• 沒有找到結果。

Concluding Remarks and Future Extensions

Chapter 3 Consumption Tax, Seigniorage Tax, and Tax Switch Policy in a

3.6 Concluding Remarks and Future Extensions

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

increases. This implies that relative to the case where mtct (the corresponding government constraint is gyt (c)ct), a decrease in c by an unit must be associated with a relatively lower money growth rate due to a larger tax base. Since the effect of seigniorage tax is weakened, the growth effect of consumption tax dominates. Thus, tax switch from consumption taxation to seigniorage taxation has a favorable effect on economic growth.

3.6 Concluding Remarks and Future Extensions

The paper develops a monetary endogenous growth model with endogenous labor-leisure choice and cash-in-advanced constraint which is only imposed on consumption to investigate the effects of alternative tax policies (the growth rate of money supply, consumption tax rate, and tax switch) under different usages of the tax revenue. With the framework, first, we find that the different usages of the tax revenue do result in a transformation in the effects of the growth rate of money supply and consumption tax respectively. Second, we show that the Friedman rule which claims the zero nominal interest rate is no longer optimal but a deflation is still necessary for social optimum if there exists the production externality of capital and the consumption tax. Finally, we re-examine the effects of a switch from consumption taxation to inflation taxation to finance a given stream of government expenditure, namely tax switch, to complement the unclear discussion in Ho et al. (2007). It has been found that the tax switch causes an increase in the steady-state growth rate through the increase in labor supply. Moreover, in contrast with the inconsistent results between MIUF and CIA approaches derived in Ho et al. (2007), this result suggests that the qualitative equivalence between MIUF and CIA approaches is still valid.

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

Finally, by referring to the similar effects of consumption tax and the money growth rate in our framework, it might be an interesting future research to evaluate the welfare consequences of the two tax policies with a numerical assessment.

In the Appendix, we prove the uniqueness and existence of the steady-state equilibrium when  1 and  0.

A.1 Case  1:

When  1, the endogenous adjustment of lump-sum transfer Rt, clearly has no direct effect on equations (15d) and (15e). From this perspective, Rt can be recursively determined by (15c). By substituting equation (15d) with xt 0 into equation (15e) with

0

zt , the steady-state equilibrium can be derived by the resulting equation and equation (15d) with xt 0 as follows: steady-state equilibrium exists and is unique.

Furthermore, let  and 1  be the two characteristic roots of the dynamic system. 2

and 2 0. As documented in the literature of dynamic rational expectation models, including Buiter (1984) and Turnovsky (2000b), the dynamic system has unique perfect-foresight equilibrium if the number of unstable roots equals to the number of jump variables. The dynamic system stated in equation (17) has two jump variables xt and zt, thus a unique stable path leading to the determinate steady-state equilibrium is ensured.

A.2 Case  0:

Contrast with Case A.1, we have to substitute equation (15c) into equations (15d) and (15e). Next, by substituting equation (15d) with xt 0 into equation (15e) with zt 0, the steady-state equilibrium can be derived by the resulting equation and equation (15d) with

0

The uniqueness and existence of steady-state equilibrium claim that xt 0 and zz loci have to intersect at a single point in the (xt,zt) space. As a consequence, we show that

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

the 0xt  locus intersects the zt-coordinate at [(1 ) ] 0 1

1   

  

A when lt 0

(xt 0). Under the restriction of non-negative working hours (lt 1), along the xt 0 locus, zt has a lower bound 

  1

min 1

zt when lt 1, and the slope approaches 0 at the point. Together with the zz locus, Figure 2 indicates that the steady-state equilibrium exists and is unique.

In addition, let  and 1  be the two characteristic roots of the dynamic system 2 expressed by equation (17) with  0, we then have: (1 )

ˆ ) ˆ 1 ˆ{(

2 2

1   

     

z x x

0 } ˆ)]

( 1

[ l x 1lx

A

 and (1 ) [1 (ˆ)] } 0

ˆ {1 ) ˆ 1

ˆ( 1

2

1      Al x lx

x z

z   

 , thus

10

 and 2 0. The number of unstable roots equals to the number of jump variables in equation (17), thus there exits a unique stable path leading to the steady-state equilibrium.

with 0zt  , the steady state relationships are expressed by the resulting equation and equations (24a) with xt 0 as follows: uniqueness and existence of steady-state equilibrium. From equations (B1) and (B2), we show that the xt 0 locus and the zz locus intersect the zt -coordinate at equilibrium exists and is unique.

Furthermore, let  and 1  be the two characteristic roots of the dynamic system 2

expressed by equation (25), we then have:  

 

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

Figures

Figure 1. The Existence and Uniqueness of the Steady-State Equilibrium when 1 ]

) 1 )[(

1

( c A

zz

0 xt

xt

zt

0

) 1 ( c

Figure 2. The Existence and Uniqueness of the Steady-State Equilibrium when 0 ]

) 1 1 [(

1

A

zz

0 xt

xt

zt

0

1

1

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

] ) 1 )[(

1

( c g A zz

0 xt

xt

zt

0

1 ) ( 1

c

A g

Figure 3. The Existence and Uniqueness of the Steady-State Equilibrium when Tax Switch

) 1 ( c

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

References

Abel, A. B. and Blanchard, O. J., 1983, “An Intertemporal Model of Saving and Investment,”

Econometrica 51, 675-692.

Auerbach, A. J., Kotlikoff, L. J., and Skinner, J., 1983, “The Efficiency Gains from Dynamic Tax Reform,” International Economic Review 24, 81-100.

Auerbach, A. J. and Kotlikoff, L. J. 1987, Dynamic Fiscal Policy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Express.

Auerbach, A. J. and Obstfeld, M. 2004, “Monetary and Fiscal Remedies for Deflation,”

American Economic Review 94: Papers and Proceedings, 71-75.

Auerbach, A. J. and Obstfeld, M. 2005, “The Case for Open-Market Purchase in a Liquidity Trap,” American Economic Review 95, 110-137.

Barro, R. J., 1995, “Inflation and Economic Growth,” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 166-176.

Braun, R. A. 1994, “Tax Disturbances and Real Economic Activity in the Postwar United States,” Journal of Monetary Economics 33, 441-462.

Buiter, W. H., 1984, “Saddlepoint Problems in Continuous Time Rational Expectations Models: A General Method and Some Macroeconomic Examples,” Econometrica 52, 665-680.

Bullard, J. and Keating, J. W., 1995, “The Long-Run Relationship between Inflation and Output in Postwar Economies,” Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 477-496.

Chamley, C., 1985, “Efficient Tax Reform in a Dynamic Model of General Equilibrium,”

Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 335-356.

Chang, W. Y., Hsieh, Y. N., and Lai, C. C., 2000, “Social Status, Inflation, and Endogenous Growth in a Cash-in-Advance Economy” European Journal of Political Economy 16, 535-545.

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

Chen, S. H. and Guo, J. T., 2008, “Velocity of money, equilibrium (in)determinacy and endogenous growth,” Journal of Macroeconomics 30, 1085-1096.

Cooley, T. F. and Hansen, G. D., 1992, “Tax Distortions in a Neoclassical Monetary Economy,” Journal of Economic Theory 58, 290-316.

De Gregorio, J., 1993, “Inflation, Taxation, and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Monetary Economics 31, 271-298.

Dotsey, M. and Sarte, P. D., 2000, “Inflation Uncertainty and Growth in a Cash-in-Advance Economy,” Journal of Monetary Economics 45, 631-655.

Friedman, M., 1969, “The Optimum Quantity of Money,” The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, London: Macmillan.

Galí, J. 1994, “Government Size and Macroeconomic Stability,” European Economic Review 38, 117-132.

Gavin, M. and Roberto P., 1997, “Fiscal Policy in Latin America,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 12, MIT Press: Cambridge, Massachusetts, 11-61.

Greenwood, J. and Huffman, G. W. 1991, “Tax Analysis in a Real Business Cycle Model: on Measuring Harberger Triangles and Okun Gaps,” Journal of Monetary Economics 27, 167-190.

Gomme, P., 1993, “Money and Growth Revisited: Measuring the Costs of Inflation in an Endogenous Growth Model,” Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 51-77.

Guo, J. T. and Harrison, S. G.., 2004, “Balanced-Budget Rules and Macroeconomic (in)stability,” Journal of Economic Theory 119, 357-363.

Gylfason, T. and Herbertsson, T. T., 2001, “Does Inflation matter for Growth,” Japan and the World Economy 13, 405-428.

Ho, W. H., Zeng, J. and Zhang, J., 2007, “Inflation Taxation and Welfare with Externalities and Leisure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, 105-131.

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

Itaya, J. I., 1991, “Tax Incidence in a Two-Sector Growing Economy with Perfect Foresight:

Long-Run Analysis,” Journal of Public Economics 44, 95-118.

Itaya, J. I., 1998, “Money, Neutrality of consumption Taxes, and Growth in intertemporal Optimizing Models,” Japanese Economic Review 49, 395-411.

Kaneko, A. and Matsuzaki, D., 2009, “Consumption tax and Economic Growth in an overlapping generations Model with money holdings,” Journal of Economics 98, 155-175 King, R., Plosser, C. I., and Rebelo, S. T., 1988, “Production, Growth, and Business Cycle II:

New Direction,” Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 309-342.

Marquis, M. H. and Reffett, K. L., 1991, “Real Interest Rates and Endogenous Growth in a Monetary Economy,” Economics Letters 37, 105-109.

Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. and Roubini, N., 1998, “Growth Effects of Income and Consumption taxes,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30, 721-744.

Mino, K., 1997, “Long-Run Effect of Monetary Expansion in a Two-Sector Model of Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Macroeconomics 19, 635-655.

Mundell, R., 1963, “Inflation and Real Interest,” Journal of Political Economy 71, 280-283.

Palivos, T. and Yip, C. K., 1995, “Government Expenditure Financing in an endogenous Growth Model: A Comparison,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, 1159-1178.

Pecorino, P, 1993, “Tax Structure and Growth in a Model with Human Capital,” Journal of Public Economics 52, 251-271.

Pecorino, P, 1994, “The Growth Rate Effects of Tax Reform,” Oxford Economic Papers 26, 492-502.

Pelloni, A. and Waldmann, R., 2000, “Can Waste Improve Welfare?” Journal of Public Economics 77, 45-79.

Phelps, E. S., 1973, “Inflation in the Theory of Public Finance,” Swedish Journal of Economics 75, 67-82.

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

Rebelo, S. T., 1991, “Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 99, 500-521.

Romer, P. M., 1986, “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 94, 1002-1037.

Schmitt-Grohé, S. and Uribe, M., 1997, “Balanced-Budget Rules, Distortionary Taxes, and Aggregate Instability,” Journal of Political Economy 105, 976-1000.

Sidrauski, M., 1967, “Rational Choice and Patterns of Growth in a Monetary Economy,”

American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 57, 534-544.

Stockman, A., 1981, “Anticipated Inflation and the Capital Stock in a Cash-in-Advance economy,” Journal of Monetary Economics 8, 387-393.

Summers, L. H., 1981, “Capital Taxation and Accumulation in a Life Cycle Growth Model,”

American Economic Review 71, 533-544.

Talvi, E. and Végh, C. A., 2005, “Tax Base Variability and Procyclical Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries,” Journal of Development Economics 78, 156-190

Tobin, J., 1965, “Money and Economic Growth,” Econometrica 33, 671-684.

Turnovsky, S. J., 2000a, “Fiscal Policy, Elastic Labor Supply, and Endogenous Growth,”

Journal of Monetary Economics 45, 185-210.

Turnovsky, S. J., 2000b, Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics, 2nd Ed., Cambridge, MA:

MIT Press.

Wang, P. and Yip, C. K., 1992, “Alternative approaches to Money and Growth,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 24, 553-562.

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

Chapter 4

Conclusions

To keep up with the rapid globalization of the world economy, governments have made efforts in the tax reform policies for the sake of enhancing competitiveness of nations, stimulating capital accumulation, and improving efficiency. Owens (2006) indicates that, driven by the need to provide a more competitive fiscal environment, the tax reform such as a shift in the tax structure from taxes on income and profits towards taxes on consumption is an on-going process in almost all OECD countries. Owing to the topic have been highly concerned in the developed and developing countries, we have developed two different endogenous growth frameworks—real model and monetary model to discuss the related issues to enrich the understandings in this field.

In Chapter 2, we have developed a simple Romer (1986)-type endogenous growth model with endogenous fertility choice and explore the role of endogenous fertility choice in terms of influencing the effects of tax reform on economic growth and social welfare. It has been found that the effects of tax reform on the steady-state fertility rate, the balanced growth rate, and social welfare are ambiguous. Specifically, the effect of tax reform on the steady-state fertility rate depends on the relative extent between the marginal utility of fertility and the average child-rearing cost-labor time ratio. Based on this ambiguity, we have pointed out that tax reform can serve to decrease, rather than increase, economic growth and social welfare. This result not only contrasts with the existing literature, but also provides a new insight into the policy implications.

In Chapter 3, a monetary endogenous growth model with endogenous labor-leisure

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

choice and cash-in-advance constraint which is only imposed on consumption is established to investigate the effects of alternative tax policies (seigniorage tax, consumption tax, and tax switch) under different methods of adjustment to maintain the balanced government budget.

With the framework, we find that the different methods to maintain the balanced government budget do result in a transformation in the results of the growth rate of money supply and consumption tax respectively. In the normative analysis, we show that the Friedman rule which claims the zero nominal interest rate is no longer optimal but a deflation is still necessary for social optimum if there exists the production externality of capital and the consumption tax. Finally, we re-examine the effects of a switch from consumption taxation to inflation taxation to finance a given amount of government expenditure, namely tax switch, to complement the unclear discussion in Ho et al. (2007). It has been found that the tax switch causes an increase in the steady-state growth rate through the increase in labor supply.

Moreover, contrast to the inconsistent results between MIUF and CIA approaches derived in Ho et al. (2007), this result suggests that the qualitative equivalence between MIUF and CIA approaches is still valid.

立 政 治 大 學

N a tio na

l C h engchi U ni ve rs it y

References

Ho, W. H., Zeng, J. and Zhang, J., 2007, “Inflation Taxation and Welfare with Externalities and Leisure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, 105-131.

Owens, J., 2006, “Fundamental Tax Reform: an International Perspective,” National Tax Journal 69, 131-164.

Romer, P. M., 1986, “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 94, 1002-1037.

相關文件