• 沒有找到結果。

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

21

4. Empirical Results

4.1 Herding and feedback trading by individual investors and the effect of trade sizes

Table 4 shows herding and feedback trading by individual investors during the

entire sample period. In Panel A, we observe a significant positive correlation

between TAIEX Futures return in last period and the net buy orders by individual

investors. It demonstrates that individual investors are significant positive feedback

traders. They are less-informed traders, so they pay more attention to public

information such as market prices. They buy TAIEX futures when market price rises

and sell it when market price falls. On the other hand, we observe individual investors

tend to transact with lags and the opposing direction to institutional investors.

To examine the effect of trade sizes on herding and feedback trading behavior by

individual investors, we divide individual investors into large and small groups.

Table 2 shows descriptive statistics per contract by trade size categories. We define

two trade sizes of individual investors each as follows: individual investors whose

total trading volumes are above 3,864 contracts belong to the large group, individual

investors whose total trading volumes are below and equal to 3,864 contracts belong

to the small group. We can see that the average trade sizes of large individual

investors and small individual investors vary drastically. The average trade sizes of

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

22

large individual investors are over one hundred times more than the average trade

sizes of small individual investors

By looking at Panel B of Table 4, we find that only lag of the net buy orders by

large individual investors can explain TAIEX futures return in current period. The

statistics result is slightly significant. It implies that large individual investors are

informed traders and they have capability of predicting market returns. Besides, we

observe that large individual investors are neither positive feedback nor negative

feedback traders. It is interesting that we find that large individual investors tend to

transact with lags to small individual investors.

According to Panel C, we observe that small individual investors are significant

positive feedback traders. On the other hand, we observe small individual investors

tend to transact with lags and the opposing direction to large individual investors and

small institutional investors. The result is consistent with the result of Lee et al.

(1999).

In short, individual investors are significant positive feedback traders but engage

in herding not significantly. We find that large individual investors are informed

traders and their trading behavior is independent and different from average individual investors’ trading behavior. Small individual investors are less-informed traders, and

they tend to engage in positive feedback trading to get more attention.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

23

4.2 Herding and feedback trading by institutional investors and the effect of trade sizes

Table 8 shows herding and feedback trading by institutional investors during the

entire sample period. In Panel A, we observe a significant negative correlation

between TAIEX Futures return in last period and the net buy orders by institutional

investors. It demonstrates that institutional investors are significant negative feedback

traders. What is more, we find that they engage in herding to themselves. Because of

the competition among institutional investors and reception of similar information,

institutional investors have significant herding behavior.

To examine the effect of trade sizes on herding and feedback trading behavior by

institutional investors, we also divide institutional investors into large and small

groups. Table 2 shows institutional investors whose total trading volumes are above

577,850 contracts belong to the large group, and institutional investors whose total

trading volumes are below and equal to 577,850 contracts belong to the small group.

We can see that the average trade sizes of large individual investors and small

individual investors vary widely. The numbers of large institutional investors account

for 1.5% of the numbers of all institutional investors. However, the total trading

volumes of large institutional investors account for more than half of the total trading

volumes of all institutional investors.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

24

By looking at Panel B of Table 8, we observe that large institutional investors are

positive feedback traders. There is slight evidence to indicate that large institutional

investors follow their lag trading, but they would not follow other types of investors.

Meanwhile, Panel C shows that small institutional investors are significant negative

feedback traders. In addition, we find that they engage in herding not only to

themselves but also to large individual investors.

In brief, institutional investors have significant herding and negative feedback

trading behavior. Large institutional investors’ trading behavior is not consistent with average institutional investors’ trading behavior. Small institutional investors have the

most significant herding behavior among all types of investors because of competition

among them and reception of the similar information.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

25

4.3 Herding and feedback trading in different periods

We divide the entire sample period into a period of contraction and a period of

expansion and examine whether each type of investors change their trading behavior

in different phases of the business cycle. Table 3 and Table 7 present descriptive

statistics for all dependent variables of VAR models. We can see that average return

during the entire sample period is 0.03%, average return during a period of

contraction is -0.02%, and average return during a period of expansion is 0.05%.

Table 5 and Table 6 separately present individual investors’ trading behavior

during a period of contraction and a period of expansion. By looking at Panel A to

Panel C of Table 5, we find that herding almost disappears among individual

investors during a period of contraction. Panel A to Panel C of Table 6 discover that

herding prevails over individual investors during a period of expansion. Large

individual investors have no capability of predicting market returns during a

recession. Small individual investors are positive feedback traders both during

periods of contraction and expansion. However, the evidence of positive feedback

trading is much weaker during a period of contraction.

Table 9 and Table 10 present institutional investors’ trading behavior during

periods of contraction and expansion, respectively. According to Panel A to Panel C

of Table 9 and Table 10, we observe herding by institutional investors is more

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

26

significant during a period of expansion than a period of contraction except for large

institutional investors. Large institutional investors engage in herding and positive

feedback trading during a period of contraction but the phenomenon is slightly

significant. Small institutional investors herd to themselves and large individual

investors significantly during a period of expansion. Nevertheless, small institutional

investors do not follow themselves anymore and the evidence of herding to large

individual investors is weaker during a period of contraction. Besides, we observe

that small institutional investors are significant negative feedback traders both during

periods of contraction and expansion.

In sum, investors react asymmetrically to periods of contraction and expansion.

Herding and feedback trading prevail more over almost all types of investors during a

period of expansion except for large institutional investors. Chau et al. (2011) suggest

that feedback trading is largely caused by the presence of sentiment-driven trading.

Because the emotion of investors is stronger during a period of expansion than during

a period of contraction, the intensity of herding and positive feedback trading increase

during a period of expansion. Choe et al. (1999) suggest that investors are less capable

of trading as a result of market liquidity shortfall during a period of contraction.

Therefore, the phenomenon of herding is less significant during a period of

contraction than during a period of expansion.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

27

4.4 Herding and feedback trading by different institutional investors

In prior to the examination, we find that institutional investors have significant

herding and positive feedback trading behaviors. However, institutional investors can

be categorized into three types of investors: domestic institutional investors,

proprietary firm investors, foreign institutional investors. In this part, we discuss

whether these three types of institutional investors all engage in herding and negative

feedback trading.

Table 11 presents descriptive statistics for all dependent variables of VAR models

with these three types of institutional investors. We can discover that the range of FOREt is -0.99 to 1.00, and kurtosis is negative. It implies that foreign institutional

investors are better-informed traders, and that the direction of trading by them is

extremely the same.

Table 12 reports herding and feedback trading by different types of institutional

investors during the entire sample period. In Panel A, we observe that no lag of the net

buy orders by all types of institutional investors has significant evidence to explain

TAIEX futures return in current period.

In Panel B, we discover that domestic institutional investors tend to transact with

lags and the opposing direction to themselves. On the other hand, domestic

institutional investors are neither positive feedback nor negative feedback traders.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

28

In Panel C, we find that proprietary firm investors do not engage in herding and

feedback trading. In Panel D, we observe that foreign institutional investors have

significant herding and negative feedback trading behavior. They buy when market

prices falls and sell following increase in market prices. The intensity of herding

among foreign institutional investors is larger than other types of institutional

investors. The result is consistent with the evidence of Bowe and Domuta (2004).

In a word, only foreign institutional investors engage in herding. They are more

likely to follow the same type of institutional investors than different types of

institutional investors. The result accords with the result of Sias (2004). Moreover, we

observe that only foreign institutional engage in negative feedback trading among all

types of institutional investors.

‧ 國

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

29

相關文件