P1, P2, . . . , Pj and the price of the j-period zero-coupon bond.

aRecall p. 1036, repeated on next page with j = 3.

(48)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree Calibration (continued)

Baseline rates

A C

B B

C

C

D

D D H2 D

H L2 2

H L3 3

H L3 32 H1

H3

(49)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree Calibration (continued)

• One dollar at time j has a known market value of 1/[ 1 + S(j) ]j, where S(j) is the j-period spot rate.

• Alternatively, this dollar has a present value of g(r) =Δ P1

(1 + r) + P2

(1 + rv) + P3

(1 + rv2) +· · · + Pj

(1 + rvj−1) (see the next plot).

• So we solve

g(r) = 1

[ 1 + S(j) ]j (142) for r.

(50)

1

1

P

i

rv

i1

(51)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree Calibration (continued)

• Given a decreasing market discount function, a unique positive solution for r is guaranteed.

• The state prices at time j can now be calculated (see panel (a) of the next page with j = 2).

• We call a tree with these state prices a binomial state price tree (see panel (b) of the next page).

• The calibrated tree is depicted on p. 1058.

(52)

A C B

B

C

C

D

D D

D 4.00%

3.526%

2.895%

0.480769

0.460505

0.228308 A

C B

C

C

D

D D D

B

period 2 period 3 period 1

4.0% 4.4% 4.5%

Implied forward rates:

0.480769 1

0.112832

(b)

0.333501

0.327842

0.107173 0.232197

(a) 1

H

HL

2 HL

2

2 1

= B

2 H

2 HL

1 2

2 1

= B = B

2 1 2

H

1

2 1

= B

21

22

(53)

4.00%

3.526%

2.895%

5.289%

4.343%

6.514%

A

C B

C

C

D

D D D

B

period 2 period 3 period 1

4.0% 4.4% 4.5%

Implied forward rates:

(54)

Binomial Interest Rate Tree Calibration (concluded)

• Use the Newton-Raphson method to solve for the r in Eq. (142) on p. 1054 as g(r) is easy to evaluate.

• The monotonicity and the convexity of g(r) also facilitate root finding.

• The total running time is O(n2), as each root-finding routine consumes O(j) time.

• With a good initial guess,a the Newton-Raphson method converges in only a few steps.b

aSuch as rj = ( 2

1+vj )j−1 fj on p. 1046.

bLyuu (1999).

(55)

A Numerical Example

• One dollar at the end of the second period should have a present value of 0.92101 by the sample term structure.

• The baseline rate for the second period, r2, satisfies 0.480769

1 + r2 + 0.480769

1 + 1.5 × r2 = 0.92101.

• The result is r2 = 3.526%.

• This is used to derive the next column of state prices shown in panel (b) on p. 1057 as 0.232197, 0.460505, and 0.228308.

• Their sum matches the market discount factor 0.92101.

(56)

A Numerical Example (concluded)

• The baseline rate for the third period, r3, satisfies 0.232197

1 + r3 + 0.460505

1 + 1.5 × r3 + 0.228308

1 + (1.5)2 × r3 = 0.88135.

• The result is r3 = 2.895%.

• Now, redo the calculation on p. 1047 using the new rates:

1 4× 1

1.04×

 1

1.03526 ×

 1

1.02895 + 1 1.04343



+ 1

1.05289 ×

 1

1.04343 + 1 1.06514



,

which equals 0.88135, an exact match.

• The tree on p. 1058 prices without bias the benchmark securities.

(57)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds

• Model prices by the calibrated tree seldom match the market prices of nonbenchmark bonds.

• The incremental return over the benchmark bonds is called spread.

• If we add the spread uniformly over the short rates in the tree, the model price will equal the market price.

• We will apply the spread concept to option-free bonds next.

(58)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (continued)

• We illustrate the idea with an example.

• Start with the tree on p. 1064.

• Consider a security with cash flow Ci at time i for i = 1, 2, 3.

• Its model price is p(s), which is equal to

1

1.04 + s ×



C1 + 1

2 × 1

1.03526 + s ×



C2 + 1 2

 C3

1.02895 + s + C3 1.04343 + s



+

1

2 × 1

1.05289 + s ×



C2 + 1 2

 C3

1.04343 + s + C3 1.06514 + s



.

• Given a market price of P , the spread is the s that solves P = p(s).

(59)

4.00%+I

3.526%+I

2.895%+I

5.289%+I

4.343%+I

6.514%+I

A C

B

period 2 period 3 period 1

4.0% 4.4% 4.5%

Implied forward rates:

B

C

C

D

D D D

(60)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (continued)

• The model price p(s) is a monotonically decreasing, convex function of s.

• Employ any root-finding method to solve p(s) − P = 0

for s.

• But a quick look at the equation for p(s) reveals that evaluating p(s) directly is infeasible.

• Fortunately, the tree can be used to evaluate both p(s) and p(s) during backward induction.

(61)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (continued)

• Consider an arbitrary node A in the tree associated with the short rate r.

• While computing the model price p(s), a price pA(s) is computed at A.

• Prices computed at A’s two successor nodes B and C are discounted by r + s to obtain pA(s) as follows,

pA(s) = c + pB(s) + pC(s) 2(1 + r + s) , where c denotes the cash flow at A.

(62)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (continued)

• To compute pA(s) as well, node A calculates pA(s) = pB(s) + pC(s)

2(1 + r + s) pB(s) + pC(s) 2(1 + r + s)2 .

(143)

• This is easy if pB(s) and pC(s) are also computed at nodes B and C.

• When A is a terminal node, simply use the payoff function for pA(s).a

aContributed by Mr. Chou, Ming-Hsin (R02723073) on May 28, 2014.

(63)

1 1 ? I

= B

1 1 ?L I

= B

1 1? ?L2 ID

1 1 = I

= B

1 1 >L I

= B

1 1 > I

= B

1 1= > IB2

1 1= ? IB2

1 1= ?L IB2

1 1

?

?L2 I

D

2

1 1= >L IB2

1 1= = IB2

A C

B B

C

C

D

D D D

A C

B B

C

C

D

D D D

(a) (b)

A

C (c)

F I*= B

B F I ? F I F I

)= B *2 1=( ) H I+( )B

F I F I F I H I

F I F I

)= B = B = B*2 1( ) +( ) 2 1*( )H I+( )2

F I+= B

F I+= B

F I*= B

=

>

?

=

>

?

H

(64)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (continued)

• Apply the above procedure inductively to yield p(s) and p(s) at the root (p. 1068).

• This is called the differential tree method.a – Similar ideas can be found in automatic

differentiationb (AD) and backpropagationc in artificial neural networks.

• The total running time is O(n2).

• The memory requirement is O(n).

aLyuu (1999).

bRall (1981).

cWerbos (1974); Rumelhart, Hinton, & Williams (1986).

(65)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (continued)

Number of Running Number of Number of Running Number of partitions n time (s) iterations partitions time (s) iterations

500 7.850 5 10500 3503.410 5

1500 71.650 5 11500 4169.570 5

2500 198.770 5 12500 4912.680 5

3500 387.460 5 13500 5714.440 5

4500 641.400 5 14500 6589.360 5

5500 951.800 5 15500 7548.760 5

6500 1327.900 5 16500 8502.950 5

7500 1761.110 5 17500 9523.900 5

8500 2269.750 5 18500 10617.370 5

9500 2834.170 5 . . . . . . . . . . . .

75MHz Sun SPARCstation 20.

(66)

Spread of Nonbenchmark Bonds (concluded)

• Consider a three-year, 5% bond with a market price of 100.569.

• Assume the bond pays annual interest.

• The spread is 50 basis points over the tree.a

• Note that the idea of spread does not assume parallel shifts in the term structure.

• It also differs from the yield spread (p. 133) and static spread (p. 134) of the nonbenchmark bond over an otherwise identical benchmark bond.

aSee plot on the next page.

(67)

4.50%

100.569 A

C B

5 5 105

Cash flows:

B

C

C

D

D D 4.026% D

3.395%

5.789%

4.843%

7.014%

105

105

105

105 106.552

105.150

103.118 106.754

103.436

(68)

More Applications of the Differential Tree: Calculating Implied Volatility (in seconds)

a

American call American put

Number of Running Number of Number of Running Number of partitions time iterations partitions time iterations

100 0.008210 2 100 0.013845 3

200 0.033310 2 200 0.036335 3

300 0.072940 2 300 0.120455 3

400 0.129180 2 400 0.214100 3

500 0.201850 2 500 0.333950 3

600 0.290480 2 600 0.323260 2

700 0.394090 2 700 0.435720 2

800 0.522040 2 800 0.569605 2

Intel 166MHz Pentium, running on Microsoft Windows 95.

aLyuu (1999).

(69)

Fixed-Income Options

• Consider a 2-year 99 European call on the 3-year, 5%

Treasury.

• Assume the Treasury pays annual interest.

• From p. 1075 the 3-year Treasury’s price minus the $5 interest at year 2 are $102.046, $100.630, and $98.579.

– The accrued interest is not included as it belongs to the bond seller.

• Now compare the strike price against the bond prices.

• The call is in the money in the first two scenarios out of the money in the third.

(70)

A

C B

B

C

C

D

D D D

105

105

105

105 4.00%

101.955 1.458

3.526%

102.716 2.258

2.895%

102.046 3.046

5.289%

99.350 0.774

4.343%

100.630 1.630 6.514%

98.579 0.000 (a)

A

C B

B

C

C

D

D D D

105

105

105

105 4.00%

101.955 0.096

3.526%

102.716 0.000

2.895%

102.046 0.000

5.289%

99.350 0.200

4.343%

100.630 0.000 6.514%

98.579 0.421 (b)

(71)

Fixed-Income Options (continued)

• The option value is calculated to be $1.458 on p. 1075(a).

• European interest rate puts can be valued similarly.

• Consider a two-year 99 European put on the same security.

• At expiration, the put is in the money only when the Treasury is worth $98.579.

• The option value is computed to be $0.096 on p. 1075(b).

(72)

Fixed-Income Options (concluded)

• The present value of the strike price is PV(X) = 99 × 0.92101 = 91.18.

• The Treasury is worth B = 101.955.

• The present value of the interest payments during the life of the options isa

PV(I) = 5 × 0.96154 + 5 × 0.92101 = 9.41275.

• The call and the put are worth C = 1.458 and P = 0.096, respectively.

• The put-call parity is preserved:

C = P + B − PV(I) − PV(X).

(73)

Delta or Hedge Ratio

• How much does the option price change in response to changes in the price of the underlying bond?

• This relation is called delta (or hedge ratio), defined as Oh − O

Ph − P .

• In the above Ph and P denote the bond prices if the short rate moves up and down, respectively.

• Similarly, Oh and O denote the option values if the short rate moves up and down, respectively.

(74)

Delta or Hedge Ratio (concluded)

• Delta measures the sensitivity of the option value to changes in the underlying bond price.

• So it shows how to hedge one with the other.

• Take the call and put on p. 1075 as examples.

• Their deltas are

0.774 − 2.258

99.350 − 102.716 = 0.441, 0.200 − 0.000

99.350 − 102.716 = −0.059,

respectively.

(75)

Volatility Term Structures

• The binomial interest rate tree can be used to calculate the yield volatility of zero-coupon bonds.

• Consider an n-period zero-coupon bond.

• First find its yield to maturity yh (y, respectively) at the end of the initial period if the short rate rises

(declines, respectively).

• The yield volatility for our model is defined as 1

2 ln

yh y



. (144)

(76)

Volatility Term Structures (continued)

• For example, take the tree on p. 1058 (repeated on next page).

• The two-year zero’s yield at the end of the first period is 5.289% if the rate rises and 3.526% if the rate declines.

• Its yield volatility is therefore 1

2 ln

0.05289 0.03526



= 20.273%.

(77)

Volatility Term Structures (continued)

4.00%

3.526%

2.895%

5.289%

4.343%

6.514%

A

C B

C

C

D

D D D

B

period 2 period 3 period 1

4.0% 4.4% 4.5%

Implied forward rates:

(78)

Volatility Term Structures (continued)

• Consider the three-year zero-coupon bond.

• If the short rate rises, the price of the zero one year from now will be

1

2 × 1

1.05289 ×

 1

1.04343 + 1 1.06514



= 0.90096.

• Thus its yield is 

1

0.90096 − 1 = 0.053531.

• If the short rate declines, the price of the zero one year from now will be

1

2 × 1

1.03526 ×

 1

1.02895 + 1 1.04343



= 0.93225.

(79)

Volatility Term Structures (continued)

• Thus its yield is 

1

0.93225 − 1 = 0.0357.

• The yield volatility is hence 1

2 ln

0.053531 0.0357



= 20.256%, slightly less than the one-year yield volatility.

• This is consistent with the reality that longer-term bonds typically have lower yield volatilities than shorter-term bonds.a

• The procedure can be repeated for longer-term zeros to obtain their yield volatilities.

aThe relation is reversed for price volatilities (duration).

(80)

0 100 200 300 400 500 Time period

0.1 0.101 0.102 0.103 0.104

Spot rate volatility

(Short rate volatility is flat at %10.)

(81)

Volatility Term Structures (concluded)

• We started with vi and then derived the volatility term structure.

• In practice, the steps are reversed.

• The volatility term structure is supplied by the user along with the term structure.

• The vi—hence the short rate volatilities via Eq. (139) on p. 1035—and the ri are then simultaneously

determined.

• The result is the Black-Derman-Toy (1990) model of Goldman Sachs.

參考文獻

相關文件

The bivariate binomial values with 270 time steps are compared with the values generated by Hilliard and Schwartz [1996], the Hull-White stochastic volatility model [1987], and

Based on the suggestions collected from the Principal Questionnaire and this questionnaire, feedback collected from various stakeholders through meetings and

• use Chapter 4 to: a) develop ideas of how to differentiate the classroom elements based on student readiness, interest and learning profile; b) use the exemplars as guiding maps to

The min-max and the max-min k-split problem are defined similarly except that the objectives are to minimize the maximum subgraph, and to maximize the minimum subgraph respectively..

Given a graph and a set of p sources, the problem of finding the minimum routing cost spanning tree (MRCT) is NP-hard for any constant p > 1 [9].. When p = 1, i.e., there is only

• The existence of different implied volatilities for options on the same underlying asset shows the Black-Scholes model cannot be literally true... Binomial Tree Algorithms for

• The existence of different implied volatilities for options on the same underlying asset shows the Black-Scholes model cannot be literally true.... Binomial Tree Algorithms

• When this happens, the option price corresponding to the maximum or minimum variance will be used during backward induction... Numerical