• 沒有找到結果。

集團企業的繼承與創新

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "集團企業的繼承與創新"

Copied!
35
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

行政院國家科學委員會專題研究計畫 成果報告

集團企業的繼承與創新(第 3 年)

研究成果報告(完整版)

計 畫 類 別 : 個別型 計 畫 編 號 : NSC 98-2410-H-004-048-MY3 執 行 期 間 : 100 年 08 月 01 日至 101 年 07 月 31 日 執 行 單 位 : 國立政治大學科技管理研究所 計 畫 主 持 人 : 溫肇東 計畫參與人員: 博士班研究生-兼任助理人員:莊皓鈞 報 告 附 件 : 赴大陸地區研究心得報告 公 開 資 訊 : 本計畫涉及專利或其他智慧財產權,2 年後可公開查詢

中 華 民 國 101 年 11 月 30 日

(2)

中 文 摘 要 : 本研究發現,隸屬集團將有助於公司的創新,而家族企業雖 傾向較非家族企業創新,但隸屬於集團的家族企業卻較隸屬 於集團的非家族企業較不創新,再深入分析發現,家族集團 非交叉持股型、及具有超額控制權的企業是屬於較不創新的 一群,但隸屬於集團的非家族企業則較會利用超額控制權來 有效分散風險、增加創新。 中文關鍵詞: 創新、家族偏好、集團子公司、代理成本、風險分散 英 文 摘 要 : 英文關鍵詞:

(3)

1

INTRODUCTION

In this study, we attempt to make a contribution to the literatures on the corporate

governance and innovation. Innovation has been considered as a source of

competitive advantage for an enterprise (Sundaram, John, & John, 1996). However,

agency costs are often the impediment for a large corporation to do innovative

projects (Holmstrom, 1989). In order to solve this problem, Francis and Smith (1995)

empirically prove that concentrated ownership monitoring is an effective means to

alleviate the high agency costs associated with innovation. Unfortunately, there

remains a lack of consistent results with regard to the effect of ownership structure on

innovation (Belloc, 2011).

Revisiting Holmstrom’s (1989) work on agency cost and innovation, we can find that

the possible missing link between corporate governance and innovation may be

caused by the omitting of a large shareholder’s risk preference and ability to share risk.

For group-affiliated firms in pyramidal groups the divergence between voting rights

and cash flow rights is often high. This arrangement of ownership structure allows

their ultimate controllers control a firm and share risk simultaneously.

Traditionally, the studies of corporate governance only focus on the costs of agency

problems (Villalonga & Amit, 2006) while omitting the advantage of risk sharing on

venturous investments, like innovative projects. While Admati, Pfleiderer, & Zechner

(1994) point out that concentrated ownership not only encourages a high rate of

monitoring by large shareholders but leads to a potential loss of risk-sharing benefits

that usually requires diffused shareholders. When the effectiveness of large

shareholders’ monitoring does not increase with their holdings, large shareholders will

(4)

2

risk-sharing purposes. Accordingly, large publicly traded firms which are

characterized as highly diffuse ownership structures are supposed to have the

preference to invest in riskier and more innovative projects.

Along the same vein, we suggest that the arrangement of pyramidal structure may not

for the purpose of appropriation but for risk-sharing benefits. Pyramidal groups are

often featured as high divergence between voting rights and cash flow right. This

contingence provides us a good field to test our conjectures.

Our empirical analysis is conducted using Top 3000 public manufacturing firms in

Taiwan between 2000 and 2005. And we collect these firm’s patent data, which is

granted by United States Patent and Trademark Office, to measure their

innovativeness. The results confirm our conjecture that pyramidal control mechanism

is for the purpose of risk sharing. We also find that family businesses are risk averted

while they have the propensity to do innovation for the sake of their longer investment

horizons.

THEORY AND HYPOTHESES Family preference and innovation

Until now, there is weak agreement and understanding about the relationship between

family preferences and innovative investments. Firstly because of long-payoff horizon

and risk (Holmstrom, 1989; Lee & O'Neill, 2003), a family will be reluctant to bet its

reputation and wealth of innovative projects (Dyer & Whetten, 2006). Moreover,

innovative projects are also characterized as complexity and costly and need the

involvement of outside experts and venture capitalists. But it’s hard for a family to

cede its control rights. Thu, investments with long-term uncertain payoffs are seen by

(5)

3 & Kintana, 2010).

On the other hand, innovation has been considered as a source of competitive

advantage for an enterprise (Sundaram et al., 1996). Although R&D investments

provide long-term benefits (Del Monte & Papagni, 2003; Hall, 1932), professional

managers of large public firms do not have the incentive to invest in innovative

projects because it’s more costly than routines. But the presence of a large, controlling

shareholder like a family, can influence investment decisions from the long-horizon

perspective and mitigate myopic loss aversion (Shleifer & Vishny, 1986). According

to the discussions above, we suggest the following competitive hypotheses:

H1a: Risk-averse firms will have less innovation.

H1b: Risk-taking firms will have more innovation. Ownership structure, risk preference and innovation Expropriation Perspective

The separation of ownership and control is the root of agency problems. In United

State, widely held firms are the archetype of large corporations. Because dispersed

ownership reduce shareholders’ incentives to monitor professional managers, the rise

of large corporations often accompany with the concentrated power of professional

managers (Berle & Means, 1932). The separations of interests between managers and

shareholders then cause the so-called principle-agent problems.

Holmstrom (1989) argues that agency problem can be a critical obstruction for large

firms to invest in innovative projects. Within a firm, it is costly to monitor and

(6)

4

pressures from the capital market influence a firm’s risk-taking behavior; past

performances determine whether a firm can get new capital from the capital market.

Thus, large public firms would rather avoid investing in innovative yet risky projects.

The agency problems in business groups stem from high diversion of cash flows. La

Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (1999) show that most large corporations

around the world have controlling owners and control pyramids are ubiquitous.

Although control pyramids can be taken as devices for circumventing inadequate

institutions – this argument implicitly presumes that the controlling shareholder’s

allocation of resources across groups are efficient enough – the ownership structure

might also cause conflicts of interests between controlling and minority shareholders.

Control pyramids allow the controlling shareholders to secure control rights without

commensurate cash flow rights. Therefore, controlling shareholders share only a small

part of monetary payoffs but retain all of the private benefits in any investment. This

situation leads the controlling owners to pursuit of private benefits while let all group

members bear high cost of capital (Almeida & Wolfenzon, 2006; Morck, Wolfenzon,

& Yeung, 2005).

The agency problems in business groups result from high diversion of cash flows

often deteriorate group member firms’ innovativeness due to three reasons. The first

reason is about incentives and monitors. Berle & Means (1932) argue that the

separation of ownership and control in pyramidal groups is similar to those in widely

held firms. Thus we expect that controlling shareholders can get rid of minority

shareholders’ scrutiny and invest less in innovation. Secondly, the divergence between

control rights and cash flow rights will induce capital misallocation. When the

(7)

5

benefits with non-controlling shareholders while then also have the access to all of the

retained earnings. Therefore controlling shareholders will prefer to invest in projects

with high net present value than risk failure. Thirdly, since lower-tier firms in

pyramidal groups also bear tunneling problems(Johnson, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes,

& Shleifer, 2000). The controlling shareholder can lift assets and income from lower

to higher tier firms, and dumps losses and liabilities from higher to lower levels of the

pyramid (Morck, Wolfenzon, and Yeung, 2005); lower-tier firms in control pyramids

are vulnerable to divergence of interest and entrenchment problems simultaneously.

Thus it is hard for them to obtain sufficient resources to innovate. Taken together, we

propose the following hypotheses:

H2a: The effect of pyramid ownership structure will negatively affect a firm’s incentive to do innovation.

H3a: The higher a firm’s degree of divergence between voting rights and ownership, the lower a firm’s incentive to do innovation.

H4a: The lower layer a firm is placed at in a business group, the less a firm’s incentive to do innovation.

Risk-Sharing Perspective

Conventional wisdom on risk-sharing hypothesis suggests that business groups enable

member firms to share risks by smoothing the variance of operating profit (Nakatani,

1984). However the data from 13 countries do not provide consistent evidence for this

hypothesis and the motivation for smoothing is still unknown (Khanna & Yafeh,

2005).

In order to shed light on the issue about risk sharing and business group, we draw on

(8)

6

focuses on the paradox of large shareholder activism. Admati, Pfleiderer, & Zechner

(1994) suggest that the monitoring of large shareholders is a public good for minority

shareholders and to increase large shareholders’ monitoring level by increased

holdings will cause the loss of risk-sharing benefits. It is supposed that yielding the

advantage of risk sharing would impel large shareholders to act more cautiously on

risky investment and innovation projects are considered to be risky, unpredictable,

long-term, multi-stage, labor intensive and idiosyncratic (Holmstrom, 1989). Thus we

suggest that large publicly traded firms which are characterized as highly diffuse

ownership structures are ought to have the preference to invest in riskier and more

innovative projects.

The divergence between voting rights and ownership is regarded as the cause of

agency problems in business groups. In business groups, high divergence between

voting rights and ownership often occur in the pyramid structure. When firms are

controlled by the pyramidal ownership structure or at the bottom of the pyramid, their

ultimate controllers hold only a fraction of shares of those firms yet have the control

rights of these firms. This means that ultimate controllers do not only have incentives

to use the advantage of risk sharing but also have the power to make investment

decisions. Hence, while from the perspective of risk sharing, the arrangement of

pyramidal structure may not for the purpose of expropriation but for risk-sharing

benefits. Accordingly, we propose the competitive hypotheses below:

H2b: The effect of pyramid ownership structure will positively affect a firm’s incentive to do innovation.

H3b: The higher a firm’s degree of divergence between voting rights and ownership, the more a firm’s incentive to do innovation.

(9)

7

H4b: The lower layer a firm is placed at in a business group, the more a firm’s incentive to do innovation.

Ownership structure, risk preference and exploration innovation

In order to full understand family’s risk preference, we apply the notion of exploration

innovation to our study. The theory of exploration-exploitation is originated from

James March’s (1991) seminal work, “Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational

Learning”. March defines exploration as “search, variation, risk-taking,

experimentation, play, flexibility, discovery, and innovation”, while exploitation is

“refinement, choice, production, efficiency, selection, implementation and execution”; the distinction between exploration and exploitation is the degree of dependence on an

organization’s prior knowledge (Lavie, Stettner, & Tushman, 2010). Because

exploration involves the more distant search for new knowledge, we suggest that the

creation and acquirement of exploration innovations is more risky than exploitation

innovations. Therefore, we propose the following hypotheses:

H5a: Family firms will have a lower percentage of exploration innovations H5b: Family firms will have a higher percentage of exploration innovations.

In addition, we similarly test the moderating effect of pyramidal control mechanisms

as described above. The moderating effect of pyramidal control mechanisms is

assumed to be negative when we adopt the expropriation perspective. On the contrary,

this effect will become positive when we embrace the risk-sharing perspective. In the

same vein, we propose the following competitive hypotheses:

H6a: Pyramidal control mechanisms will negatively affect family firms’ incentive to do exploration.

(10)

8 exploration.

DATA AND METHODS Data source and sample

To test our hypotheses we use manufacturing firms included in the Taiwan Economic

Journal top 3000 from 2000 to 2005. The Taiwan Economic Journal (hereafter TEJ) is the most credible database in Taiwan and subscribed by many authoritative

international database providers, including DATASTREAM, Dialog, QUICK (in

Japan), Capital Interactive Prospective, BARRA, REUTERS, Thomson Financial, etc.

Besides the financial statement data of all publicly traded firms in Taiwan, TEJ also

construct the database of business groups in Taiwan from 1999. Masulis et. al. (2011)

also use TEJ’s business groups database to make international comparison. TEJ uses

weakest-link principle (La Porta et al., 1999) to identify the ultimate controllers for

each firm, then distinguish the relationship between these ultimate controllers. If

shared identity, interlocking directorate or cross holding occurs, the firms connected

by these relationships are considered as a business group.

Dependent variable

Innovation. The basic unit of analysis in our study is a firm. To measure firms’ innovation we collected the number of granted patents for each firm from United

States Patent and Trademark Office (hereafter USPTO). We also backdate to the

application date when we count the number for the sake of possible time-lag between

application for a patent and issue of a patent.

Exploration Innovation. In order to test the risk preference of family business, we use exploration innovation as a proxy for high risky investment. We construct this

variable according to Benner & Tushman’s definition (2002). Using a firm’s patent

(11)

9

citations or self-citations for each patent. Exploration innovations are patents that

depart entirely from prior firm knowledge (less repeat citations or self-citations). So,

we count the number of patents by year for each firm that constitute 10 percent or less,

20 percent or less, and 40 percent or less, respectively, of the citations to prior

knowledge of the focal firm. Then we can create the ratio of exploration innovations

to total patent counts at 10 percent, 20 percent, and 40 percent levels.

Independent variables and controls

Family. The way to determine a firm as family business in this research is through the

identity of ultimate controllers. The ultimate controllers can be team members, family

members. When one or more family members of the ultimate controller are officers,

directors, or blockholders, and when this family is the largest voteholder or the largest

shareholder in a firm, we define this firm as family business.

FamilyGroup. The definition of group is described in the section about data source

and sample. For the purpose of compare difference between family groups and

non-family groups, we create familygroup variable by multiplying binary family

variable and binary group variable.

Pyramidal control. La Porta et al. (1999) define pyramidal groups as a chain of firms

controlled by the controlling shareholder through at least one publicly traded firm.

Thus, we define pyramidal control mechanism as indirectly holdings; a firm held by

another publicly traded firm through either direct holdings or cross-holdings.

Divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights. Voting rights is the seats that

the ultimate controllers hold on the board. And the cash flow rights are the sum of

(12)

10

flow rights are the sum of indirect holdings. If ultimate controller A holds 5 % shares

of firm 1, 6% shares of firm2, and firm1 also holds 20% shares of firm 2, for A,

his/her indirect holdings of firm 2 is 1 percent. Then A’s cash flow rights is equal to

6% (5% + 1%). The divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights equal to

voting rights minus cash flow rights.

Layer. This variable is a firm’s layer position in pyramidal groups. The firm at the top

of the pyramidal group is coded 1. And the lower tier a firm is positioned, the larger

number it is coded.

Interactions. To test H6a and H6b, we investigate the interactions between family

groups and non-family groups and pyramidal control mechanisms. Because we want

to untangle the family effects and the group effects, we create two moderator

variables by multiplying the binary group variable and binary family groups by each

of the three pyramidal control mechanisms (pyramidal control, divergence between

voting rights and cash flow rights, and layer). Controls

Following prior studies related to the patenting behavior of firms (Hall & Ziedonis,

2001; Mansfield, 1986), we control pharmaceutical, semiconductor and other

capital-intensive industries in Taiwan, like components, electrical, machinery,

photoelectric, and communication. In addition, we use the log of the number of employee to control the effect of firm size (Scherer, 1965; Soete, 1979). Firm age

(Chrisman & C., 2011) and CEO duality (Villalonga & Amit, 2006) are also

controlled for the sake of possible entrenchment in family firms. To control for firm

performance we use ROA. A firm’s incentive scheme and R&D investment my also

(13)

11

sales. In order to exclude other group effects, we also use internal trading (sales), loan, endorsement and focal firm’s re-investment to assets as proxies to control the possible effect of internal market. Lastly, year dummies are also included.

Data analysis.

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics. The average patent counts for each firm is 3.69

while its standard deviation is very high (29.65). This initial screening of our data

suggests that means our dependent variable is overdipersion. In addition, only less

than quarter (21%) firms have at least one patent. Thus, to test H1 and H2 is

vulnerable to estimation bias due to excess zeros and overdispersion. Following prior

studies where the number of patent counts is the dependent variable (Chang, Chung,

& Mahmood, 2006; Mahmood & Zheng, 2009), we use robust zero-inflated negative

binomial (ZINB) models to test the hypotheses. Besides that, we also use two-year

time lag of all independent variables as determinants of innovations.

RESULTS Ownership structures and innovation

Table 2 presents the results using total patent counts as the dependent variable. In

order to understand the difference between non-family groups and family groups, we

involve family effect and group effect simultaneously. Model 1 show that, while both

group effect and family effect are positively associated with patent counts, the

interaction of group effect and family effect is negatively associated with patent

counts. It seems that family businesses have the propensity to do innovation (β

=1.308; p<0.01) but when family business formed into a business group, they become

less innovative (β=-2.075; p<0.01). Besides that, group effect is positively associated

(14)

12

For the purpose of untangling the group effect, we further create three interaction

terms by multiplying three different kinds of ownership structures (pyramidal control,

divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights, and layer) with group variable

and family group variable and include them separately into our model (from model 2

to model 4). The results show that group affiliation with pyramidal control has

positive effect on innovation for non-family business (β= 0.750; p<0.01) while has

negative effect on family business (β= -1.147; p<0.01). Secondly, group affiliation

with high divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights is positively related

to patent counts for non-family businesses (β= 2.093; p<0.01) but is negatively

related to patent counts for family businesses (β= -2.477; p<0.01). Thirdly, the lower

layer a firm is placed at in a non-family business group the more a firm’s incentive to

do innovation (β= 0.430; p<0.01), while the layer position do not have significant

effect on innovation for the members of family business group (β= -0.225; p>0.1).

Ownership structures and exploration innovation

To test competitive hypotheses 5a, 5b and 6a, 6b, we use three different levels of

exploration innovation. The results present separately in table3, table4, and table5.

Overall, the effect of non-family groups is not significant while family group

affiliation induce higher percentage of exploration innovation. Moreover, in

pyramidal control, firms in non-family groups have lower percentage of exploration

innovation, whereas firms in family groups have higher percentage of exploration

innovation. Take the results in table 3 as an example, group affiliation with pyramidal

control is negatively related to the percentage of exploration innovation for

non-family businesses (β= -0.064; p<0.01), while is positively related to the percentage of exploration innovation for family businesses (β= 0.086; p<0.01).

(15)

13

Secondly, group affiliation with high divergence between voting rights and cash flow

rights is negatively related to patent counts for non-family businesses (β= -0.143; p<0.01) but is positively related to patent counts for family businesses (β= 0.197=; p<0.01). Thirdly, the higher layer a firm is placed at in a non-family business group the more a firm’s incentive to do innovation (β= -0.039; p<0. 1), while the layer position do not have significant effect on innovation for the members of family

business group (β= 0.045; p>0.1). DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

The ownership structures in business groups are different from that in freestanding

firms. However related empirical studies are still scant. We intend to fill this void in

the field of corporate governance. Drawing on risk-sharing perspective, we propose

that one way to directly test whether the arrangement of pyramidal structure is for the

purpose of appropriation or for risk-sharing benefits is to investigate its effect on risky

investments, like innovations.

Using longitudinal data of business groups in Taiwan, we show that how different

traits of pyramidal control mechanism influence non-family and family group

affiliates’ incentive to do innovation. We began by analyzing family effect and group

effect on innovation and found that group affiliates prefer to do innovation while

family group affiliates object to do innovation. Based on this finding, we argue that

group affiliates are risk takers (H1b), whereas family group affiliates are risk averters

(H1a). Moreover, we found that pyramidal control mechanisms increase group

affiliates’ incentive to do innovation, but deteriorate family group affiliates’ intent to

do innovation. This result seems to imply that risk takers (non-family business) would

(16)

14

contrast, risk averters instead take pyramidal control mechanisms as a means to

expropriation (H2a, H3a, and H4a).

To verify our temporary conjecture, we replaced the dependent variable with the

percentage of exploration innovations. The further investigation suggest that, though

family group affiliates gain less innovations, they have higher percentage of

exploration innovations (H5b). We also found that most pyramidal control

mechanisms encourage family group affiliates to gain higher percentage of

exploration innovations (H6b).

As described above, our study makes contributions to three separately streams of prior

research: corporate governance, business groups, and innovations. In terms of the

studies on innovation, we add insights into how control mechanisms influence firm’s

incentive to acquire innovations. Existing literature on innovations has underlined

innovation as a result of corporate ownership and controls, like family firms’ aversion

to the loss of socioemotional wealth (Chrisman & C., 2011), the effects of internal

controls and strategic controls (Hitt, Hoskisson, Johnson, & Moesel, 1996), and the

diminishing discipline over innovative projects (Nohria & Gulati, 1996). We do not

intend to refute these arguments but we doubt the implicit assumption that active

involvement in the market for corporate control can impede their pursuit of

innovations. These studies which focus on monitoring and controls omit the

risk-sharing benefit derive from diffuse ownership structures (Admati et al., 1994).

Although Hoskisson, Hitt, Johnson, & Grossman (2002) has specified the influence of

ownership structures on corporate innovation strategies and there are ample studies in

(17)

15

corporate governance and innovation, there is scant research and understanding on

firms’ purpose of the arrangement of the ownership structures. Focusing on the

arrangement of the ownership structures, our research contributes to the main stream

research by underlining how firms arrange ownership structure to achieve risk-sharing

benefits. That is to say, the use of control mechanisms can be not only for

expropriation, but also for risk-sharing. These findings also dissolve the risk

preference of family business groups. Families are very cautious with risky projects;

even risk-sharing is possible family business groups acquire fewer innovations than

non-family business groups. But families still have the propensity to do innovation in

nature (longer investment horizons), thus they have higher percentage of exploration

innovation.

We also intend to contribute to research on business groups by adopting risk-sharing

perspective. Although internal market hypothesis dominate the theories of business

group and there is ample evidence from around the world (Belenzon & Berkovitz,

2010; Chang et al., 2006; Masulis et al., 2011), our research sheds light on the effect

of corporate ownership in a scenario to decide to do high risk investment or not. After

controlling the internal capital market factors, we find pyramidal mechanisms

facilitate group affiliates’ incentive to gain more innovation. This results support

risk-sharing hypothesis and explain why the present of business groups in markets

with relatively complete institution (for example, high-tech companies in Taiwan, like

(18)

16

Table1. Mean, Standard Deviations, and Correlations

Variable Mean Std. Dev. innov family group fgroup pyramid1

divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights

layer dualcontrol bonus affiliated sales/revenue affiliated loans/equity endorsement Reinvest /assets RD_rate /revenue ln(number of

employee) ROA firm_age

innov 3.687584 29.65198 1 family 0.610855 0.487593 -0.0879* 1 group 0.799554 0.400364 0.0535* 0.0148 1 fgroup 0.491301 0.499962 -0.0594* 0.7844* 0.4921* 1 pyramid1 0.334275 0.471772 0.0887* -0.0460* 0.2863* 0.0956* 1 divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights 0.340537 0.260748 0.1192* -0.0792* 0.1839* 0.0392* 0.4188* 1 layer 1.152252 0.416933 0.0201 -0.1224* 0.1798* -0.0337* 0.4135* 0.1914* 1 dualcontrol 0.658885 0.474119 -0.0450* 0.0684* -0.1072* -0.0019 -0.1510* -0.1349* -0.1360* 1 bonus 7.509854 34.75274 0.0641* -0.0578* 0.0083 -0.0430* -0.0117 -0.0027 0.0042 -0.0235 1 affiliated sales/revenue 0.14976 0.202947 0.0408* -0.0585* 0.1878* 0.0448* 0.1560* 0.1092* 0.1808* -0.0326* 0.0123 1 affiliated loans/equity 0.010178 0.0725 -0.0144 0.0149 0.0353* 0.0352* 0.0041 0.0145 -0.0169 -0.0108 -0.0182 -0.0025 1 endorsement 0.060429 0.22326 -0.0126 0.0478* 0.1019* 0.0980* 0.0754* 0.1164* -0.0231 -0.0371* -0.023 0.0717* 0.2661* 1 reinvest/assets 0.168288 0.157631 0.0296 0.1673* 0.3592* 0.3264* 0.1535* 0.1961* -0.0639* -0.0951* -0.0273 0.1403* 0.0183 0.2048* 1 RD/revenue 0.474682 21.06188 -0.0016 0.0067 -0.0396* -0.0193 -0.0128 -0.0101 -0.0057 0.0123 -0.0106 -0.0132 -0.0029 -0.0058 -0.016 1 ln(number of employee) 5.589005 1.133262 0.2328* 0.0334* 0.2307* 0.1503* 0.2398* 0.2956* 0.0760* -0.1146* 0.0125 0.1157* -0.002 0.1490* 0.1993* -0.0375* 1 ROA 0.052178 0.123065 0.0594* -0.0222 0.0092 -0.0305 -0.1259* -0.1430* -0.0315* 0.0017 0.1994* -0.0004 -0.1286* -0.1169* 0.0193 -0.0331* 0.0334* 1 firm_age 19.7557 12.07034 -0.0294 0.3162* 0.1526* 0.3325* 0.0715* 0.1361* -0.1512* 0.0148 -0.1314* -0.0428* 0.0634* 0.1682* 0.3785* -0.0307 0.3039* -0.0636* 1

(19)

17

Table 2. Results of zero-inflated negative binomial (ZINB) regression for total number of patents

innov (1) (2) (3) (4) family 1.308*** 1.302*** 1.261*** 1.300*** group 1.196*** 0.796*** 0.301 0.625** family*group -2.075*** -1.538*** -0.952*** -1.766*** group*pyramid 0.750*** familygroup*pyramid -1.147***

group*divergence between voting

rights and cash flow rights 2.093***

familygroup*divergence between

voting rights and cash flow rights -2.477***

group*layer 0.430*** familygroup*layer -0.225 dualcontrol 0.061 0.097 0.088 0.095 bonus 0.014*** 0.012*** 0.010*** 0.013*** affiliated sales/revenue 0.080 0.045 -0.112 -0.016 affiliated loans/equity -2.297 -1.575 -1.625 -2.020 endorsement -1.057*** -0.929*** -0.912*** -1.053*** reinvest/assets 1.621*** 1.548*** 1.432*** 1.728*** RD_rate/revenue 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 ln(number of employee) 0.936*** 0.941*** 0.893*** 0.933*** ROA 1.763*** 1.603*** 1.801*** 1.886*** firm_age -0.030*** -0.029*** -0.029*** -0.027*** y2001 0.070 0.057 0.094 0.075 y2002 0.086 0.078 0.114 0.090 y2003 0.217 0.239 0.239 0.197 y2004 0.252 0.246 0.263 0.242 y2005 0.090 0.103 0.128 0.084 components 0.283*** 0.270*** 0.293*** 0.357*** semiconductor 0.766*** 0.800*** 0.843*** 0.858*** electrical -0.220 -0.242 -0.192 -0.205 machinery -0.087 -0.111 -0.067 -0.061 pharmaceutical 0.213 0.199 0.160 0.258 photoelectric 0.311** 0.399*** 0.369** 0.344** communication -0.876*** -0.735*** -0.825*** -0.811*** _cons -5.629*** -5.678*** -5.399*** -5.714*** Log pseudo-likelihood -5037.94 -5013.13 -5000.41 -5032.05 Wald Chi-square 1243.45 1293.07 1318.51 1255.23 Observations 5540 5540 5540 5540 *P<0.1; **p<0.05;***P<0.01

(20)

18

Table3. Results of OLS regression for 10 percent level of exploration innovation (%)

10% exploration (5) (6) (7) (8) family -0.119*** -0.116** -0.115** -0.117*** group 0.034 0.067* 0.095** 0.087* family*group 0.118** 0.076 0.035 0.059 group*pyramid -0.064*** familygroup*pyramid 0.086***

group*divergence between voting

rights and cash flow rights -0.143***

familygroup*divergence between

voting rights and cash flow rights 0.197***

group*layer -0.039* familygroup*layer 0.045 dualcontrol -0.006 -0.008 -0.007 -0.007 bonus 0.001* 0.001* 0.001** 0.001* affiliated sales/revenue -0.039 -0.027 -0.022 -0.032 affiliated loans/equity 0.595** 0.568** 0.585** 0.579** endorsement -0.073 -0.074 -0.073 -0.069 reinvest/assets 0.040 0.033 0.036 0.030 RD_rate/revenue 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 ln(number of employee) -0.044*** -0.044*** -0.042*** -0.044*** ROA -0.094 -0.091 -0.092 -0.094 firm_age 0.000 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 y2001 -0.025 -0.025 -0.026 -0.026 y2002 -0.042 -0.043 -0.043 -0.042 y2003 -0.020 -0.021 -0.023 -0.020 y2004 -0.019 -0.018 -0.021 -0.019 y2005 -0.020 -0.021 -0.024 -0.020 components -0.007 -0.009 -0.001 -0.006 semiconductor -0.028 -0.024 -0.021 -0.028 electrical -0.041 -0.037 -0.037 -0.041 machinery -0.184*** -0.182*** -0.182*** -0.183*** pharmaceutical -0.046 -0.047 -0.041 -0.047 photoelectric 0.001 -0.002 0.010 -0.001 communication 0.043 0.035 0.048 0.041 _cons 1.132*** 1.131*** 1.116*** 1.135*** R-squared 0.0843 0.0914 0.093 0.0867 Observations 1242 1242 1242 1242

(21)

19

Table4. Results of OLS regression for 20 percent level of exploration innovation (%)

20% exploration (9) (10) (11) (12) family -0.128*** -0.125*** -0.125*** -0.127*** group 0.005 0.035 0.056 0.054 family*group 0.120*** 0.085** 0.053 0.066 group*pyramid -0.059*** familygroup*pyramid 0.071***

group*divergence between voting

rights and cash flow rights -0.122***

familygroup*divergence between

voting rights and cash flow rights 0.155***

group*layer -0.036 familygroup*layer 0.042 dualcontrol -0.005 -0.008 -0.007 -0.007 bonus 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 affiliated sales/revenue -0.022 -0.011 -0.008 -0.016 affiliated loans/equity 0.510** 0.485** 0.500** 0.494** endorsement -0.010 -0.012 -0.010 -0.006 reinvest/assets 0.069 0.064 0.068 0.060 RD_rate/revenue 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 ln(number of employee) -0.031*** -0.030*** -0.029*** -0.031*** ROA -0.061 -0.062 -0.061 -0.061 firm_age -0.002** -0.002** -0.002** -0.002** y2001 -0.026 -0.026 -0.026 -0.027 y2002 -0.044 -0.045 -0.045 -0.044 y2003 -0.018 -0.019 -0.020 -0.018 y2004 -0.010 -0.010 -0.012 -0.010 y2005 -0.017 -0.018 -0.020 -0.017 components -0.009 -0.011 -0.005 -0.008 semiconductor -0.036 -0.032 -0.030 -0.035 electrical -0.003 0.001 0.000 -0.002 machinery -0.152*** -0.152*** -0.151*** -0.151*** pharmaceutical 0.016 0.015 0.019 0.015 photoelectric -0.006 -0.009 0.000 -0.008 communication 0.032 0.024 0.036 0.030 _cons 1.124*** 1.121*** 1.108*** 1.127*** R-squared 0.0783 0.0855 0.0859 0.081 Observations 1242 1242 1242 1242

(22)

20

Table5. Results of OLS regression for 40 percent level of exploration innovation (%)

40% exploration (13) (14) (15) (16) family -0.059** -0.057** -0.057** -0.059** group 0.019 0.040 0.054** 0.049 family*group 0.060** 0.034 0.018 0.026 group*pyramid -0.042*** familygroup*pyramid 0.053***

group*divergence between voting

rights and cash flow rights -0.087***

familygroup*divergence between

voting rights and cash flow rights 0.094***

group*layer -0.022 familygroup*layer 0.027 dualcontrol -0.007 -0.009 -0.009 -0.008 bonus 0.000 0.000 0.000** 0.000 affiliated sales/revenue -0.018 -0.010 -0.009 -0.015 affiliated loans/equity 0.213 0.195 0.205 0.204 endorsement -0.049 -0.050 -0.049 -0.047 reinvest/assets 0.003 -0.001 0.007 -0.002 RD_rate/revenue 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 ln(number of employee) -0.019*** -0.018*** -0.016*** -0.019*** ROA -0.040 -0.040 -0.043 -0.040 firm_age -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 y2001 -0.044*** -0.044*** -0.044*** -0.044*** y2002 -0.035** -0.035** -0.036** -0.035** y2003 -0.039** -0.040** -0.041** -0.039** y2004 -0.026 -0.026 -0.028 -0.026 y2005 -0.034** -0.034** -0.036** -0.034** components -0.003 -0.004 -0.001 -0.002 semiconductor -0.042*** -0.040*** -0.038*** -0.042*** electrical 0.024 0.027 0.026 0.024 machinery -0.024 -0.024 -0.024 -0.024 pharmaceutical -0.023 -0.024 -0.021 -0.023 photoelectric -0.026 -0.028 -0.022 -0.027 communication 0.014 0.008 0.016 0.013 _cons 1.100*** 1.098*** 1.085*** 1.102*** R-squared 0.0596 0.0678 0.067 0.0619 Observations 1242 1242 1242 1242

(23)

21 References

Admati, A. R., Pfleiderer, P., & Zechner, J. 1994. Large Shareholder Activism, Risk Sharing, and Financial Market Equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy, 102(6): 1097-1130.

Almeida, H. V., & Wolfenzon, D. 2006. A theory of pyramidal ownership and family business groups. Journal of Finance, 61(6): 2637-2680.

Belenzon, S., & Berkovitz, T. 2010. Innovation in Business Groups. Management

Science, 56(3): 519-535.

Belloc, F. 2011. Corporate governance and innovation: a survey. Journal of Economic

Surveys, In Press.

Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. 2002. Process management and technological innovation: A longitudinal study of the photography and paint industries.

Administrative Science Quarterly, 47(4): 676-706.

Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. 1932. The modern corporation and private property. New York: Macmillan.

Chang, S. J., Chung, C. N., & Mahmood, I. P. 2006. When and how does business group affiliation promote firm innovation? A tale of two emerging economies.

Organization Science, 17(5): 637-656.

Chrisman, J. J., & C., P. P. 2011. Variations in R&D Investments of Family and

Non-family Firms: Behavioral Agency and Myopic Loss Aversion Perspectives.

Academy of Management Journal, In Press.

Del Monte, A., & Papagni, E. 2003. R&D and the growth of firms: empirical analysis of a panel of Italian firms. Research Policy, 32(6): 1003-1014.

Dyer, W. G., & Whetten, D. A. 2006. Family firms and social responsibility: Preliminary evidence from the S&P 500. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 30(6): 785-802.

Francis, J., & Smith, A. 1995. Agency Costs and Innovation Some Empirical-Evidence.

Journal of Accounting & Economics, 19(2-3): 383-409.

Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Makri, M., & Kintana, M. L. 2010. Diversification Decisions in Family-Controlled Firms. Journal of Management Studies, 47(2): 223-252. Hall, B. 1932. "Land" and Taxes on Monopolists. American Economic Review, 22(4):

693-694.

Hall, B. H., & Ziedonis, R. H. 2001. The patent paradox revisited: an empirical study of patenting in the US semiconductor industry, 1979-1995. Rand Journal of

Economics, 32(1): 101-128.

Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., Johnson, R. A., & Moesel, D. D. 1996. The market for corporate control and firm innovation. Academy of Management Journal,

(24)

22 39(5): 1084-1119.

Holmstrom, B. 1989. Agency Costs and Innovation. Journal of Economic Behavior &

Organization, 12(3): 305-327.

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Grossman, W. 2002. Conflicting voices: The effects of institutional ownership heterogeneity and internal governance on corporate innovation strategies. Academy of Management Journal, 45(4): 697-716.

Johnson, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2000. Tunneling.

American Economic Review, 90(2): 22-27.

Khanna, T., & Yafeh, Y. 2005. Business groups and risk sharing around the world.

Journal of Business, 78(1): 301-340.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 1999. Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance, 54(2): 471-517.

Lavie, D., Stettner, U., & Tushman, M. L. 2010. Exploration and Exploitation Within and Across Organizations. Academy of Management Annals, 4: 109-155. Lee, P. M., & O'Neill, H. M. 2003. Ownership structures and R&D investments of US

and Japanese firms: Agency and stewardship perspectives. Academy of

Management Journal, 46(2): 212-225.

Mahmood, I. P., & Zheng, W. T. 2009. Whether and how: Effects of international joint ventures on local innovation in an emerging economy. Research Policy, 38(9): 1489-1503.

Mansfield, E. 1986. Patents and Innovation - an Empirical-Study. Management

Science, 32(2): 173-181.

March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational Learning.

Organization Science, 2(1): 71-87.

Masulis, R. W., Pham, P. K., & Zein, J. 2011. Family Business Groups around the World: Financing Advantages, Control Motivations, and Organizational Choices.

Review of Financial Studies, 24(11): 3556-3600.

Morck, R., Wolfenzon, D., & Yeung, B. 2005. Corporate governance, economic entrenchment, and growth. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(3): 655-720. Nakatani, I. 1984. The economic role of financial corporate grouping. In M. Aoki (Ed.),

the economic analysis of the Japanese firm. New York: North-Holland.

Nohria, N., & Gulati, R. 1996. Is slack good or bad for innovation? Academy of

Management Journal, 39(5): 1245-1264.

Scherer, F. M. 1965. Firm Size, Market-Structure, Opportunity, and the Output of Patented Inventions. American Economic Review, 55(5): 1097-1125.

Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1986. Large Shareholders and Corporate-Control. Journal

(25)

23

Soete, L. L. G. 1979. Firm Size and Inventive Activity - Evidence Reconsidered.

European Economic Review, 12(4): 319-340.

Sundaram, A. K., John, T. A., & John, K. 1996. An empirical analysis of strategic competition and firm values - The case of R&D competition. Journal of

Financial Economics, 40(3): 459-486.

Villalonga, B., & Amit, R. 2006. How do family ownership, control and management affect firm value? Journal of Financial Economics, 80(2): 385-417.

(26)

1

國科會補助專題研究計畫項下赴國外(或大陸地區)出差或研習心得報告

日期: 年 月 日

一、國外(大陸)研究過程

此次出國目的有二,一是至大陸拜訪可能的訪問對象,二是到香港參加 2012

IACMR Conference。

大陸參訪過程:

實務上對台商而言,大陸不止能提供製造業相對低廉的勞工,更提供了一個廣大

的消費市場,然而,大陸仍為一政府主導的市場,對外資企業而言,如何在一個

制度不完善、但政治穩定度高的國家中制定正確的策略,是一個急待研究的議

題,更重要的是,實務上大陸目前正處於從出口導向型經濟轉向為內需導向型經

濟,過去研究探討制度對集團企業的影響多著重於當地集團企業如何因應制度環

境的改變,而較少從外資如何面對制度變遷此一面向出發,目前的研究結果告訴

我們隨著市場越來越完善,集團企業的重要性會降低,建立內部市場的門檻也會

增加,但若集團企業能有能力利用一些特殊的無形資產(如政商關係)進行轉型

投資,集團企業反而較非集團企業有優勢,然而制度的轉型過程中,外資所扮演

的角色卻是很少被研究的,因此這次大陸參訪的重點在於瞭解集團企業在大陸的

概況並尋求可能的參訪對象。

相對於以中小企業台商為主的珠三角地區,長三角地區的台商則多為大型集團,

其中包括傳統業與電子業,如統一、華碩等,至今大型餐飲集團也逐漸進軍大陸,

如王品。此行透過友人的安排接觸了幾間工廠、一間餐廳及一個服務品牌的負責

人,然而最大的收獲則是認識了安信國際投顧的胡總。

胡總是 1997 年到蘇州獨立創業的,一開始對大陸資本市場有興趣而開始收集大

陸政策法規及各個上市公司的經營狀況,然而,因為當時大陸股市不確定性太

高,於是胡總轉而利用手上收集的市場資訊來服務在大陸投資的台商。從每週舉

計畫編號

NSC

98-2410-H-004-048

-MY3

計畫名稱

集團企業的繼承與創新

出國人員

姓名

莊皓鈞

服務機構

及職稱

政大科管所博士候選人

出國時間

101 年 6 月 20 日至

101 年 6 月 24 日

出國地點

大陸地區及香港

附件五

(27)

2

辦一次的免費經濟講座開始做起,經營了一年多,許多有接觸的台商開始相信安

信團隊的專業,於是開始聘請胡總在長江三角洲地區替他們選擇適合的投資地

點,由於安信團隊長期、大量地收集當地市場資訊,因此能做到比大陸人更瞭解

大陸投資環境,1999 年起五年內已經為 50 多家台商找到適合的投資地點,在提

供政策訊息、商情諮詢上也擁有 70 多家固定客戶。

這次我參與的座談會中,胡總也分享了他對未來大陸經濟情勢的看法,他認為長

期而言中國還是會持續成長,雖然短期內因為歐美經濟不景氣,中國出口減少,

可能使得人民幣在短期內較弱,但從長期趨勢來看,他認為中國經濟仍會持續成

長,主要原因在於大陸會從出口經濟轉向內需經濟,未來隨著中產階級的興起,

中國經濟可望持續成長,同時,中產階級興起也會帶動服務業的成長。

雖然還不確定未來中國的生活型態與服務業的發展型式,但從這次參訪可以發

現,已經台商已經開始引入休閒農場及啤酒屋等行業,一服飾公司的做法則是在

當地風景區建立通路販售過季商品,將觀光與購物結合在一起,種種跡象也與胡

總的看法不謀而合。我們相信這些經驗與人脈則有助於本研究未來將研究主題延

伸至「集團企業的國際投資策略」上。

參加 2012 IACMR Conference:

IACMR 為在美華人為致力於華人管理研究與發展而創立的協會,創辦人徐淑英

(Anne S. Tsui)為唯一同時獲得 ASQ 與 AMJ 最佳論文獎的華人管理學者,目前

為 AOM 會長(2011-2012)

,曾擔任 AMJ 主編,做為華人最有成就的學者之一,其

創新 IACRM 的目的在為建立一個華人研究的平台,這幾年下來,在兩岸三地辦過

多場研究方法工作坊,二年一度的會議除了邀請國際一流的學者來分享最新的研

究趨勢與成果外,更設計活動創造新進學者與大師面對面的機會,這是一個知識

分享、創造與合作的平台,聚集了世界級的精英,並且重視華人脈絡,對一個致

力於本土學術研究的新進學者而言,這個會議能幫助其研究成果讓世界看到。

這次是我第一次參加,會議貼心的安排了新進會員介紹會,在介紹會中除了有有

趣的活動幫助新進人員瞭解整個學會的歷史與 mission,還有學生代表現身說

法,Dong Lui 畢業於 University of Washington,目前任教於 Georgia Institute

of Technology,他在博士班其間積極利用 IACMR 提供的資源,他認為參與工作

坊與研討會幫助他將文章修改得更好,因此他也非常願意回饋學會,擔任學生代

表與 reviewer,並鼓勵我們將作品拿到會議中與大師討論。

參加這次的會議與本研究相關的議題集中在第二天關於公司治理與家族企業的

議題,我希望透過這次的會議瞭解此領域的發展方向,除此之外,其他時間我盡

量透過參與 Keynote panel 瞭解目前管理學最新的研究議題。

(28)

3

第一天:

早上的 Keynote 由陳明哲教授開場,他一上台就說美國人通常會以笑話開場,但

華人卻往往是以抱歉開場,他除了以這一個例子說明中西差異外,更想表達華人

企業研究的必要性,接著他以他自己的動態競爭理論為例點出東方思想如何幫助

他建立理論。

他說他一直在問一個問題:什麼是競爭?在他眼中,競爭是 dyad 的,是一來一

往動態的,在這個互動的過程中,其機制為競爭雙方是否察覺(awareness)對

手的行動、是否產生競爭的動機(motivation),以及是否有能力來回應

(capability),他說這一整套的動態競爭理論包含了華人固有的思想

(indigenous)。除此之外,他還分享了他對華人企業的觀察,他認為華人企業

與西方企業不同之處在於受到儒家思想的影響,我們的企業在競爭上比較不傾向

打倒對手,此外也可以看到一些甘於做小的企業,我們的企業也比較傾向合作而

不是競爭,他認為這些都是未來的研究議題。

最後他鼓勵後進學者要能專一與堅持。

下午 social structure and organizations 的主講人有著名的制度理論學家

Woody Powell 以及社會學家 Mark Granovetter,分別提出他們最新的研究議題。

Powell 收集了美國 1970 年代開始生技產業中全部的 the dedicated biotech

firm (DBF),並研究這些新創新公司在前十年的創業行為,他發現新企業的出現

主要是透過兩種機制:recombination and transposition。所謂 recombination

指的是在大公司中的執行長結合過去實務經驗與新的科學技術而成立,並以商業

化為主要目標(In science to do business),相反的,transposition 指的是

將技術移植至實務界而形成的新企業,其創辦人多半是腳跨學術與實務界的科學

家所(amphibious scientist-founders)

,而形成研究導向的企業(In business

to do science)。他認為雖然透過 transposition 機制形成的企業本質上存在新

進者的劣勢(liability of newness)

,但能產生重大發明的卻也是這些企業。

Mark Granovetter 過去提出弱連結的優勢(the strength of weak ties),他

發現點頭之交對於找工作的人比較有幫助,他認為弱連結較多元,是對外性的連

結,因此能促進連結外部資訊。他這次則是用弱連結的觀點來檢視 Facebook 或

Twitter 等線上的社會媒體(online social media),他認為因為人們因為時間

跟認知的限制而無法全面瞭解自己的社會網絡,這使得人們使用線上社會媒體來

瞭解自己所處的社會網絡面向,但線上社會媒體還能幫助人們恢復失聯的關係、

維持關係,甚至建立新的弱連絡,從中東社會革命運動來看,就可以發現這些線

上社會媒體的影響力。

(29)

4

第二天

在 Corporate Governance and Ownership 這場中總共有四篇文章,前三篇文章

與所有權有關:

第一篇文章 The Ownership and Performance of Asian Firms: A Meta-analysis

of the Effects of Institutional Voids and Ownership Identity 回顧了 145

個過去的實證研究進行 meta-analysis,其結果發現所有權對績效的關係受到制

度的影響,此研究中顯示,東亞 14 個國家中所有權集中程度對績效有正向影響

的有 4 個國家(南韓、新加坡、約旦及香港),有負向影響的包括了日本及

Armenia,其他國家則無影響。所有者類型則是另一個影響所有權與績效關係的

因素,外資(foreign owners)及散戶(market owners)比重越高,廠商的績

效也越好,相反地,stable owner 卻有負向影響。

第二篇文章 Does Owner Type Matter for Firm Performance? Manufacturing

Firms in China 1998-2007 使用的是中國製造業的資料,但與第一篇文章一樣

關心「誰是所有者?」這個問題,這篇文章將所有者分成 central government,

financial institutions, corporations, private individuals, foreign

investors 四類,並比較所有者的影響與廠商特性(資源與能力)何者的影響較

大,結果發現,雖然所有者對廠商績效有影響,但更重要的是廠商特性。但問題

是,這裡所指的廠商特性是 error term,這個指標過於模糊。

第三篇文章 FOREIGN INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS, POLITICAL TIES, AND CORPORATE

GOVERNANCE REFORMS IN EMERGING ECONOMIES 是台灣的研究,這篇文章認為政

商關係有 2 種效果,一方面,有政商關係的廠商能取得額外資源,因此較能低抗

對抗外部壓力,另一方面,有政商關係的廠商必須配合政府政策,因此當政策改

變時(改善公司治理)有政商關係的廠商反而有義務配合。這篇文章發現,外資

有助於廠商改善公司治理(獨立董監比例高),而政商關係則會阻礙廠商改善公

司治理,但外資與政商關係的交互作用卻反而正向影響公司治理的改善。

在 Business Group and Family Firms 這場也有四篇文章,其中就有三篇是使用

台灣集團企業的資料,一篇是中國大陸的資料,其中一位是台灣的學者,其他三

位都是國立新加坡大學的博士生。

第一篇文章試圖比較型一代理問題與型二代理問題的影響,這篇文章主要的發現

是在家族企集團中,CEO duality 能降低型一代理問題,而金字塔的控制結構對

未公開發行公司而言能降低代理問題,但對公開發行公司卻會增加代理問題,作

者藉此發現意圖推論對台灣家族集團企業而言,型一代理問題重於型二代理問

題。

(30)

5

第二篇文章在討論外資所有權對家族控制董事會席次的影響,其結果發現外資持

股越高,家族控制董事會席次越少,而家族所有權越高家族較不會失去控制權,

此外,regulation(台灣走向西方公司治理模式)會增加外資的影響力,因此外

資持股對降低家族控制的影響會增強,而家族控制的影響也會減少。

第三篇文章 DOES OWNERSHIP MATTER? 使用的是中國的資料,大陸研究集團企業

與台灣明顯不同的是他們比較重視政府的角色,台灣在解除管制後,政府的角色

弱化,但目前中國的國營企業仍佔很大的影響力,此研究發現,非國營的集團母

公司代理問題較少,CEO 學經歷對國家所有權集團績效的影響弱於民營與地方集

團,國家所有權較地方或民間所有權有利於集團間無形資產的分享,而民間所有

權則有利於集團間有形財務資產的分享。

第四篇文章也是台灣集團企業的資料,這個研究企圖說明家族特性對廠商多角化

的影響,從代理觀點出發,多角化的目的在於實現家庭利益(而非企業利益),

因此當家族認知鑲嵌程度大時,廠商會選擇成立獨立子公司達成多角化,而非成

立內部部門。

第三天:

John Child 認為中國的特色是政治及政府介入商業活動極深,並有其歷史淵

源,中國的資本主義也因此被認為是一種變型的資本主義──國家資本主義

(state capitalism)。因此國家所有權及對廠商的影響就變得非常重要,過去

學者就曾討論過國家、地方及民營企業因文化與制度不同,對經濟協調與控制也

有不同的回應方式,這三種不同的系統中也呈現出對立的價值,不同的所有權、

控制權以及不同的資本或資源取得方式。因此在討論中國企業時必不可忽略政治

及制度觀點。同樣地,政府或制度對於廠商的海外投資也有直接的影響(如提供

低成本的財務資助)

,而政府及制度代理人對地方企業及民營企業國際化的影響

卻是目前為止仍很少被討論的。

為了解決上述問題,John Child 提供了一個「制度限制」及「政治穩定度」兩

構面的架構給大家參考,他的分析中美國屬於制度完整、政治穩定高的國家,而

中國則屬於制度不完整、政治穩定度高的國家,透過這個架構我們能瞭解不同地

區研究的差異性。

接著 John Child 的是 Oded Shenkar,他認為雖然中國研究常常受到評論質疑其

資料可靠度及合法性,其知識體系、出口及對外投資方式都與西方有很大的差

異,而使得中國研究不被重視。要改善這種情況必須有像 John Child 如此富有

名聲的學者來投入,才能使得管理研究需要中國的野田,也使得管理研究能對中

國有所幫助。他也提出了與 John Child 類似的、可能的研究觀點:

(31)

6

2. Context

3. Institution

4. History

5. Chinese perspective

6. SMEs

7. 聯盟的共演化

8. 政治對策略制定的影響

最後 Redding 接著提出他的中國商業系統的觀點(business system)

。他比較中

國式的資本主義與其他國家的資本主義發現,中國在下一個十到二十年之內都很

難形成美國式的資本主義,但比較容易走向南韓的路線。不過這條路仍存在兩個

主要的問題:一、經濟上的創新能力;二、在管理上能否授權。前者隨著大學、

資本市場及智財權的強化而能獲得改善,但後者在中國卻是一個難題。其主要原

因在於華人社會普遍缺乏制度信任、老闆常常親力親為或只信任少數親信,這對

於發展有效率、世界級、能處理複雜任務的管理系統是很大的阻礙。雖然從匯流

研究來看,廠商的商業系統會趨同:有同樣的組織行為、策略能力,但這不意味

著所有廠商都會採用相同的技術或例規(routines),從制度理論來看,這是文

化的影響,從複雜理論來看,這意味者在表面上可以看到廠商行為趨同,但不同

的社會特性仍會表現在經濟行為上。

二、心得

IACMR 聚集了全世界對華人世界有興趣的學者,這使得與會者有機會把本土研究

展現給世界,也有助於促使本土研究達到國際水準,如在這次的會議中,我有時

間把研究成果跟國立新加坡大學的鐘基年討論,鐘基年長年研究台灣家族集團企

業,並有許多研究成果發表 ASQ、AMJ、SMJ 等頂級期刊,能與這類型的學者研討

有助於我們將研究做得更好,並提供了未來與知名學者合作的機會。

(32)

國科會補助計畫衍生研發成果推廣資料表

日期:2012/11/30

國科會補助計畫

計畫名稱: 集團企業的繼承與創新 計畫主持人: 溫肇東 計畫編號: 98-2410-H-004-048-MY3 學門領域: 策略管理

無研發成果推廣資料

(33)

98 年度專題研究計畫研究成果彙整表

計畫主持人:溫肇東 計畫編號:98-2410-H-004-048-MY3 計畫名稱:集團企業的繼承與創新 量化 成果項目 實際已達成 數(被接受 或已發表) 預期總達成 數(含實際已 達成數) 本計畫實 際貢獻百 分比 單位 備 註 ( 質 化 說 明:如 數 個 計 畫 共 同 成 果、成 果 列 為 該 期 刊 之 封 面 故 事 ... 等) 期刊論文 0 0 100% 研究報告/技術報告 0 0 100% 研討會論文 0 0 100% 篇 論文著作 專書 0 0 100% 申請中件數 0 0 100% 專利 已獲得件數 0 0 100% 件 件數 0 0 100% 件 技術移轉 權利金 0 0 100% 千元 碩士生 0 0 100% 博士生 1 1 100% 博士後研究員 0 0 100% 國內 參與計畫人力 (本國籍) 專任助理 0 0 100% 人次 期刊論文 0 0 100% 研究報告/技術報告 0 0 100% 研討會論文 1 1 100% 篇 論文著作 專書 0 0 100% 章/本 申請中件數 0 0 100% 專利 已獲得件數 0 0 100% 件 件數 0 0 100% 件 技術移轉 權利金 0 0 100% 千元 碩士生 0 0 100% 博士生 0 0 100% 博士後研究員 0 0 100% 國外 參與計畫人力 (外國籍) 專任助理 0 0 100% 人次

(34)

其他成果

(

無法以量化表達之成 果如辦理學術活動、獲 得獎項、重要國際合 作、研究成果國際影響 力及其他協助產業技 術發展之具體效益事 項等,請以文字敘述填 列。) 無 成果項目 量化 名稱或內容性質簡述 測驗工具(含質性與量性) 0 課程/模組 0 電腦及網路系統或工具 0 教材 0 舉辦之活動/競賽 0 研討會/工作坊 0 電子報、網站 0 目 計畫成果推廣之參與(閱聽)人數 0

(35)

國科會補助專題研究計畫成果報告自評表

請就研究內容與原計畫相符程度、達成預期目標情況、研究成果之學術或應用價

值(簡要敘述成果所代表之意義、價值、影響或進一步發展之可能性)

、是否適

合在學術期刊發表或申請專利、主要發現或其他有關價值等,作一綜合評估。

1. 請就研究內容與原計畫相符程度、達成預期目標情況作一綜合評估

■達成目標

□未達成目標(請說明,以 100 字為限)

□實驗失敗

□因故實驗中斷

□其他原因

說明:

2. 研究成果在學術期刊發表或申請專利等情形:

論文:□已發表 ■未發表之文稿 □撰寫中 □無

專利:□已獲得 □申請中 ■無

技轉:□已技轉 □洽談中 ■無

其他:(以 100 字為限)

此計畫前 2 年以收集國內主要集團企業資料為主,含蓋中華徵信所 1972-2007 年百大集團 企業資料及 TEJ 集團企業資料庫,兩項資料庫皆已建置完成。此外,目前此計畫完成 1 篇國 際研討會論文(已被接受),另有 2 篇未發表之文稿,預計投稿 2013 年中舉辦的 AOM。

3. 請依學術成就、技術創新、社會影響等方面,評估研究成果之學術或應用價

值(簡要敘述成果所代表之意義、價值、影響或進一步發展之可能性)(以

500 字為限)

集團企業為英美之外世界各地普遍存在的組織型式,但此類研究受英美學術主流文獻的影 響而長期被忽略,自 2000 年左右始有財務學者開始關注,接著管理學者也跟進,目前研 究仍以集團績效、多角化策略受到較多的討論,未來的趨勢則聚焦於高階管理階層、社會 脈絡以及創新。本研究結合了集團企業資料、專利資料以及總經理董事長學經歷資料,因 此極具發展潛力。

數據

Table 2. Results of zero-inflated negative binomial (ZINB) regression for total number of patents

參考文獻

相關文件

• The  ArrayList class is an example of a  collection class. • Starting with version 5.0, Java has added a  new kind of for loop called a for each

The proof is based on Hida’s ideas in [Hid04a], where Hida provided a general strategy to study the problem of the non-vanishing of Hecke L-values modulo p via a study on the

The main interest in the interpretation and discussion of passages from the sutra is to get a clear picture of how women are portrayed in the sutra and to find out

Quality kindergarten education should be aligned with primary and secondary education in laying a firm foundation for the sustainable learning and growth of

• Introduction of language arts elements into the junior forms in preparation for LA electives.. Curriculum design for

We explicitly saw the dimensional reason for the occurrence of the magnetic catalysis on the basis of the scaling argument. However, the precise form of gap depends

According to a team at Baycrest’s Rotman Research Institute in Canada, there is a clear link between bilingualism and a delayed onset of the symptoms of Alzheimer ’s and other

H., Liu, S.J., and Chang, P.L., “Knowledge Value Adding Model for Quantitative Performance Evaluation of the Community of Practice in a Consulting Firm,” Proceedings of