• 沒有找到結果。

Conflicts between Managers and Investors over the Optimal Financial Contract

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Conflicts between Managers and Investors over the Optimal Financial Contract"

Copied!
16
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Conflicts between Managers and Investors over the Optimal

Financial Contract

Richard Fairchild*

Department of Corporate Finance, University of Bath, U.K.

Abstract

We develop a principal-agent model of financial contracting in which investors face moral hazard problems relating to managerial effort. The level of debt potentially mitigates these problems in two ways. For high debt levels, the manager owns more of the equity, and also the threat of financial distress increases. In the absence of financial distress costs, we derive a novel irrelevance result; the financial contract does not affect managerial effort or firm value. Therefore, the manager and the investors are indifferent between a high debt and low debt contract. In the presence of financial distress costs, the manager has an incentive to increase his effort level in order to reduce the threat of distress. Now investors unambiguously prefer the (value-maximising) high debt contract. When effort costs and financial distress costs are low, the manager also prefers the high debt contract. When effort costs and financial distress costs are high, the manager prefers the (value-minimising) low debt contract.

Key words: financial contracting; moral hazard; equity ownership; financial distress JEL classification: G32

1. Introduction

In the field of corporate finance, it has long been recognised that the way in which a firm finances its activities can have a substantial effect on its performance and valuation in the market. Modigliani and Miller’s (1958; henceforth abbreviated MM) seminal irrelevance theorem stated that, under certain conditions, the value of the firm is independent of its capital structure (for example, MM assumed that the manager always acts in the shareholders’ best interests). Subsequent research has sought to examine the conditions under which a firm’s capital structure can affect its value.

In this paper, we develop a principal-agent model of financial contracting in which investors (the principals) provide finance, and then the manager (the agent) exerts effort in creating firm value. Since investors provide money up-front, and

Received August 30, 2003, revised December 14, 2003, accepted February 9, 2004.

*Correspondence to: Department of Corporate Finance, School of Management, University of Bath, Bath

(2)

then the manager makes value-affecting decisions, we can study the relationship with a focus on moral hazard (hidden action) problems. The investors are only in-terested in value-maximising policies, while the manager may pursue other (value-reducing) objectives, such as extracting money from the firm for private benefits, or not exert the high effort levels required for firm value maximisation.

Jensen and Meckling’s (1976; henceforth JM) pioneering agency cost model demonstrated how the capital structure may affect firm value in a principal-agent setting. They considered an owner-manager who seeks finance for a new project. If he issues a large amount of outside equity, he dilutes his own equity stake. This in-creases his incentives to spend company funds on private benefits, hence reducing firm value. If he increases the debt level and reduces the level of outside equity, he increases his own equity stake. Hence, a high debt level reduces his incentives to spend company funds on his private benefits, and this increases firm value.

JM only considered the income rights relating to debt and equity (debt holders obtain the first, fixed claim on the company’s income, while the equity holders are residual claimants). Recent financial contracting research (e.g., Grossman and Hart, 1982; Aghion and Bolton, 1992; Dewatripont and Tirole, 1994; Zwiebel, 1996; and Jong and Veld, 2000) has recognised that securities allocate both income and control rights. Debt holders have the right to liquidate the firm if they are not paid, while equity holders have much weaker control rights.

The financial contracting research views debt as a disciplining device. For ex-ample, in Grossman and Hart’s (1982) model, the bankruptcy threat of debt can mitigate the manager’s incentives to extract company funds for his own consump-tion. In Aghion and Bolton’s (1992) model, the financial contract is designed to force the firm to make an efficient liquidation/continuation decision. When the firm is performing effectively, equity holders make the value-maximising decision to allow the firm to continue. When the firm is performing badly, debt holders make the value-maximising liquidation decision. In Dewatripont and Tirole’s (1994; henceforth DT) model, the liquidation threat from debt holders affects the manager’s effort level.

It is generally assumed that the manager chooses the financial contract. Fur-thermore, under the assumption that financial markets are competitive, price-taking investors pay a fair price for securities. The implication is that the manager gains all of the value-added from the financial contract. Hence, in JM’s model, it is in the manager’s interests to align himself with investors by adopting the value-maximising capital structure.

However, Garvey and Hanka (1997) argue that, when the manager has no eq-uity stake and is only concerned with keeping his job, he may not be aligned with investors in choosing the value-maximising capital structure. He may avoid debt, in order to avoid financial distress costs.

As far as we are aware, no model exists that satisfactorily combines the two incentive-aligning roles of debt; that is, the effect of debt on the manager’s equity stake and the effect of the financial distress threat of debt. Our principal-agent model addresses this. Our specific goal in this paper is to analyse when managers and

(3)

in-vestors may be aligned in their capital structure preferences and when they may be in conflict. We demonstrate that this depends crucially on the manager’s marginal cost of effort and on the level of financial distress costs. Our main results are as fol-lows.

(a) When we only consider the effect of debt on the manager’s equity stake, we de-rive a novel “irrelevance” result. Increasing the level of debt increases the manager’s equity stake, but this is neutralised by the increase in the required debt repayments (that is, the increase in the face value of debt) due to the increased risk faced by debt holders. Therefore, increasing debt does not increase managerial effort or firm value. Hence, both the manager and the investors are indifferent between a high debt and low debt contract.

(b) When we introduce financial distress costs, increasing the level of debt increases the manager’s effort levels as he seeks to avoid financial distress. When financial distress and effort costs are low, the manager and the investors’ interests are aligned in preferring the high debt contract. When financial distress and effort costs are high, there is a conflict of interests, with the manager choosing the low debt contract.

The paper is organised as follows. In the next section, we describe and develop the model. In Section 3, we compare the pure debt and the debt-equity contracts in order to analyse when the manager’s and investors’ capital structure preferences are aligned or in conflict. The equilibrium financial contract is derived in Section 4. In Section 5, we focus on the case where the pure debt contract forces a higher effort level. We present a numerical example in Section 6. Section 7 provides the conclu-sion and directions for future theoretical and empirical research.

2. The Model

We consider a firm operating in an economy consisting of risk-neutral agents. Since agents are risk-neutral, they are only concerned with their expected cashflows, and not with the variability of these cashflows. Furthermore, since they are risk-neutral, they discount future cashflows at the risk-free rate (that is, they do not require a risk premium). For simplicity, we assume that the risk-free rate is zero. Therefore, we do not need to discount future cashflows when considering an agent’s wealth.

We consider the following sequence of events.

Date 0: A project becomes available to the firm. The manager issues securities, and,

if he raises sufficient funds, he invests in the project.

Date 1: The manager exerts an effort level which affects the outcome of the project. Date 2: The outcome of the project is realised, payoffs occur, and the world ends.

(4)

The details of the model are as follows. A firm, with no assets in place and no current projects, has an opportunity to invest in a new project. The project requires investment funds I at date 0. Two possible states can occur at date 2. The good

state occurs with probability p, in which case the project provides income RH

(H for “high income”). The bad state occurs with probability 1−p, in which

case the project provides income of RL ( L for “low income”), with

.

H L

R > >I R Therefore, if the firm takes this project, the date 0 value of the firm is

(1 ) .

H L

V = pR + −p R

At date 1, the manager exerts effort ei, where i∈{ , }.L H That is, he can ex-ert a high effort level, eH, or he can exert a low effort level, eL, with eH >eL.

The manager faces a cost of effort C e( ),i with C e( )H >C e( ).L

Managerial effort positively affects the probability of the good state, such that [0,1].

e p

γ = ∈ Therefore, date 0 firm value can be written as Ve Ri H +

(1−γe Ri) .L We assume that γe RH H + −(1 γeH)RLe RL H + −(1 γe RL) LI; that

is, the value of the firm exceeds the required investment funds, whether the manager exerts the high or low effort level. Hence, the manager can always obtain funding. Note that γ represents managerial ability; the higher is γ the greater the effect , of effort level on the good state probability.

Two possible methods of finance are available to the manager at date 0. He can issue a pure debt contract to investors, retaining all of the equity himself, or he can issue a debt/equity contract.

Throughout the model, we assume that the financial market is competitive, such that investors are price-takers. The implication of this is that financial contracts are fairly priced. Hence, the investors provide finance at zero net present value (NPV); that is, they provide investment funds at date 0 equal to the discounted value of expected future cashflows. Recall that we assume risk-neutrality and a zero risk-free rate; this means that the discount rate is zero. Hence, in equilibrium, the financial contract must be priced such that it has a terminal expected value ,I in order that competitive investors provide investment funds I at date 0.

For example, the debt contract contains the face value of debt D which in a , competitive market will be set such that the expected value of the debt contract is

.

I In issuing debt and equity, the expected value of total equity will determine what proportion of equity α the manager will be able to retain and what proportion (1−α) he can issue such that the total debt-equity contract is worth I to the in-vestors. We will analyse this in more detail in the next section.

Since investors provide finance at zero NPV, the manager gains all of the posi-tive NPV. Hence, the manager ultimately suffers from his own moral hazard problem relating to effort level. If investors expect low managerial effort after they have pro-vided finance, α and D adjust in equilibrium such that the financial contract remains valued at ,I and it is the manager who suffers in terms of reduced NPV. Hence, it may be in the manager’s interests to use the financial contract as a com-mitment device; that is, to commit to a high effort level.

The manager must raise sufficient funds I in order to take the project. Recall that I>RL. Therefore, if he raises the investment funds using a pure debt contract,

(5)

the debt holders do not receive full payment if the bad state occurs. Furthermore, a feature of a debt contract is that the holders’ income is capped at the face value (i.e., the maximum that they can receive in the good state). As we analyse below, this means that the face value of debt must actually exceed the required investment funds, so that the holders are compensated for the shortfall in the bad state. In finance, we term this risky debt (from the debt holders’ point of view), where risk relates to volatility of income.

From the manager’s viewpoint, if he finances the project with a pure debt con-tract, he faces financial distress costs F in the case where debt holders are not paid at date 1. The manager can avoid financial distress costs by reducing the debt level so that the debt holders are guaranteed to receive the same fixed payment in either state; that is, debt is risk-free (from the debt holders’ point of view). The manager does so by issuing debt with a face value RL. Since the debt holders are guaranteed payment of RL in either state at date 2, they will be willing to invest RL at date 0

(recall that we are assuming a discount rate of zero). Hence, the manager can avoid financial distress costs by reducing the debt level so that debt is risk-free. However, since debt holders are only willing to invest RL, he must raise the balance of the funds by issuing equity. This dilutes the manager’s equity stake.

The main aim of our model is to analyse when the manager and the investors are aligned or in conflict in their choice of financial contract. In the presence of fi-nancial distress costs, we will demonstrate that investors aim to maximise firm value and so (weakly) prefer the pure debt contract since the threat of financial distress forces high managerial effort. The manager may or may not prefer the pure debt contract. He may use the pure debt contract to commit to a high effort level since this has a positive effect on his NPV. However, this incentive is crucially affected by his cost of effort and the expected financial distress costs. If either is too high, he will prefer the debt-equity contract.

We solve the game by backward induction. That is, we first take the financial contract, D , and α as given and solve for the manager’s optimal effort level. Then we solve for the competitively market-determined D and α . We finally work out the impact on the payoffs and solve for the optimal security structure (both from the viewpoint of the manager and the investors).

3. Comparison of Financial Contracts

We solve the game by backward induction. That is, we first take the financial contract (pure debt or debt-equity) as given. Within these contracts, we initially take the values D and α under the assumption that the manager exerts equilibrium effort level *.e We then solve for the manager’s equilibrium effort level. Next, we recognise that, in equilibrium, the market-determined D and α and the optimal effort level must be consistent with each other. Next, we derive the manager’s and the investors’ equilibrium payoffs. This will enable us to determine the manager’s and investors’ optimal contracts. Finally, we derive the equilibrium contract.

(6)

First, we consider the pure debt contract. The respective expected payoffs for the manager, the debt holders, and the total firm value at date 0 are:

( ) ( ( *)) (1 ) ( ) D i i H i i M ee RD e − −γe FC e , (1) ( *) (1 ) D i i L Se D e + −γe R =I, (2) (1 ) D i H i L Ve R + −γe R . (3)

We analyse these payoffs as follows. The first term in (1) represents the man-ager’s payoff if the good state occurs. The good state occurs with probability γ ei. In this state, the debt holders’ payoff is capped at the face value D e( *). The man-ager receives the remainder RHD e( *). The second term represents his payoff in the bad state. The bad state occurs with probability (1−γei). In this state, the debt holders are not fully paid, and so the manager faces financial distress costs .F The final term in (1) is the manager’s cost of effort.

The first term in (2) represents the debt holders’ capped payoff, D e( *), if the good state occurs. If the bad state occurs, the debt holders only receive RL. As

dis-cussed in the previous section, competitive debt holders invest at zero NPV; that is, the debt contract is worth .I

Equation (3) represents total firm value. Since investors are risk-neutral and the risk-free rate is zero, total firm value equals the expected date 2 cashflow, which in the good state is RH and in the bad state is RL. Furthermore, we note that

(1 ) ( );

D D D i i

M +S =V − −γe FC e that is, the manager and the debt holders have a share in firm value, but the manager also faces private financial distress costs and effort costs. This provides a conflict between investors, who wish to maximise firm value, and the manager, who is also concerned with his private costs.

Using backward induction, we first recognise that the manager’s equilibrium effort level is affected by the face value of debt. We then note that the face value of debt is determined in (2) by the manager’s effort level. Intuitively, if the debt holders expect a low managerial effort level, they will set a high face value of debt (as com-pensation for the low probability of being fully paid). If they expect a high manage-rial effort level, they will set a low face value of debt.

In equilibrium, the market-determined face value of debt must be consistent with the manager’s equilibrium effort level, and the manager’s equilibrium effort level must be consistent with the equilibrium face value of debt.

We solve as follows. First, take as given that the market has set the face value of debt D e( *). What will the manager’s optimal effort level be? Equilibrium will occur when D e( *) leads to effort level *e .

Define ∆MD =MD( )eHMD( ).eL This represents the gain in managerial

wealth from exerting the high effort level compared with the low effort level for a given D Therefore, for a given . D the manager exerts the high effort level iff ,

0.

D

M

∆ ≥ Substituting for i∈{ , }H L in (1), we find that the manager selects eH

iff

( )( ( *) ) ( ) ( ) 0

D H L H L H

M γ e e R D e F C e C e

(7)

The first term represents the expected marginal benefit from the manager’s higher effort. That is, higher effort increases the probability of the good state, represented by (γ eHeL). If the good state occurs, the manager receives payoff RHD e( *).

Furthermore, the manager avoids financial distress costs in the good state. We later identify that the avoidance of financial distress costs is a key difference between the manager’s effort incentives in the pure debt contract and the debt-equity contract. The second and third terms together represent the marginal cost of the higher effort level.

From (2), we obtain the market-determined face value of debt ,D given that the manager exerts effort level e*:

( *) * L L I R D e R e γ − = + . (5)

This represents the face value of debt for which the expected value of the debt con-tract equals I, given that the manager exerts effort level *.e That is, the debt holders invest at zero NPV.

We wish to examine the conditions under which the manager exerts the high or low effort level in equilibrium. We do this as follows. First, assume that the man-ager’s equilibrium effort level is e*=eH. Substituting into (5) and then substitut-ing into (4), we obtain condition c1:

( )( ) ( )( ) H L L ( ) ( ) ( ) 0 H L H L H L L H H e e I R e e R R e e F C e C e e γ − − − − − +γ − + − ≥ , (c1)

If condition c1 is satisfied, the debt holders set D e( )H in equilibrium, and the

manager exerts e*=eH in equilibrium. Hence, the manager’s effort incentives are

consistent with the face value of debt set by the market. If condition c1 is violated, then, if the market sets D e( ),H the manager will exert the low effort level. Hence,

the high effort level cannot be an equilibrium. Therefore, the market sets D e( )L ,

and the equilibrium effort level is e*=eL.

Next, consider the debt-equity contract. The respective expected payoffs for the manager, the debt and equity holders, and the total firm value at date 0 are:

( ) ( *) ( ) ( ) DE i i H L i M ee γe RRC e , (6) , (1 ( *)) ( ) D L E i H L S =R S = −α e γe RR , (7) D E S +S =I , (8) (1 ) DE i H i L Ve R + −γe R . (9)

We analyse these payoffs as follows. The debt holders hold a contract with face value of debt, D=RL; that is, debt is risk-free. In other words, the debt holders are guaranteed full payment. The manager and the equity holders share the firm’s equity (i.e., the value of the firm in excess of the value of debt RL). The manager issues a proportion (1−α( *))e to outside equity holders and retains a proportion α( *).e

(8)

Define ∆MDE =MDE( )eHMDE( ).eL This represents the gain in managerial

wealth from exerting the high effort level compared with the low effort level for a given .α Therefore, the manager selects eH iff

( *) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) 0

DE H L H L L H

M α e γ e e R R C e C e

∆ = − − + − ≥ , (10)

From (7) and (8), we obtain the market-determined α given that the man-*, ager exerts effort level e*:

( *) 1 *( ) L H L I R e e R R α γ − = − − , (11)

This represents the proportion of the equity that the manager can keep (issuing 1− ( *)e

α to outside equity holders), given that the market is expecting an effort level *,

e and values equity accordingly. The combined values of debt and equity then

equal I; that is, the debt holders and equity holders invest at zero NPV.

As before, we wish to examine the conditions under which the manager exerts the high or low effort level in equilibrium. Assume that the manager’s equilibrium effort level is e*=eH. Substituting into (11) and then substituting into (10), we obtain condition c2: ( )( ) ( )( ) H L L ( ) ( ) 0 H L H L L H H e e I R e e R R C e C e e γ − − − − − + − ≥ . (c2)

If condition c2 is satisfied, the market sets the share price such that the manager must issue 1−α( )eH and can only retain α( )eH for himself. Given this equity

allocation, the manager exerts e*=eH in equilibrium. Hence, the manager’s effort

incentives are consistent with the equity allocation set by the market. If condition c2 is violated, then, if the market allocates 1−α( )eH and α( ),eH the manager will

exert the low effort level. Hence, the high effort level cannot be an equilibrium. Therefore, the market allocates 1−α( )eL and α( ),eL and the equilibrium effort

level is e*=eL.

We note that condition c1 exceeds condition c2 by γ(eHe FL) . This repre-sents the expected reduction in financial distress costs from exerting the higher ef-fort level in the pure debt contract. Since there are no financial distress costs in the debt-equity contract, this term is absent from c2. Furthermore, if F = conditions 0, c1 and c2 are identical. The implication of this is that it is only the expected finan-cial distress costs that force the manager to exert the higher effort level. Since the investors (both the debt holders and equity holders) invest at zero NPV, the manager has identical effort incentives under the pure debt and debt-equity contracts in the absence of financial distress costs.

Lemma 1 compares the manager’s effort incentives in the pure debt and debt-equity contracts.

(9)

Lemma 1: The manager’s incentives to exert high effort in the pure debt and

debt-equity contracts are determined by the expected marginal benefits and marginal costs of high effort. Furthermore, in the pure debt contract, an additional incentive to exert high effort is provided by the existence of financial distress costs. This incen-tive is absent in the debt-equity contract. Therefore, we may state the following. (a) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +γ(eHe FL) +C e( )LC e( )H

0 and γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +C e( )LC e( ) 0H ≥ (that is,

conditions c1 and c2 hold), the marginal benefit from the higher effort level exceeds the marginal cost, and therefore the manager exerts the high effort level in both con-tracts.

(b) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +γ(eHe FL) +C e( )LC e( )H <

0 and γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +C e( )LC e( ) 0H < (conditions

c1 and c2 are violated), the marginal cost of exerting the higher effort level exceeds the marginal benefit, and the manager exerts the low effort level in both contracts. (c) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +γ(eHe FL) +C e( )LC e( )H

0 and γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +C e( )LC e( ) 0H < (condition

c1 holds, and c2 is violated), the marginal benefit from the higher effort level ex-ceeds the marginal cost in the pure debt contract, but the marginal cost of exerting the higher effort level exceeds the marginal benefit in the debt-equity contract. Therefore, the manager exerts the high effort level in the pure debt contract and the low effort level in the debt-equity contract. The difference in incentives is not caused by the equity stake (since investors invest at zero NPV) but by the financial distress costs.

In the special case where F= conditions c1 and c2 are identical. Therefore, 0, they both either hold or are violated. In other words, when F= we derive an 0, irrelevance result, where the manager exerts the same effort level in either contract. The intuition is that, although the manager has a higher equity stake in the pure debt contract, which has a positive effect on effort level, this is completely cancelled by the increase in the face value of debt, due to debt being risky, which has an offset-ting negative effect on effort incentives.

4. The Equilibrium Financial Contract

We now solve for the equilibrium financial contract. We compare two cases: (a) the investor selects the contract and (b) the manager selects the contract.

First, consider the case where the investor selects the contract. The investor aims to maximise firm value. By comparing (3) and (9), we note that, in order to maximise firm value, the investor selects the financial contract that maximises the manager’s effort level.

Next, consider the case where the manager selects the optimal contract. The manager is not concerned with firm value. He selects the contract that maximises his

(10)

expected personal wealth; that is, he compares (1) and (6). In order to make the comparisons, we substitute for D e( *) in (1) and for α( *)e in (6). These equations

become ( *) *( ) (1 *) ( *) D H L L M ee RR +R − − −I γe FC e , (12) ( *) *( ) ( * ) DE H L L i M ee RR +R − −I C e . (13)

At this point, it is instructive to re-write the firm value equation (3) or (9) as *( H L) L.

Ve RR +R Hence, we note that, in both contracts, the manager has all

of the equity in excess of I. This is because the investors provide finance at zero NPV; that is, in both contracts, the total value of the investors’ contract is I. The manager has the positive NPV.

Recall that we are dealing with a moral hazard problem, whereby investors provide finance up front, and the manager then exerts his effort level. Hence, there is a commitment problem. In comparing (12) and (13), the manager recognises that his choice of financial contract affects the market’s expectation of his effort level, which ultimately affects the manager’s NPV and wealth.

We will be examining the manager’s use of the pure debt contract to commit to a higher effort level. We note that, if the manager exerts the same effort level in both contracts (either high or low), then (13) > (12) due to the presence of the financial distress costs in (12). That is, he strictly prefers the debt-equity contract. If the man-ager exerts the high effort level under the pure debt contract and the low effort level under the debt-equity contract, he is then comparing

( ) ( ) (1 ) ( ) D H H H L L H H M ee RR +R − − −I γe FC e , (14) ( ) ( ) ( ) DE L L H L L L M ee RR +R − −I C e . (15)

Lemma 2 compares the manager’s and the investor’s optimal contracts.

Lemma 2: The investor prefers the contract that maximises firm value. The manager

prefers the contract that maximises his personal payoff.

If the choice of financial contract does not affect the manager’s effort level (and hence does not affect firm value), then investors are indifferent between the con-tracts. The manager unambiguously prefers the debt-equity contract due to the ex-pected financial distress costs from the pure debt contract.

If the choice of financial contract affects the effort level, then investors unam-biguously prefer the pure debt contract, since financial distress costs force higher managerial effort. The manager’s choice of contract depends on the marginal effect on his wealth (including the expected financial distress costs in the pure debt con-tract). Therefore, we conclude the following.

(a) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +γ(eHe FL) +C e( )LC e( )H

0 and γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +C e( )LC e( ) 0H ≥ (conditions

c1 and c2 both hold), or γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +

(eH e FL) C e( )L C e( )H

(11)

( )L ( ) 0H

C eC e < (conditions c1 and c2 are both violated), the choice of financial

contract does not affect the manager’s effort level (from Lemma 1). Therefore, the investor is indifferent between the debt and debt-equity contracts. The manager pre-fers the debt-equity contract.

(b) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +γ(eHe FL) +C e( )LC e( )H

0 and γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +C e( )LC e( ) 0H < (c1 holds

and c2 is violated), the investor prefers the pure debt contract (since this induces higher managerial effort and higher firm value).

The manager is aligned with the investors in preferring the (value-maximising) pure debt contract if MD( )eHMDE( ).eL In contrast, the manager is in conflict

with the investors, preferring the (value-minimising) debt-equity contract, if

( ) ( ).

DE L D H

M e >M e

We obtain our irrelevance result in the special case where F= In this case, 0. c1 and c2 both hold or are both violated. Therefore, the manager exerts the same effort level in either contract. Hence, the investors are indifferent between the two contracts. Also, since F = and the manager’s effort level is unaffected, examina-0 tion of (14) and (15) reveals that the manager is also indifferent between the two contracts.

Note that, for ease of modelling, we have assumed only two discrete manage-rial effort levels (high or low). Therefore, under certain conditions (as described in Lemma 2a), the financial contract does not affect the manager’s effort levels or firm value. Hence, investors are indifferent between the two contracts, and the manager prefers the debt-equity contract (due to the financial distress costs).

In a more complex model, we would assume a continuous distribution of possi-ble effort levels. In such a model, we would expect the financial contract to affect the manager’s effort level, with the pure debt contract forcing a high effort level.

Lemma 2b demonstrates the conditions under which we obtain precisely this result in our discrete effort level case. The financial contract does affect the manag-ers’ effort level. The manager exerts the low effort level under the debt-equity con-tract and the high effort level under the pure debt concon-tract. Now, the investors un-ambiguously prefer the pure debt contract.

The manager may be aligned or in conflict with the investors in the choice of financial contract. The manager will have an incentive to issue the pure debt contract to commit to a higher effort level. However, he will compare this incentive with the marginal cost of effort and the expected financial distress costs from using the pure debt contract.

For the remainder of this paper, we focus on Lemma 2b. That is, we focus on a case where c1 holds and c2 is violated, so that the debt contract has a role to play in forcing the higher effort level.

(12)

5. Equilibrium Financial Contracts When the Pure Debt Contract Forces Higher Managerial Effort

The manager is aligned with investors in selecting the pure debt contract iff

( ) ( )

D H DE L

M eM e ; that is, iff

(eH eL)(RH RL) (1 eH)F C e( )L C e( ) 0H

γ − − − −γ + − ≥ . (c3)

The first term of condition c3 represents the expected gain in the manager’s wealth from higher effort level due to the increased probability of the good state. The sec-ond term represents the expected financial distress costs from the pure debt contract. The last two terms represent the marginal cost of the higher effort level under the pure debt contract. Hence, the manager has an incentive to issue the pure debt con-tract in order to commit to a higher effort level (the first term), but this incentive may be reduced by the expected financial distress costs and the increased cost of effort.

Proposition 1 draws the analysis together to provide our main result.

Proposition 1: When the pure debt contract forces a higher managerial effort level

than the debt-equity contract, investors unambiguously prefer the pure debt contract. The manager’s choice of contract depends on the marginal effect on his wealth. By choosing the pure debt contract, he commits to a higher effort level, which has a positive effect on his wealth (since investors provide finance at zero NPV and the manager gains all of the positive NPV). However, he also faces the negative effects of expected financial distress costs. Hence, if both

(eH eL)(RH RL) (eH eL)(I RL) /eH (eH e FL) C e( )L C e( )H

γ − − − − − +γ − + − ≥ 0 and

(eH eL)(RH RL) (eH eL)(I RL) /eH C e( )L C e( ) 0H

γ − − − − − + − < (c1 holds and c2 is

violated), the manager exerts higher effort under the pure debt contract. This is purely due to the threat of financial distress costs. Therefore, we conclude as fol-lows.

(i) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (1− −γeH)F+C e( )LC e( ) 0,H ≥ the manager is aligned

with the investors in preferring the pure debt contract.

(ii) If γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (1− −γeH)F+C e( )LC e( ) 0,H < the manager is in

con-flict with the investors, preferring the debt-equity contract.

Therefore, the investor strictly prefers the pure debt contract, since this will in-duce the high effort level (due to the financial distress threat). We note that the manager is aligned with the investor in preferring the value-maximising pure debt contract if his wealth gain from committing to the higher effort level exceeds the higher cost of effort and the expected financial distress costs from issuing pure debt.

On the other hand, the manager is in conflict with the investor if the expected financial distress costs from issuing pure debt, plus the higher cost of effort, exceed his wealth gain from committing to the higher effort level.

In the next section, we consider a numerical example to illustrate the possible conflict in choice of financial contract and the effect on firm value.

(13)

6. Numerical Example

We assign the following parameter values: 1600,

H

R = RL =200, I=400, eH =0.7, eL =0.2, γ = 1, F∈{300,500},

( ) 600,H

C e = C e( ) 0.L =

Note that we have assigned two possible values for financial distress costs in order to analyse the effect on the manager’s choice of financial contract.

First, consider the case where F=300. Substituting the parameters into c1, we obtain γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (− eHeL)(IRL) /eH +γ(eHe FL) +C e( )L

( ) 108H

C e = ≥ 0. Furthermore, substituting the parameters into c2, we obtain

(eH eL)(RH RL) (eH eL)(I RL) /eH C e( )L C e( )H 42 0.

γ − − − − − + − = − < Therefore, c1

holds and c2 is violated. As described in Proposition 1, the manager exerts the high effort level in the pure debt contract and the low effort level in the debt-equity con-tract. Hence, the investors prefer the (value-maximising) pure debt concon-tract.

Now, substitute the parameters into c3 in order to determine the manager’s op-timal contract. We obtain γ(eHeL)(RHRL) (1− −γeH)F+C e( )LC e( )H =

10 0.≥ Therefore, Proposition 1(i) applies; the manager is aligned with the inves-tors in preferring the pure debt contract. The intuition is that the manager’s financial gain from committing to the high effort level exceeds the higher cost of effort and the expected financial distress costs.

Next, consider the case where F=500. Condition c1 becomes

(eH eL)(RH RL) (eH eL)(I RL) /eH (eH e FL) C e( )L C e( ) 208 0.H

γ − − − − − +γ − + − = ≥

Condition c2 remains as

(eH eL)(RH RL) (eH eL)(I RL) /eH C e( )L C e( )H 42 0.

γ − − − − − + − = − <

Therefore, c1 still holds, and c2 is still violated. The manager continues to exert the high effort level in the pure debt contract and the low effort level in the debt-equity contract, and the investors continue to prefer the pure debt contract.

Condition c3 becomes

(eH eL)(RH RL) (1 eH)F C e( )L C e( )H 50 0.

γ − − − −γ + − = − <

Since condition c3 is now negative, Proposition 1(ii) now applies. In contrast to the investors, the manager prefers the debt-equity contract. The intuition is that, al-though the pure debt contract commits the manager to a higher effort level, thus in-creasing the manager’s NPV, this gain is less than the financial distress costs and the higher cost of effort from the pure debt contract.

(14)

7. Conclusion

We have developed a principal-agent model of financial contracting that con-siders two effects of debt on a manager’s effort incentives. First, following Jensen and Meckling (1976), a high debt level increases the manager’s equity stake, whereas a low debt level dilutes the manager’s equity stake. Second, the threat of financial distress increases with the high debt level.

In the absence of financial distress costs, we derive a novel irrelevance result; the financial contract does not affect managerial effort or firm value. This is because, for high debt levels, the manager has a greater equity stake, but this is exactly offset by the increase in the face value of risky debt. In the presence of financial distress costs, a high debt level forces an increase in managerial effort, as the manager seeks to avoid these costs. Hence, investors unambiguously prefer the high debt contract. The manager’s optimal contract depends on the level of financial distress and effort costs. If these are low, he is aligned with investors in preferring the pure debt con-tract. If these are high, he prefers the low debt concon-tract.

Our model provides a basis for future research as follows.

(a) For simplicity, we only considered two types of financial contract; first, a pure debt contract (in which debt is risky), and second, a debt-equity contract, where debt is risk-free. Furthermore, we only considered two possible effort levels, high or low. It would be interesting to develop the model to include a continuum of effort levels and debt levels.

(b) Our model provides a basis for empirical testing. A promising approach would be to develop Garvey and Hanka’s (1997) takeover model. In their model, a manager uses the capital structure as a defensive mechanism against a hostile takeover threat. The manager holds no equity in the firm and merely is interested in keeping his job. When takeover threats are weak, he sets low debt levels in order to avoid financial distress. When takeover threats are strong, he sets high debt levels in order to in-crease firm value and therefore reduce the takeover threat. Hence, there are large swings in leverage relating to takeover cycles. Our model suggests that if we include the manager’s equity stake in Garvey and Hanka’s (1997) model, then these swings in leverage may be mitigated. If financial distress costs are low, the manager always carries high debt levels. If financial distress costs are high, then the swings in lever-age will be larger.

(c) In our model, the manager suffers from financial distress costs to a greater extent than the investors (since he has his human capital and reputation tied up in the firm). Therefore, he naturally favors a lower debt level. An extremely interesting area of research examines the behavioral aspects of corporate finance (e.g., Besharov, 2002; Gervais, Heaton, and Odean, 2003; Heaton, 2002; Mattson and Weibull, 2002; She-frin, 1999; and Stein, 1996). One extensively researched aspect is that of overconfi-dence. Heaton (2002) argues that agents, such as managers, are more optimistic about outcomes that they believe they can control. Shefrin (1999) argues that

(15)

“over-confident executives may underestimate the probability of default, and as a result choose an overly debt-heavy capital structure.” Furthermore, Besharov (2002) de-velops a framework in which an irrational individual suffers from positive and nega-tive biases. It is then possible that these biases cancel each other, such that the agent makes an optimal decision overall. It would be possible to develop our model to consider a trade-off between the manager’s rational aversion to financial distress (favoring a low debt level) and his irrational overconfidence (favoring a high debt level). Applying the Besharov (2002) framework, we could then examine when these opposing biases result in the optimal (value-maximising) debt level from the investors’ point of view.

(d) Furthermore, we should consider the impact of asymmetric information and sig-nalling in our model (see Ross, 1977; Leland and Pyle, 1977; and Myers and Majluf, 1984, for pioneering signalling models of the capital structure).

References

Aghion, P. and P. Bolton, (1992), “An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting,” Review of Economic Studies, 59, 473-494.

Berkovitch, E. and R. Israel, (1996), “The Design of Internal Control and Capital Structure,” Review of Financial Studies, 9, 209-240.

Berkovitch, E., R. Israel, and Y. Spiegel, (2000), “Managerial Compensation and Capital Structure,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 9, 549-584.

Besharov, G., (2002), “Second-Best Considerations in Correcting Cognitive Biases,” Mimeo.

Dewatripont, M. and J. Tirole, (1994), “A Theory of Debt and Equity: Diversity of Securities and Manager-Shareholder Congruence,” Quarterly Journal of Eco-nomics, 1027-1053.

Garvey, G. and G. Hanka, (1997), “The Management of Corporate Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence,” Mimeo, SSRN database.

Gervais, S., J. Heaton, and T. Odean, (2003), “Overconfidence, Investment Policy, and Executive Stock Options,” Mimeo.

Grossman, S., and O. Hart, (1982), “Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives,” in The Economics of Uncertainty, E. Lippman and J. McCall eds., Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Harris, M. and A. Raviv, (1991), “The Theory of Capital Structure,” The Journal of Finance.

Heaton, J., (2002), “Managerial Optimism and Corporate Finance,” Financial Man-agement, 33-45.

Jensen, M., (1986), “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance and Take-overs,” American Economic Review, 76, 323-339.

Jensen, M. and W. Meckling, (1976), “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Capital Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360.

(16)

Jong, A. and C. Veld, (2002), “An Empirical Analysis of Incremental Capital Struc-ture decisions Under Managerial Entrenchment,” Mimeo.

Leland, H. and D. Pyle, (1977), “Information Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation,” Journal of Finance, 32, 371-388.

Mattson, L. and J. Weibull, (2002), “Probabilistic Choice and Procedurally Bounded Rationality,” Games and Economic Behavior, 41, 61-78.

Modigliani, F. and M. Miller, (1958), “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment,” American Economic Review, 48, 261-297.

Myers, S. and N. Majluf, (1984), “Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions when Firms Have Information that Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Finan-cial Economics, 13, 187-221.

Ross, S., (1977), “The Determinants of Financial Structure: The Incentive Signalling Approach.” Bell Journal of Economics, 8, 23-40.

Shefrin, H., (1999), “Behavioral Corporate Finance,” Mimeo.

Statman, M. and D. Caldwell, (1987), “Applying Behavioral Finance to Capital Budgeting: Project Terminations,” Financial Management, 7-15.

Stein, J., (1996) “Rational Capital Budgeting in an Irrational World,” Journal of Business, 69(4), 429-455.

參考文獻

相關文件

Let f being a Morse function on a smooth compact manifold M (In his paper, the result can be generalized to non-compact cases in certain ways, but we assume the compactness

To stimulate creativity, smart learning, critical thinking and logical reasoning in students, drama and arts play a pivotal role in the..

 Promote project learning, mathematical modeling, and problem-based learning to strengthen the ability to integrate and apply knowledge and skills, and make. calculated

The measurement basis used in the preparation of the financial statements is historical cost except that equity and debt securities managed by the Fund’s

The measurement basis used in the preparation of the financial statements is historical cost except that equity and debt securities managed by the Fund’s

Wang, Solving pseudomonotone variational inequalities and pseudocon- vex optimization problems using the projection neural network, IEEE Transactions on Neural Networks 17

Define instead the imaginary.. potential, magnetic field, lattice…) Dirac-BdG Hamiltonian:. with small, and matrix

* School Survey 2017.. 1) Separate examination papers for the compulsory part of the two strands, with common questions set in Papers 1A &amp; 1B for the common topics in