• 沒有找到結果。

Intrinsic Value

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "Intrinsic Value"

Copied!
67
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Put-Call Parity (Castelli, 1877)

C = P + S − PV(X). (19)

• Consider the portfolio of one short European call, one long European put, one share of stock, and a loan of PV(X).

• All options are assumed to carry the same strike price and time to expiration, τ .

• The initial cash flow is therefore

C − P − S + PV(X).

(2)

The Proof (continued)

• At expiration, if the stock price Sτ ≤ X, the put will be worth X − Sτ and the call will expire worthless.

• After the loan, now X, is repaid, the net future cash flow is zero:

0 + (X − Sτ) + Sτ − X = 0.

• On the other hand, if Sτ > X, the call will be worth Sτ − X and the put will expire worthless.

• After the loan, now X, is repaid, the net future cash flow is again zero:

(3)

The Proof (concluded)

• The net future cash flow is zero in either case.

• The no-arbitrage principle implies that the initial

investment to set up the portfolio must be nil as well.

(4)

Consequences of Put-Call Parity

• There is only one kind of European option because the other can be replicated from it in combination with the underlying stock and riskless lending or borrowing.

– Combinations such as this create synthetic securities.

• S = C − P + PV(X) says a stock is equivalent to a

portfolio containing a long call, a short put, and lending PV(X).

• C − P = S − PV(X) implies a long call and a short put amount to a long position in stock and borrowing the PV of the strike price (buying stock on margin).

(5)

Intrinsic Value

Lemma 1 An American call or a European call on a non-dividend-paying stock is never worth less than its intrinsic value.

• The put-call parity implies

C = (S − X) + (X − PV(X)) + P ≥ S − X.

• Recall C ≥ 0.

• It follows that C ≥ max(S − X, 0), the intrinsic value.

• An American call also cannot be worth less than its intrinsic value.

(6)

Intrinsic Value (concluded)

A European put on a non-dividend-paying stock may be worth less than its intrinsic value (p. 161).

Lemma 2 For European puts, P ≥ max(PV(X) − S, 0).

• Prove it with the put-call parity.

• Can explain the right figure on p. 161 why P < X − S when S is small.

(7)

Early Exercise of American Calls

European calls and American calls are identical when the underlying stock pays no dividends.

Theorem 3 (Merton (1973)) An American call on a non-dividend-paying stock should not be exercised before expiration.

• By an exercise in text, C ≥ max(S − PV(X), 0).

• If the call is exercised, the value is the smaller S − X.

(8)

Remarks

• The above theorem does not mean American calls should be kept until maturity.

• What it does imply is that when early exercise is being considered, a better alternative is to sell it.

• Early exercise may become optimal for American calls on a dividend-paying stock.

– Stock price declines as the stock goes ex-dividend.

(9)

Early Exercise of American Calls: Dividend Case

Surprisingly, an American call should be exercised only at a few dates.

Theorem 4 An American call will only be exercised at expiration or just before an ex-dividend date.

In contrast, it might be optimal to exercise an American put even if the underlying stock does not pay dividends.

(10)

Convexity of Option Prices

Lemma 5 For three otherwise identical calls or puts with strike prices X1 < X2 < X3,

CX2 ≤ ωCX1 + (1 − ω) CX3 PX2 ≤ ωPX1 + (1 − ω) PX3 Here

ω ≡ (X3 − X2)/(X3 − X1).

(Equivalently, X2 = ωX1 + (1 − ω) X3.)

(11)

The Intuition behind Lemma 5

a

• Consider ωCX1 + (1 − ω) CX3 − CX2.

• This is a butterfly spread (p. 171).

• It has a nonnegative value as

ω max(S−X1, 0)+(1−ω) max(S−X3, 0)−max(S−X2, 0) ≥ 0.

• Therefore, ωCX1 + (1 − ω) CX3 − CX2 ≥ 0.

• In the limit, ∂2C/∂X2 ≥ 0.

aContributed by Mr. Cheng, Jen-Chieh (B96703032) on March 17, 2010.

(12)

Option on Portfolio vs. Portfolio of Options

An option on a portfolio of stocks is cheaper than a portfolio of options.

Theorem 6 Consider a portfolio of non-dividend-paying assets with weights ωi. Let Ci denote the price of a

European call on asset i with strike price Xi. Then the call on the portfolio with a strike price X ≡ P

i ωiXi has a value at most P

i ωiCi. All options expire on the same date.

The same result holds for European puts.

(13)

Option Pricing Models

(14)

If the world of sense does not fit mathematics, so much the worse for the world of sense.

— Bertrand Russell (1872–1970) Black insisted that anything one could do with a mouse could be done better with macro redefinitions of particular keys on the keyboard.

— Emanuel Derman, My Life as a Quant (2004)

(15)

The Setting

• The no-arbitrage principle is insufficient to pin down the exact option value.

• Need a model of probabilistic behavior of stock prices.

• One major obstacle is that it seems a risk-adjusted interest rate is needed to discount the option’s payoff.

• Breakthrough came in 1973 when Black (1938–1995) and Scholes with help from Merton published their celebrated option pricing model.

– Known as the Black-Scholes option pricing model.

(16)

Terms and Approach

• C: call value.

• P : put value.

• X: strike price

• S: stock price

• ˆr > 0: the continuously compounded riskless rate per period.

• R ≡ erˆ: gross return.

• Start from the discrete-time binomial model.

(17)

Binomial Option Pricing Model (BOPM)

• Time is discrete and measured in periods.

• If the current stock price is S, it can go to Su with probability q and Sd with probability 1 − q, where 0 < q < 1 and d < u.

– In fact, d < R < u must hold to rule out arbitrage.

• Six pieces of information suffice to determine the option value based on arbitrage considerations: S, u, d, X, ˆr, and the number of periods to expiration.

(18)

S

Su q

1 q

Sd

(19)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period

• The expiration date is only one period from now.

• Cu is the call price at time one if the stock price moves to Su.

• Cd is the call price at time one if the stock price moves to Sd.

• Clearly,

Cu = max(0, Su − X), Cd = max(0, Sd − X).

(20)

C

Cu= max( 0, Su X ) q

1 q

Cd = max( 0, Sd X )

(21)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period (continued)

• Set up a portfolio of h shares of stock and B dollars in riskless bonds.

– This costs hS + B.

– We call h the hedge ratio or delta.

• The value of this portfolio at time one is either hSu + RB or hSd + RB.

• Choose h and B such that the portfolio replicates the payoff of the call,

hSu + RB = Cu, hSd + RB = Cd.

(22)

Call on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Single Period (concluded)

• Solve the above equations to obtain h = Cu − Cd

Su − Sd ≥ 0, (20)

B = uCd − dCu

(u − d) R . (21)

• By the no-arbitrage principle, the European call should cost the same as the equivalent portfolio, C = hS + B.

• As uCd − dCu < 0, the equivalent portfolio is a levered long position in stocks.

(23)

American Call Pricing in One Period

• Have to consider immediate exercise.

• C = max(hS + B, S − X).

– When hS + B ≥ S − X, the call should not be exercised immediately.

– When hS + B < S − X, the option should be exercised immediately.

• For non-dividend-paying stocks, early exercise is not optimal by Theorem 3 (p. 191).

• So C = hS + B.

(24)

Put Pricing in One Period

• Puts can be similarly priced.

• The delta for the put is (Pu − Pd)/(Su − Sd) ≤ 0, where Pu = max(0, X − Su),

Pd = max(0, X − Sd).

• Let B = uP(u−d) Rd−dPu.

• The European put is worth hS + B.

• The American put is worth max(hS + B, X − S).

– Early exercise is always possible with American puts.

(25)

Risk

• Surprisingly, the option value is independent of q.

• Hence it is independent of the expected gross return of the stock, qSu + (1 − q) Sd.

• It therefore does not directly depend on investors’ risk preferences.

• The option value depends on the sizes of price changes, u and d, which the investors must agree upon.

• Note that the set of possible stock prices is the same whatever q is.

(26)

Can You Figure Out u, d without Knowing q?

a

• Yes, you can under BOPM.

• Let us observe the time series of past stock prices, e.g.,

u is available

z }| {

S, Su, Su2, Su3, Su3d

| {z }

d is available

, . . .

• So with sufficiently long history, you will figure out u and d without knowing q.

aContributed by Mr. Hsu, Jia-Shuo (D97945003) on March 11, 2009.

(27)

Pseudo Probability

• After substitution and rearrangement,

hS + B =

³R−d u−d

´

Cu +

³u−R u−d

´ Cd

R .

• Rewrite it as

hS + B = pCu + (1 − p) Cd

R ,

where

p ≡ R − d u − d .

• As 0 < p < 1, it may be interpreted as a probability.

(28)

Risk-Neutral Probability

• The expected rate of return for the stock is equal to the riskless rate ˆr under p as pSu + (1 − p) Sd = RS.

• The expected rates of return of all securities must be the riskless rate when investors are risk-neutral.

• For this reason, p is called the risk-neutral probability.

• The value of an option is the expectation of its

discounted future payoff in a risk-neutral economy.

• So the rate used for discounting the FV is the riskless rate in a risk-neutral economy.

(29)

Binomial Distribution

• Denote the binomial distribution with parameters n and p by

b(j; n, p) ≡

µn j

pj(1 − p)n−j = n!

j! (n − j)! pj(1 − p)n−j. – n! = n × (n − 1) · · · 2 × 1 with the convention 0! = 1.

• Suppose you toss a coin n times with p being the probability of getting heads.

• Then b(j; n, p) is the probability of getting j heads.

(30)

Option on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Multi-Period

• Consider a call with two periods remaining before expiration.

• Under the binomial model, the stock can take on three possible prices at time two: Suu, Sud, and Sdd.

– There are 4 paths.

– But the tree combines.

• At any node, the next two stock prices only depend on the current price, not the prices of earlier times.

(31)

S

Su

Sd

Suu

Sud

Sdd

(32)

Option on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Multi-Period (continued)

• Let Cuu be the call’s value at time two if the stock price is Suu.

• Thus,

Cuu = max(0, Suu − X).

• Cud and Cdd can be calculated analogously, Cud = max(0, Sud − X),

Cdd = max(0, Sdd − X).

(33)

C

Cu

Cd

Cuu= max( 0, Suu X )

Cud = max( 0, Sud X )

Cdd = max( 0, Sdd X )

(34)

Option on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Multi-Period (continued)

• The call values at time one can be obtained by applying the same logic:

Cu = pCuu + (1 − p) Cud

R , (22)

Cd = pCud + (1 − p) Cdd

R .

• Deltas can be derived from Eq. (20) on p. 206.

• For example, the delta at Cu is Cuu − Cud

.

(35)

Option on a Non-Dividend-Paying Stock: Multi-Period (concluded)

• We now reach the current period.

• An equivalent portfolio of h shares of stock and $B riskless bonds can be set up for the call that costs Cu (Cd, resp.) if the stock price goes to Su (Sd, resp.).

• The values of h and B can be derived from Eqs. (20)–(21) on p. 206.

• That is, compute

pCu + (1 − p) Cd R

as the price.

(36)

Early Exercise

• Since the call will not be exercised at time one even if it is American, Cu ≥ Su − X and Cd ≥ Sd − X.

• Therefore,

hS + B = pCu + (1 − p) Cd

R [ pu + (1 − p) d ] S − X R

= S − X

R > S − X.

– The call again will not be exercised at present.a

• So

C = hS + B = pCu + (1 − p) Cd

R .

(37)

Backward Induction of Zermelo (1871–1953)

• The above expression calculates C from the two successor nodes Cu and Cd and none beyond.

• The same computation happened at Cu and Cd, too, as demonstrated in Eq. (22) on p. 218.

• This recursive procedure is called backward induction.

• Now, C equals

[ p2Cuu + 2p(1 − p) Cud + (1 − p)2Cdd](1/R2)

= [ p2 max¡

0, Su2 − X¢

+ 2p(1 − p) max (0, Sud − X) +(1 − p)2 max¡

0, Sd2 − X¢

]/R2.

(38)

S0 1

*

j

S0u p

*

j

S0d 1 − p

*

j

S0u2 p2

S0ud

2p(1 − p)

S0d2

(39)

Backward Induction (concluded)

• In the n-period case, C =

Pn

j=0

¡n

j

¢pj(1 − p)n−j × max¡

0, Sujdn−j − X¢

Rn .

– The value of a call on a non-dividend-paying stock is the expected discounted payoff at expiration in a

risk-neutral economy.

• The value of a European put is P =

Pn

j=0

¡n

j

¢pj(1 − p)n−j × max¡

0, X − Sujdn−j¢

Rn .

(40)

Risk-Neutral Pricing Methodology

• Every derivative can be priced as if the economy were risk-neutral.

• For a European-style derivative with the terminal payoff function D, its value is

e−ˆrnEπ[ D ].

– Eπ means the expectation is taken under the risk-neutral probability.

• The “equivalence” between arbitrage freedom in a model and the existence of a risk-neutral probability is called

(41)

Self-Financing

• Delta changes over time.

• The maintenance of an equivalent portfolio is dynamic.

• The maintaining of an equivalent portfolio does not depend on our correctly predicting future stock prices.

• The portfolio’s value at the end of the current period is precisely the amount needed to set up the next portfolio.

• The trading strategy is self-financing because there is neither injection nor withdrawal of funds throughout.

– Changes in value are due entirely to capital gains.

(42)

The Binomial Option Pricing Formula

• The stock prices at time n are

Sun, Sun−1d, . . . , Sdn.

• Let a be the minimum number of upward price moves for the call to finish in the money.

• So a is the smallest nonnegative integer such that Suadn−a ≥ X,

or, equivalently,

a =

»ln(X/Sdn.

(43)

The Binomial Option Pricing Formula (concluded)

• Hence,

C

=

Pn

j=a

¡n

j

¢pj(1 − p)n−j ¡

Sujdn−j − X¢

Rn (23)

= S

Xn j=a

µn j

(pu)j[ (1 − p) d ]n−j Rn

X Rn

Xn j=a

µn j

pj(1 − p)n−j

= S

Xn j=a

b (j; n, pu/R) − Xe−ˆrn

Xn j=a

b(j; n, p).

(44)

Numerical Examples

• A non-dividend-paying stock is selling for $160.

• u = 1.5 and d = 0.5.

• r = 18.232% per period (R = e0.18232 = 1.2).

– Hence p = (R − d)/(u − d) = 0.7.

• Consider a European call on this stock with X = 150 and n = 3.

• The call value is $85.069 by backward induction.

• Or, the PV of the expected payoff at expiration:

390 × 0.343 + 30 × 0.441 + 0 × 0.189 + 0 × 0.027

(1.2)3 = 85.069.

(45)

160

540 (0.343)

180 (0.441)

60 (0.189)

20 (0.027) Binomial process for the stock price

(probabilities in parentheses)

360 (0.49)

120 (0.42)

40 (0.09) 240

(0.7)

80 (0.3)

85.069 (0.82031)

390

30

0

0 Binomial process for the call price

(hedge ratios in parentheses)

235 (1.0)

17.5 (0.25)

0 (0.0) 141.458

(0.90625)

10.208 (0.21875)

(46)

Numerical Examples (continued)

• Mispricing leads to arbitrage profits.

• Suppose the option is selling for $90 instead.

• Sell the call for $90 and invest $85.069 in the replicating portfolio with 0.82031 shares of stock required by delta.

• Borrow 0.82031 × 160 − 85.069 = 46.1806 dollars.

• The fund that remains,

90 − 85.069 = 4.931 dollars, is the arbitrage profit as we will see.

(47)

Numerical Examples (continued)

Time 1:

• Suppose the stock price moves to $240.

• The new delta is 0.90625.

• Buy

0.90625 − 0.82031 = 0.08594

more shares at the cost of 0.08594 × 240 = 20.6256 dollars financed by borrowing.

• Debt now totals 20.6256 + 46.1806 × 1.2 = 76.04232 dollars.

(48)

Numerical Examples (continued)

Time 2:

• Suppose the stock price plunges to $120.

• The new delta is 0.25.

• Sell 0.90625 − 0.25 = 0.65625 shares.

• This generates an income of 0.65625 × 120 = 78.75 dollars.

• Use this income to reduce the debt to

76.04232 × 1.2 − 78.75 = 12.5

(49)

Numerical Examples (continued)

Time 3 (the case of rising price):

• The stock price moves to $180.

• The call we wrote finishes in the money.

• For a loss of 180 − 150 = 30 dollars, close out the

position by either buying back the call or buying a share of stock for delivery.

• Financing this loss with borrowing brings the total debt to 12.5 × 1.2 + 30 = 45 dollars.

• It is repaid by selling the 0.25 shares of stock for 0.25 × 180 = 45 dollars.

(50)

Numerical Examples (concluded)

Time 3 (the case of declining price):

• The stock price moves to $60.

• The call we wrote is worthless.

• Sell the 0.25 shares of stock for a total of 0.25 × 60 = 15

dollars.

• Use it to repay the debt of 12.5 × 1.2 = 15 dollars.

(51)

Binomial Tree Algorithms for European Options

• The BOPM implies the binomial tree algorithm that applies backward induction.

• The total running time is O(n2).

• The memory requirement is O(n2).

– Can be further reduced to O(n) by reusing space

• To price European puts, simply replace the payoff.

(52)

C[2][0]

C[2][1]

C[2][2]

C[1][0]

C[1][1]

C[0][0]

p

p

p p

p p

max

c

0,Sud2 X

h

max

c

0,Su d2 X

h

max

c

0,Su3 X

h

max

c

0,Sd3 X

h

1 p

1 p

1 p

1 p

1 p

1 p

(53)

Further Improvement for Calls

0

0 0

All zeros

X

(54)

Optimal Algorithm

• We can reduce the running time to O(n) and the memory requirement to O(1).

• Note that

b(j; n, p) = p(n − j + 1)

(1 − p) j b(j − 1; n, p).

(55)

Optimal Algorithm (continued)

• The following program computes b(j; n, p) in b[ j ]:

1: b[ a ] := ¡n

a

¢ pa(1 − p)n−a;

2: for j = a + 1, a + 2, . . . , n do

3: b[ j ] := b[ j − 1 ] × p × (n − j + 1)/((1 − p) × j);

4: end for

• It runs in O(n) steps.

(56)

Optimal Algorithm (concluded)

• With the b(j; n, p) available, the risk-neutral valuation formula (23) on p. 227 is trivial to compute.

• We only need a single variable to store the b(j; n, p)s as they are being sequentially computed.

• This linear-time algorithm computes the discounted expected value of max(Sn − X, 0).

• The above technique cannot be applied to American options because of early exercise.

• So binomial tree algorithms for American options

2

(57)

On the Bushy Tree

S

Su

Sd

Su2

Sud

Sdu

Sd2

2n

n

Sun Sun 1 Su3

Su2d Su2d

Sud2 Su2d

Sud2 Sud2

Sd3

Sun 1d

(58)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula

• The binomial model seems to suffer from two unrealistic assumptions.

– The stock price takes on only two values in a period.

– Trading occurs at discrete points in time.

• As n increases, the stock price ranges over ever larger numbers of possible values, and trading takes place nearly continuously.

• Any proper calibration of the model parameters makes the BOPM converge to the continuous-time model.

• We now skim through the proof.

(59)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• Let τ denote the time to expiration of the option measured in years.

• Let r be the continuously compounded annual rate.

• With n periods during the option’s life, each period represents a time interval of τ /n.

• Need to adjust the period-based u, d, and interest rate ˆ

r to match the empirical results as n goes to infinity.

• First, ˆr = rτ /n.

– The period gross return R = erˆ.

(60)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• Use b

µ ≡ 1 n E

·

ln Sτ S

¸

and bσ2 1

n Var

·

ln Sτ S

¸

to denote, resp., the expected value and variance of the continuously compounded rate of return per period.

• Under the BOPM, it is not hard to show that b

µ = q ln(u/d) + ln d, b

σ2 = q(1 − q) ln2(u/d).

(61)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• Assume the stock’s true continuously compounded rate of return over τ years has mean µτ and variance σ2τ .

– Call σ the stock’s (annualized) volatility.

• The BOPM converges to the distribution only if nbµ = n(q ln(u/d) + ln d) → µτ, nbσ2 = nq(1 − q) ln2(u/d) → σ2τ.

• Impose ud = 1 to make nodes at the same horizontal level of the tree have identical price (review p. 237).

– Other choices are possible (see text).

(62)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• The above requirements can be satisfied by u = eσ

τ /n, d = e−σ

τ /n, q = 1

2 + 1 2

µ σ

rτ

n . (24)

• With Eqs. (24),

nbµ = µτ, nbσ2 =

·

1 − ³ µ σ

´2 τ n

¸

σ2τ → σ2τ.

(63)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• The no-arbitrage inequalities d < R < u may not hold under Eqs. (24) on p. 246.

– If this happens, the risk-neutral probability may lie outside [ 0, 1 ].a

• The problem disappears when n satisfies eσ

τ /n > erτ /n,

or when n > r2τ /σ2 (check it).

– So it goes away if n is large enough.

– Other solutions will be presented later.

aMany papers forget to check this!

(64)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• What is the limiting probabilistic distribution of the continuously compounded rate of return ln(Sτ/S)?

• The central limit theorem says ln(Sτ/S) converges to the normal distribution with mean µτ and variance σ2τ .

• So ln Sτ approaches the normal distribution with mean µτ + ln S and variance σ2τ .

• Sτ has a lognormal distribution in the limit.

(65)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

Lemma 7 The continuously compounded rate of return ln(Sτ/S) approaches the normal distribution with mean (r − σ2/2) τ and variance σ2τ in a risk-neutral economy.

• Let q equal the risk-neutral probability p ≡ (erτ /n − d)/(u − d).

• Let n → ∞.

(66)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (continued)

• By Lemma 7 (p. 249) and Eq. (18) on p. 151, the expected stock price at expiration in a risk-neutral economy is Se.

• The stock’s expected annual rate of returna is thus the riskless rate r.

aIn the sense of (1/τ ) ln E[ Sτ/S ] (arithmetic average rate of return) not (1/τ )E[ ln(Sτ/S) ] (geometric average rate of return).

(67)

Toward the Black-Scholes Formula (concluded)

a

Theorem 8 (The Black-Scholes Formula) C = SN (x) − Xe−rτN (x − σ√

τ ), P = Xe−rτN (−x + σ√

τ ) − SN (−x), where

x ≡ ln(S/X) + ¡

r + σ2/2¢ τ σ√

τ .

aOn a United flight from San Francisco to Tokyo on March 7, 2010, a real-estate manager mentioned this formula to me!

參考文獻

相關文件

• The existence of different implied volatilities for options on the same underlying asset shows the Black-Scholes model cannot be literally true.

 If I buy a call option from you, I am paying you a certain amount of money in return for the right to force you to sell me a share of the stock, if I want it, at the strike price,

One, the response speed of stock return for the companies with high revenue growth rate is leading to the response speed of stock return the companies with

The above information is for discussion and reference only and should not be treated as investment

 Warrants are an instrument which gives investors the right – but not the obligation – to buy or sell the underlying assets at a pre- set price on or before a specified date.

• When a call is exercised, the holder pays the strike price in exchange for the stock.. • When a put is exercised, the holder receives from the writer the strike price in exchange

• When a call is exercised, the holder pays the strike price in exchange for the stock.. • When a put is exercised, the holder receives from the writer the strike price in exchange

The ES and component shortfall are calculated using the simulation from C-vine copula structure instead of that from multivariate distribution because the C-vine copula