• 沒有找到結果。

Foundations of Term Structure Modeling

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "Foundations of Term Structure Modeling"

Copied!
97
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Foundations of Term Structure Modeling

(2)

[Meriwether] scoring especially high marks in mathematics — an indispensable subject for a bond trader.

— Roger Lowenstein, When Genius Failed (2000)

(3)

[The] fixed-income traders I knew seemed smarter than the equity trader [· · · ] there’s no competitive edge to being smart in the equities business[.]

— Emanuel Derman, My Life as a Quant (2004) Bond market terminology was designed less to convey meaning than to bewilder outsiders.

— Michael Lewis, The Big Short (2011)

(4)

Terminology

• A period denotes a unit of elapsed time.

– Viewed at time t, the next time instant refers to time t + dt in the continuous-time model and time t + 1 in the discrete-time case.

• Bonds will be assumed to have a par value of one — unless stated otherwise.

• The time unit for continuous-time models will usually be measured by the year.

(5)

Standard Notations

The following notation will be used throughout.

t: a point in time.

r(t): the one-period riskless rate prevailing at time t for repayment one period later.a

P (t, T ): the present value at time t of one dollar at time T .

aAlternatively, the instantaneous spot rate, or short rate, at time t.

(6)

Standard Notations (continued)

r(t, T ): the (T − t)-period interest rate prevailing at time t stated on a per-period basis and compounded once per period.a

F (t, T, M ): the forward price at time t of a forward

contract that delivers at time T a zero-coupon bond maturing at time M ≥ T .

aIn other words, the (T − t)-period spot rate at time t.

(7)

Standard Notations (concluded)

f (t, T, L): the L-period forward rate at time T implied at time t stated on a per-period basis and compounded once per period.

f (t, T ): the one-period or instantaneous forward rate at time T as seen at time t stated on a per period basis and compounded once per period.

• It is f(t, T, 1) in the discrete-time model and f (t, T, dt) in the continuous-time model.

• Note that f(t, t) equals the short rate r(t).

(8)

Fundamental Relations

• The price of a zero-coupon bond equals

P (t, T ) =

⎧⎨

(1 + r(t, T ))−(T −t), in discrete time, e−r(t,T )(T −t), in continuous time.

• r(t, T ) as a function of T defines the spot rate curve at time t.

• By definition,

f (t, t) =

⎧⎨

r(t, t + 1), in discrete time, r(t, t), in continuous time.

(9)

Fundamental Relations (continued)

• Forward prices and zero-coupon bond prices are related:

F (t, T, M ) = P (t, M )

P (t, T ) , T ≤ M. (115) – The forward price equals the future value at time T

of the underlying asset.a

• Equation (115) holds whether the model is discrete-time or continuous-time.

aSee Exercise 24.2.1 of the textbook for proof.

(10)

Fundamental Relations (continued)

• Forward rates and forward prices are related definitionally by

f (t, T, L) =

 1

F (t, T, T + L)

1/L

− 1 =

 P (t, T ) P (t, T + L)

1/L

− 1 (116)

in discrete time.

– The analog to Eq. (116) under simple compounding is f (t, T, L) = 1

L

 P (t, T )

P (t, T + L) − 1

 .

(11)

Fundamental Relations (continued)

• In continuous time,

f (t, T, L) = −ln F (t, T, T + L)

L = ln(P (t, T )/P (t, T + L))

L (117)

by Eq. (115) on p. 969.

• Furthermore,

f (t, T, Δt) = ln(P (t, T )/P (t, T + Δt))

Δt → −∂ ln P (t, T )

∂T

= −∂P (t, T )/∂T P (t, T ) .

(12)

Fundamental Relations (continued)

• So

f (t, T ) ≡ lim

Δt→0f (t, T, Δt) = −∂P (t, T )/∂T

P (t, T ) , t ≤ T.

(118)

• Because Eq. (118) is equivalent to P (t, T ) = e

T

t f (t,s) ds, (119) the spot rate curve is

r(t, T ) =

 T

t f (t, s) ds T − t .

(13)

Fundamental Relations (concluded)

• The discrete analog to Eq. (119) is

P (t, T ) = 1

(1 + r(t))(1 + f (t, t + 1)) · · · (1 + f (t, T − 1)).

• The short rate and the market discount function are related by

r(t) = − ∂P (t, T )

∂T



T =t

.

(14)

Risk-Neutral Pricing

• Assume the local expectations theory.

• The expected rate of return of any riskless bond over a single period equals the prevailing one-period spot rate.

– For all t + 1 < T ,

Et[ P (t + 1, T ) ]

P (t, T ) = 1 + r(t). (120) – Relation (120) in fact follows from the risk-neutral

valuation principle.a

aTheorem 17 on p. 503.

(15)

Risk-Neutral Pricing (continued)

• The local expectations theory is thus a consequence of the existence of a risk-neutral probability π.

• Rewrite Eq. (120) as

Etπ[ P (t + 1, T ) ]

1 + r(t) = P (t, T ).

– It says the current market discount function equals the expected market discount function one period from now discounted by the short rate.

(16)

Risk-Neutral Pricing (continued)

• Apply the above equality iteratively to obtain

P (t, T )

= Etπ

 P (t + 1, T ) 1 + r(t)



= Etπ

 Et+1π [ P (t + 2, T ) ] (1 + r(t))(1 + r(t + 1))



= · · ·

= Etπ

 1

(1 + r(t))(1 + r(t + 1)) · · · (1 + r(T − 1))



. (121)

(17)

Risk-Neutral Pricing (concluded)

• Equation (120) on p. 974 can also be expressed as Et[ P (t + 1, T ) ] = F (t, t + 1, T ).

– Verify that with, e.g., Eq. (115) on p. 969.

• Hence the forward price for the next period is an unbiased estimator of the expected bond price.a

aBut the forward rate is not an unbiased estimator of the expected future short rate (p. 925).

(18)

Continuous-Time Risk-Neutral Pricing

• In continuous time, the local expectations theory implies P (t, T ) = Et

e

T

t r(s) ds

, t < T. (122)

• Note that etT r(s) ds is the bank account process, which denotes the rolled-over money market account.

(19)

Interest Rate Swaps

• Consider an interest rate swap made at time t (now) with payments to be exchanged at times t1, t2, . . . , tn.

• The fixed rate is c per annum.

• The floating-rate payments are based on the future annual rates f0, f1, . . . , fn−1 at times t0, t1, . . . , tn−1.

• For simplicity, assume ti+1 − ti is a fixed constant Δt for all i, and the notional principal is one dollar.

• If t < t0, we have a forward interest rate swap.

• The ordinary swap corresponds to t = t0.

(20)

Interest Rate Swaps (continued)

• The amount to be paid out at time ti+1 is (fi − c) Δt for the floating-rate payer.

• Simple rates are adopted here.

• Hence fi satisfies

P (ti, ti+1) = 1

1 + fiΔt.

(21)

Interest Rate Swaps (continued)

• The value of the swap at time t is thus n

i=1

Etπ

e

ti

t r(s) ds(fi−1 − c) Δt

=

n i=1

Etπ

e

ti

t r(s) ds

 1

P (ti−1, ti) − (1 + cΔt)



=

n i=1

[ P (t, ti−1) − (1 + cΔt) × P (t, ti) ]

= P (t, t0) − P (t, tn) − cΔt

n i=1

P (t, ti).

(22)

Interest Rate Swaps (concluded)

• So a swap can be replicated as a portfolio of bonds.

• In fact, it can be priced by simple present value calculations.

(23)

Swap Rate

• The swap rate, which gives the swap zero value, equals Sn(t) ≡ P (t, t0) − P (t, tn)

n

i=1 P (t, ti) Δt . (123)

• The swap rate is the fixed rate that equates the present values of the fixed payments and the floating payments.

• For an ordinary swap, P (t, t0) = 1.

(24)

The Term Structure Equation

• Let us start with the zero-coupon bonds and the money market account.

• Let the zero-coupon bond price P (r, t, T ) follow dP

P = μp dt + σp dW.

• At time t, short one unit of a bond maturing at time s1 and buy α units of a bond maturing at time s2.

(25)

The Term Structure Equation (continued)

• The net wealth change follows

−dP (r, t, s1) + α dP (r, t, s2)

= (−P (r, t, s1) μp(r, t, s1) + αP (r, t, s2) μp(r, t, s2)) dt + (−P (r, t, s1) σp(r, t, s1) + αP (r, t, s2) σp(r, t, s2)) dW.

• Pick

α ≡ P (r, t, s1) σp(r, t, s1) P (r, t, s2) σp(r, t, s2).

(26)

The Term Structure Equation (continued)

• Then the net wealth has no volatility and must earn the riskless return:

−P (r, t, s1) μp(r, t, s1) + αP (r, t, s2) μp(r, t, s2)

−P (r, t, s1) + αP (r, t, s2) = r.

• Simplify the above to obtain

σp(r, t, s1) μp(r, t, s2) − σp(r, t, s2) μp(r, t, s1)

σp(r, t, s1) − σp(r, t, s2) = r.

• This becomes

μp(r, t, s2) − r

σp(r, t, s2) = μp(r, t, s1) − r σp(r, t, s1) after rearrangement.

(27)

The Term Structure Equation (continued)

• Since the above equality holds for any s1 and s2, μp(r, t, s) − r

σp(r, t, s) ≡ λ(r, t) (124) for some λ independent of the bond maturity s.

• As μp = r + λσp, all assets are expected to appreciate at a rate equal to the sum of the short rate and a constant times the asset’s volatility.

• The term λ(r, t) is called the market price of risk.

• The market price of risk must be the same for all bonds to preclude arbitrage opportunities.

(28)

The Term Structure Equation (continued)

• Assume a Markovian short rate model, dr = μ(r, t) dt + σ(r, t) dW.

• Then the bond price process is also Markovian.

• By Eq. (14.15) on p. 202 of the textbook,

μp =



∂P

∂T + μ(r, t) ∂P

∂r + σ(r, t)2 2

2P

∂r2

 /P,

(125)

σp =



σ(r, t) ∂P

∂r



/P, (125)

subject to P ( · , T, T ) = 1.

(29)

The Term Structure Equation (concluded)

• Substitute μp and σp into Eq. (124) on p. 987 to obtain

∂P

∂T + [ μ(r, t) − λ(r, t) σ(r, t) ] ∂P

∂r + 1

2 σ(r, t)2 2P

∂r2 = rP.

(126)

• This is called the term structure equation.

• Once P is available, the spot rate curve emerges via r(t, T ) = −ln P (t, T )

T − t .

• Equation (126) applies to all interest rate derivatives, the difference being the terminal and the boundary conditions.

(30)

The Binomial Model

• The analytical framework can be nicely illustrated with the binomial model.

• Suppose the bond price P can move with probability q to P u and probability 1 − q to P d, where u > d:

P

* P d 1 − q

q j Pu

(31)

The Binomial Model (continued)

• Over the period, the bond’s expected rate of return is

μ ≡ qP u + (1 − q) P d

P − 1 = qu + (1 − q) d − 1.

(127)

• The variance of that return rate is

2 ≡ q(1 − q)(u − d)2. (128)

(32)

The Binomial Model (continued)

• In particular, the bond whose maturity is one period

away will move from a price of 1/(1 + r) to its par value

$1.

• This is the money market account modeled by the short rate r.

• The market price of risk is defined as λ ≡ (μ − r)/σ.

• As in the continuous-time case, it can be shown that λ is independent of the maturity of the bond (see text).

(33)

The Binomial Model (concluded)

• Now change the probability from q to p ≡ q − λ

q(1 − q) = (1 + r) − d

u − d , (129) which is independent of bond maturity and q.

– Recall the BOPM.

• The bond’s expected rate of return becomes pP u + (1 − p) P d

P − 1 = pu + (1 − p) d − 1 = r.

• The local expectations theory hence holds under the new probability measure p.

(34)

Numerical Examples

• Assume this spot rate curve:

Year 1 2

Spot rate 4% 5%

• Assume the one-year rate (short rate) can move up to 8% or down to 2% after a year:

4%

* 8%

j 2%

(35)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• No real-world probabilities are specified.

• The prices of one- and two-year zero-coupon bonds are, respectively,

100/1.04 = 96.154, 100/(1.05)2 = 90.703.

• They follow the binomial processes on p. 996.

(36)

Numerical Examples (continued)

90.703

* 92.593 (= 100/1.08)

j 98.039 (= 100/1.02) 96.154

* 100 j 100

The price process of the two-year zero-coupon bond is on the left; that of the one-year zero-coupon bond is on the right.

(37)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• The pricing of derivatives can be simplified by assuming investors are risk-neutral.

• Suppose all securities have the same expected one-period rate of return, the riskless rate.

• Then

(1 − p) × 92.593

90.703 + p × 98.039

90.703 − 1 = 4%,

where p denotes the risk-neutral probability of a down move in rates.

(38)

Numerical Examples (concluded)

• Solving the equation leads to p = 0.319.

• Interest rate contingent claims can be priced under this probability.

(39)

Numerical Examples: Fixed-Income Options

• A one-year European call on the two-year zero with a

$95 strike price has the payoffs, C

* 0.000 j 3.039

• To solve for the option value C, we replicate the call by a portfolio of x one-year and y two-year zeros.

(40)

Numerical Examples: Fixed-Income Options (continued)

• This leads to the simultaneous equations, x × 100 + y × 92.593 = 0.000, x × 100 + y × 98.039 = 3.039.

• They give x = −0.5167 and y = 0.5580.

• Consequently,

C = x × 96.154 + y × 90.703 ≈ 0.93 to prevent arbitrage.

(41)

Numerical Examples: Fixed-Income Options (continued)

• This price is derived without assuming any version of an expectations theory.

• Instead, the arbitrage-free price is derived by replication.

• The price of an interest rate contingent claim does not depend directly on the real-world probabilities.

• The dependence holds only indirectly via the current bond prices.

(42)

Numerical Examples: Fixed-Income Options (concluded)

• An equivalent method is to utilize risk-neutral pricing.

• The above call option is worth

C = (1 − p) × 0 + p × 3.039

1.04 ≈ 0.93,

the same as before.

• This is not surprising, as arbitrage freedom and the existence of a risk-neutral economy are equivalent.

(43)

Numerical Examples: Futures and Forward Prices

• A one-year futures contract on the one-year rate has a payoff of 100 − r, where r is the one-year rate at

maturity:

F

* 92 (= 100 − 8) j 98 (= 100 − 2)

• As the futures price F is the expected future payoff,a F = (1 − p) × 92 + p × 98 = 93.914.

aSee Exercise 13.2.11 of the textbook or p. 504.

(44)

Numerical Examples: Futures and Forward Prices (concluded)

• The forward price for a one-year forward contract on a one-year zero-coupon bond isa

90.703/96.154 = 94.331%.

• The forward price exceeds the futures price.b

aBy Eq. (115) on p. 969.

bRecall p. 448.

(45)

Equilibrium Term Structure Models

(46)

8. What’s your problem? Any moron can understand bond pricing models.

— Top Ten Lies Finance Professors Tell Their Students

(47)

Introduction

• This chapter surveys equilibrium models.

• Since the spot rates satisfy

r(t, T ) = −ln P (t, T ) T − t ,

the discount function P (t, T ) suffices to establish the spot rate curve.

• All models to follow are short rate models.

• Unless stated otherwise, the processes are risk-neutral.

(48)

The Vasicek Model

a

• The short rate follows

dr = β(μ − r) dt + σ dW.

• The short rate is pulled to the long-term mean level μ at rate β.

• Superimposed on this “pull” is a normally distributed stochastic term σ dW .

• Since the process is an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, E[ r(T ) | r(t) = r ] = μ + (r − μ) e−β(T −t) from Eq. (64) on p. 562.

aVasicek (1977).

(49)

The Vasicek Model (continued)

• The price of a zero-coupon bond paying one dollar at maturity can be shown to be

P (t, T ) = A(t, T ) e−B(t,T ) r(t), (130) where

A(t, T ) =

exp



(B(t,T )−T +t)(β2μ−σ2/2)

β2 σ2B(t,T )24β



if β = 0,

exp

 σ2(T −t)3 6



if β = 0.

and

B(t, T ) =

⎧⎨

1−e−β(T −t)

β if β = 0, T − t if β = 0.

(50)

The Vasicek Model (concluded)

• If β = 0, then P goes to infinity as T → ∞.

• Sensibly, P goes to zero as T → ∞ if β = 0.

• Even if β = 0, P may exceed one for a finite T .

• The spot rate volatility structure is the curve (∂r(t, T )/∂r) σ = σB(t, T )/(T − t).

• When β > 0, the curve tends to decline with maturity.

• The speed of mean reversion, β, controls the shape of the curve.

• Indeed, higher β leads to greater attenuation of volatility with maturity.

(51)

2 4 6 8 10 Term 0.05

0.1 0.15 0.2

Yield

humped

inverted

normal

(52)

The Vasicek Model: Options on Zeros

a

• Consider a European call with strike price X expiring at time T on a zero-coupon bond with par value $1 and maturing at time s > T .

• Its price is given by

P (t, s) N (x) − XP (t, T ) N (x − σv).

aJamshidian (1989).

(53)

The Vasicek Model: Options on Zeros (concluded)

• Above

x ≡ 1

σv ln

 P (t, s) P (t, T ) X



+ σv 2 , σv ≡ v(t, T ) B(T, s),

v(t, T )2

⎧⎨

σ2[1−e−2β(T −t)]

, if β = 0 σ2(T − t), if β = 0 .

• By the put-call parity, the price of a European put is XP (t, T ) N (−x + σv) − P (t, s) N(−x).

(54)

Binomial Vasicek

• Consider a binomial model for the short rate in the time interval [ 0, T ] divided into n identical pieces.

• Let Δt ≡ T/n and

p(r) ≡ 1

2 + β(μ − r)√ Δt

.

• The following binomial model converges to the Vasicek model,a

r(k + 1) = r(k) + σ√

Δt ξ(k), 0 ≤ k < n.

aNelson and Ramaswamy (1990).

(55)

Binomial Vasicek (continued)

• Above, ξ(k) = ±1 with

Prob[ ξ(k) = 1 ] =

⎧⎪

⎪⎨

⎪⎪

p(r(k)) if 0 ≤ p(r(k)) ≤ 1 0 if p(r(k)) < 0

1 if 1 < p(r(k))

.

• Observe that the probability of an up move, p, is a decreasing function of the interest rate r.

• This is consistent with mean reversion.

(56)

Binomial Vasicek (concluded)

• The rate is the same whether it is the result of an up move followed by a down move or a down move followed by an up move.

• The binomial tree combines.

• The key feature of the model that makes it happen is its constant volatility, σ.

(57)

The Cox-Ingersoll-Ross Model

a

• It is the following square-root short rate model:

dr = β(μ − r) dt + σ√

r dW. (131)

• The diffusion differs from the Vasicek model by a multiplicative factor

r .

• The parameter β determines the speed of adjustment.

• The short rate can reach zero only if 2βμ < σ2.

• See text for the bond pricing formula.

aCox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985).

(58)

Binomial CIR

• We want to approximate the short rate process in the time interval [ 0, T ].

• Divide it into n periods of duration Δt ≡ T/n.

• Assume μ, β ≥ 0.

• A direct discretization of the process is problematic because the resulting binomial tree will not combine.

(59)

Binomial CIR (continued)

• Instead, consider the transformed process x(r) ≡ 2√

r/σ.

• It follows

dx = m(x) dt + dW, where

m(x) ≡ 2βμ/(σ2x) − (βx/2) − 1/(2x).

• This new process has a constant volatility, and its associated binomial tree combines.

(60)

Binomial CIR (continued)

• Construct the combining tree for r as follows.

• First, construct a tree for x.

• Then transform each node of the tree into one for r via the inverse transformation

r = f (x) ≡ x2σ2 4 (see p. 1021).

• When x ≈ 0 (so r ≈ 0), the moments may not be matched well.a

aNawalkha and Beliaeva (2007).

(61)

x + 2

Δt f(x + 2

Δt)

 

x +

Δt f(x +

Δt)

   

x x f(x) f(x)

   

x −

Δt f(x −

Δt)

 

x − 2

Δt f(x − 2

Δt)

(62)

Binomial CIR (concluded)

• The probability of an up move at each node r is p(r) ≡ β(μ − r) Δt + r − r

r+ − r . (132)

– r+ ≡ f(x +

Δt) denotes the result of an up move from r.

– r ≡ f(x −

Δt) the result of a down move.

• Finally, set the probability p(r) to one as r goes to zero to make the probability stay between zero and one.

(63)

Numerical Examples

• Consider the process,

0.2 (0.04 − r) dt + 0.1√

r dW,

for the time interval [ 0, 1 ] given the initial rate r(0) = 0.04.

• We shall use Δt = 0.2 (year) for the binomial approximation.

• See p. 1024(a) for the resulting binomial short rate tree with the up-move probabilities in parentheses.

(64)

(0.472049150276)0.04

0.05988854382 (0.44081188025)

0.03155572809 (0.489789553691)

0.02411145618 (0.50975924867)

0.0713328157297 (0.426604457655)

0.08377708764

0.01222291236 0.01766718427

(0.533083330907) (0.472049150276)0.04

0.0494442719102

(0.455865503068) 0.0494442719102 (0.455865503068)

0.03155572809 (0.489789553691)

0.05988854382

0.04

0.02411145618

=

>

0.992031914837 0.984128889634 0.976293244408 0.968526861261 0.960831229521

0.992031914837 0.984128889634

0.976293244408 0.992031914837 0.990159879565

0.980492588317 0.970995502019 0.961665706744

0.993708727831 0.987391576942 0.981054487259 0.974702907786

0.988093738447 0.976486896485 0.965170249273

0.990159879565 0.980492588317

0.995189317343 0.990276851751 0.985271123591

0.993708727831 0.987391576942 0.98583472203 0.972116454453

0.996472798388 0.992781347933

0.983384173756

0.988093738447

0.995189317343

(65)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• Consider the node which is the result of an up move from the root.

• Since the root has x = 2

r(0)/σ = 4, this particular node’s x value equals 4 +

Δt = 4.4472135955.

• Use the inverse transformation to obtain the short rate x2 × (0.1)2

4 ≈ 0.0494442719102.

(66)

Numerical Examples (concluded)

• Once the short rates are in place, computing the probabilities is easy.

• Note that the up-move probability decreases as interest rates increase and decreases as interest rates decline.

– I suspect that

p(r) = A

Δt

r + B − C√

rΔt for some A, B, C > 0.a

• This phenomenon agrees with mean reversion.

• Convergence is quite good (see text).

aThanks to a lively class discussion on May 28, 2014.

(67)

A General Method for Constructing Binomial Models

a

• We are given a continuous-time process, dy = α(y, t) dt + σ(y, t) dW.

• Need to make sure the binomial model’s drift and diffusion converge to the above process.

• Set the probability of an up move to α(y, t) Δt + y − yd

yu − yd .

• Here yu ≡ y + σ(y, t)√

Δt and yd ≡ y − σ(y, t)√ Δt represent the two rates that follow the current rate y.

aNelson and Ramaswamy (1990).

(68)

A General Method (continued)

• The displacements are identical, at σ(y, t)√

Δt .

• But the binomial tree may not combine as σ(y, t)√

Δt − σ(yu, t + Δt)√ Δt

= −σ(y, t)√

Δt + σ(yd, t + Δt)√ Δt in general.

• When σ(y, t) is a constant independent of y, equality holds and the tree combines.

(69)

A General Method (continued)

• To achieve this, define the transformation x(y, t) ≡

 y

σ(z, t)−1 dz.

• Then x follows

dx = m(y, t) dt + dW for some m(y, t).a

• The diffusion term is now a constant, and the binomial tree for x combines.

aSee Exercise 25.2.13 of the textbook.

(70)

A General Method (concluded)

• The transformation is unique.a

• The probability of an up move remains

α(y(x, t), t) Δt + y(x, t) − yd(x, t) yu(x, t) − yd(x, t) ,

where y(x, t) is the inverse transformation of x(y, t) from x back to y.

• Note that

yu(x, t) ≡ y(x +

Δt, t + Δt), yd(x, t) ≡ y(x −

Δt, t + Δt).

aChiu (R98723059) (2012).

(71)

Examples

• The transformation is

 r

(σ√

z)−1 dz = 2 r σ for the CIR model.

• The transformation is

 S

(σz)−1 dz = ln S σ for the Black-Scholes model.

• The familiar binomial option pricing model in fact discretizes ln S not S.

(72)

On One-Factor Short Rate Models

• By using only the short rate, they ignore other rates on the yield curve.

• Such models also restrict the volatility to be a function of interest rate levels only.

• The prices of all bonds move in the same direction at the same time (their magnitudes may differ).

• The returns on all bonds thus become highly correlated.

• In reality, there seems to be a certain amount of independence between short- and long-term rates.

(73)

On One-Factor Short Rate Models (continued)

• One-factor models therefore cannot accommodate

nondegenerate correlation structures across maturities.

• Derivatives whose values depend on the correlation structure will be mispriced.

• The calibrated models may not generate term structures as concave as the data suggest.

• The term structure empirically changes in slope and curvature as well as makes parallel moves.

• This is inconsistent with the restriction that all

segments of the term structure be perfectly correlated.

(74)

On One-Factor Short Rate Models (concluded)

• Multi-factor models lead to families of yield curves that can take a greater variety of shapes and can better

represent reality.

• But they are much harder to think about and work with.

• They also take much more computer time—the curse of dimensionality.

• These practical concerns limit the use of multifactor models to two- or three-factor ones.

(75)

Options on Coupon Bonds

a

• Assume a one-factor short rate model.

• The price of a European option on a coupon bond can be calculated from those on zero-coupon bonds.

• Consider a European call expiring at time T on a bond with par value $1.

• Let X denote the strike price.

• The bond has cash flows c1, c2, . . . , cn at times t1, t2, . . . , tn, where ti > T for all i.

aJamshidian (1989).

(76)

Options on Coupon Bonds (continued)

• The payoff for the option is max

 n

i=1

ciP (r(T ), T, ti)



− X, 0

 .

• At time T , there is a unique value r for r(T ) that renders the coupon bond’s price equal the strike price X.

• This r can be obtained by solving X =

n i=1

ciP (r, T, ti) numerically for r.

(77)

Options on Coupon Bonds (continued)

• The solution is unique for one-factor models whose bond price is a monotonically decreasing function of r.

• Let

Xi ≡ P (r, T, ti),

the value at time T of a zero-coupon bond with par value $1 and maturing at time ti if r(T ) = r.

• Note that P (r, T, ti) ≥ Xi if and only if ≤ r.

(78)

Options on Coupon Bonds (concluded)

• As X = 

i ciXi, the option’s payoff equals max

 n

i=1

ciP (r(T ), T, ti)





i

ciXi

 , 0



=

n i=1

ci × max(P (r(T ), T, ti) − Xi, 0).

• Thus the call is a package of n options on the underlying zero-coupon bond.

• Why can’t we do the same thing for Asian options?a

aContributed by Mr. Yang, Jui-Chung (D97723002) on May 20, 2009.

(79)

No-Arbitrage Term Structure Models

(80)

How much of the structure of our theories really tells us about things in nature, and how much do we contribute ourselves?

— Arthur Eddington (1882–1944)

(81)

Motivations

• Recall the difficulties facing equilibrium models mentioned earlier.

– They usually require the estimation of the market price of risk.

– They cannot fit the market term structure.

– But consistency with the market is often mandatory in practice.

(82)

No-Arbitrage Models

a

• No-arbitrage models utilize the full information of the term structure.

• They accept the observed term structure as consistent with an unobserved and unspecified equilibrium.

• From there, arbitrage-free movements of interest rates or bond prices over time are modeled.

• By definition, the market price of risk must be reflected in the current term structure; hence the resulting

interest rate process is risk-neutral.

aHo and Lee (1986). Thomas Lee is a “billionaire founder” of Thomas H. Lee Partners LP, according to Bloomberg on May 26, 2012.

(83)

No-Arbitrage Models (concluded)

• No-arbitrage models can specify the dynamics of

zero-coupon bond prices, forward rates, or the short rate.

• Bond price and forward rate models are usually non-Markovian (path dependent).

• In contrast, short rate models are generally constructed to be explicitly Markovian (path independent).

• Markovian models are easier to handle computationally.

(84)

The Ho-Lee Model

a

• The short rates at any given time are evenly spaced.

• Let p denote the risk-neutral probability that the short rate makes an up move.

• We shall adopt continuous compounding.

aHo and Lee (1986).

(85)

 r3

 

r2

  

r1 r3 + v3

  

r2 + v2

 

r3 + 2v3



(86)

The Ho-Lee Model (continued)

• The Ho-Lee model starts with zero-coupon bond prices P (t, t + 1), P (t, t + 2), . . . at time t identified with the root of the tree.

• Let the discount factors in the next period be

Pd(t + 1, t + 2), Pd(t + 1, t + 3), . . . if short rate moves down Pu(t + 1, t + 2), Pu(t + 1, t + 3), . . . if short rate moves up

• By backward induction, it is not hard to see that for n ≥ 2,

Pu(t + 1, t + n) = Pd(t + 1, t + n) e−(v2+···+vn)

(133) (see p. 376 of the textbook).

(87)

The Ho-Lee Model (continued)

• It is also not hard to check that the n-period zero-coupon bond has yields

yd(n) ≡ −ln Pd(t + 1, t + n) n − 1

yu(n) ≡ −ln Pu(t + 1, t + n)

n − 1 = yd(n) + v2 + · · · + vn n − 1

• The volatility of the yield to maturity for this bond is therefore

κn 

pyu(n)2 + (1 − p) yd(n)2 − [ pyu(n) + (1 − p) yd(n) ]2

= 

p(1 − p) (yu(n) − yd(n))

= 

p(1 − p) v2 + · · · + vn

n − 1 .

(88)

The Ho-Lee Model (concluded)

• In particular, the short rate volatility is determined by taking n = 2:

σ = 

p(1 − p) v2. (134)

• The variance of the short rate therefore equals p(1 − p)(ru − rd)2,

where ru and rd are the two successor rates.a

aContrast this with the lognormal model (108) on p. 909.

(89)

The Ho-Lee Model: Volatility Term Structure

• The volatility term structure is composed of κ2, κ3, . . . .

– It is independent of

r2, r3, . . . .

• It is easy to compute the vis from the volatility structure, and vice versa (review p. 1047).

• The ris can be computed by forward induction.

• The volatility structure is supplied by the market.

(90)

The Ho-Lee Model: Bond Price Process

• In a risk-neutral economy, the initial discount factors satisfy

P (t, t+n) = (pPu(t+1, t+n)+(1−p) Pd(t+1, t+n)) P (t, t+1).

• Combine the above with Eq. (133) on p. 1046 and assume p = 1/2 to obtaina

Pd(t + 1, t + n) = P (t, t + n) P (t, t + 1)

2 × exp[ v2 + · · · + vn ] 1 + exp[ v2 + · · · + vn ],

(135)

Pu(t + 1, t + n) = P (t, t + n) P (t, t + 1)

2

1 + exp[ v2 + · · · + vn ].

(135)

aIn the limit, only the volatility matters.

(91)

The Ho-Lee Model: Bond Price Process (concluded)

• The bond price tree combines.

• Suppose all vi equal some constant v and δ ≡ ev > 0.

• Then

Pd(t + 1, t + n) = P (t, t + n) P (t, t + 1)

n−1 1 + δn−1, Pu(t + 1, t + n) = P (t, t + n)

P (t, t + 1)

2

1 + δn−1.

• Short rate volatility σ = v/2 by Eq. (134) on p. 1048.

• Price derivatives by taking expectations under the risk-neutral probability.

(92)

The Ho-Lee Model: Yields and Their Covariances

• The one-period rate of return of an n-period zero-coupon bond is

r(t, t + n) ≡ ln

P (t + 1, t + n) P (t, t + n)

 .

• Its value is either ln PdP (t,t+n)(t+1,t+n) or ln PuP (t,t+n)(t+1,t+n).

• Thus the variance of return is

Var[ r(t, t + n) ] = p(1 − p)((n − 1) v)2 = (n − 1)2σ2.

(93)

The Ho-Lee Model: Yields and Their Covariances (concluded)

• The covariance between r(t, t + n) and r(t, t + m) isa (n − 1)(m − 1) σ2.

• As a result, the correlation between any two one-period rates of return is unity.

• Strong correlation between rates is inherent in all one-factor Markovian models.

aSee Exercise 26.2.7 of the textbook.

(94)

The Ho-Lee Model: Short Rate Process

• The continuous-time limit of the Ho-Lee model is dr = θ(t) dt + σ dW.

• This is Vasicek’s model with the mean-reverting drift replaced by a deterministic, time-dependent drift.

• A nonflat term structure of volatilities can be achieved if the short rate volatility is also made time varying,

dr = θ(t) dt + σ(t) dW.

• This corresponds to the discrete-time model in which vi are not all identical.

(95)

The Ho-Lee Model: Some Problems

• Future (nominal) interest rates may be negative.

• The short rate volatility is independent of the rate level.

(96)

Problems with No-Arbitrage Models in General

• Interest rate movements should reflect shifts in the model’s state variables (factors) not its parameters.

• Model parameters, such as the drift θ(t) in the

continuous-time Ho-Lee model, should be stable over time.

• But in practice, no-arbitrage models capture yield curve shifts through the recalibration of parameters.

– A new model is thus born everyday.

(97)

Problems with No-Arbitrage Models in General (concluded)

• This in effect says the model estimated at some time does not describe the term structure of interest rates and their volatilities at other times.

• Consequently, a model’s intertemporal behavior is

suspect, and using it for hedging and risk management may be unreliable.

參考文獻

相關文件

• Similar to futures options except that what is delivered is a forward contract with a delivery price equal to the option’s strike price.. – Exercising a call forward option results

zero-coupon bond prices, forward rates, or the short rate.. • Bond price and forward rate models are usually non-Markovian

• P u is the price of the i-period zero-coupon bond one period from now if the short rate makes an up move. • P d is the price of the i-period zero-coupon bond one period from now

• P u is the price of the i-period zero-coupon bond one period from now if the short rate makes an up move. • P d is the price of the i-period zero-coupon bond one period from now

• Goal is to construct a no-arbitrage interest rate tree consistent with the yields and/or yield volatilities of zero-coupon bonds of all maturities.. – This procedure is

zero-coupon bond prices, forward rates, or the short rate.. • Bond price and forward rate models are usually non-Markovian

• The XYZ.com bonds are equivalent to a default-free zero-coupon bond with $X par value plus n written European puts on Merck at a strike price of $30. – By the

• The binomial interest rate tree can be used to calculate the yield volatility of zero-coupon bonds.. • Consider an n-period