• 沒有找到結果。

看得見的一隻手---新聞媒體之影響

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "看得見的一隻手---新聞媒體之影響"

Copied!
19
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

看得見的一隻手:新聞媒體之影響

研究成果報告(精簡版)

計 畫 類 別 : 個別型

計 畫 編 號 : NSC 97-2410-H-004-060-

執 行 期 間 : 97 年 08 月 01 日至 98 年 10 月 31 日

執 行 單 位 : 國立政治大學經濟學系

計 畫 主 持 人 : 何靜嫺

報 告 附 件 : 出席國際會議研究心得報告及發表論文

處 理 方 式 : 本計畫可公開查詢

中 華 民 國 98 年 12 月 21 日

(2)

Access Details: [subscription number 789752033] Publisher: Routledge

Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Asian Journal of Communication

Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713684587

Heterogeneous multi-product competition in Taiwan's

newspaper industry

Shirley J. Hoa; Mine Ping Sunb

aDepartment of Economics, National Chengchi University, Taiwan bDepartment of Journalism, National Chengchi University, Taiwan

Online Publication Date: 01 June 2008

To cite this Article: Ho, Shirley J. and Ping Sun, Mine (2008) 'Heterogeneous multi-product competition in Taiwan's newspaper industry', Asian Journal of Communication, 18:2, 102 — 116

To link to this article: DOI: 10.1080/01292980802021822 URL:http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01292980802021822

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Full terms and conditions of use:http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf

This article maybe used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

(3)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

RESEARCH ARTICLE

Heterogeneous multi-product competition in Taiwan’s newspaper

industry

Shirley J. Hoa* and Mine Ping Sunb

a

Department of Economics, National Chengchi University, Taiwan;bDepartment of Journalism, National Chengchi University, Taiwan

Taiwan’s daily newspaper industry is characterized by multiple products and heterogeneous competition. This article develops a game-theoretic model to analyze the strategic and competitive reaction of the incumbent in the newspaper market to a recent tabloid-like entertainment newspaper entrant and its impact on the industrial structure through a modification of Judd’s multi-product competi-tion model (1985), considering the property of heterogeneous competicompeti-tion in the Taiwan newspaper market. The leading incumbent operated newspapers in the general news and entertainment-oriented news segments of the market and our equilibrium analysis shows that closing its entertainment-oriented paper was the optimal response to the competitive entry in the short run. However, when the possibility that the entrant might invest in disruptive innovations in other product segments after entry is considered, the model shows that the incumbent’s withdrawal from the entertainment market could induce more severe competition in the general news market and thus hurt its long-term profits. Managerial insights and implications of the analysis are discussed.

Keywords: media economics; game theory; Apple Daily; Taiwan newspaper industry

Introduction

The Min Sheng Daily, a product of the United Daily group with a colorful history of 28 years ceased publication on November 20, 2006. The Min Sheng Daily was once labeled as ‘Taiwan’s only professional entertainment newspaper which covered the people’s livelihood,’ (The Min Sheng Daily ceases, 2006) and reached a pinnacle of 570,000 copies in July 1987. In its cessation of publication declaration, the Min Sheng Daily proclaimed that its decision was not due to harsh competition from a new competitor (the Apple Daily), but was rather the result of a rapidly changing environment, coupled with tremendous changes in consumers’ reading habits.

However, in the same harsh environment, the Apple Daily, a tabloid newspaper from Hong Kong, has started to reap positive profits only 2 years and 10 months after its launch in May 2003. According to the 2005/06 annual financial report of Next Media which owns the Apple Daily, by March 2006 the Taiwan branch of Apple Daily had earned its first positive profit of 1.2 million Hong Kong dollars (Young, 2006). Subsequently, the 2006/07 annual financial report showed total profits of

*Corresponding author. Email: sjho@nccu.edu.tw

ISSN 0129-2986 print/ISSN 1742-0911 online #2008 AMIC/SCI-NTU

DOI: 10.1080/01292980802021822 http://www.informaworld.com

(4)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

69.4 million Hong Kong dollars (Next Media Limited Corporation, 2007). According to AC Nielsen’s survey (Nielsen Media Research, 2007), at the end of March 2007, the Apple Daily’s readership shares had reached 15.9%, closely tailing The Liberty Times’ 16.3% and far ahead of the United Daily’s 10.4% and the 8.5% of the China Times.

The Apple Daily entered the market as a tabloid, providing paparazzi-style scandal exposures and exhibiting a flair for flaunting sex and violence in full-color. The so-called ‘Apple Effect’ moved the traditionally defined ‘serious reporting’ to celebrity/entertainment tabloids, so that only firms capable of transforming all types of information into ‘entertainment’ would survive. The first victims of this effect were those news firms providing entertainment news. The Da Cheng Daily, a celebrity newspaper which was once the only competition to the Min Sheng Daily, ceased publication by the end of February 2006. In November 2006, the Star News, another celebrity newspaper aimed at younger readers and also an affiliate of the United Daily group, quietly terminated operations. Finally, the Min Sheng Daily, despite undergoing a sequence of modifications, caved in after an 8-month struggle. An interesting question to ask is why, given that it was restructured to gradually become more market-oriented, the Min Sheng Daily was still unable to turn the tide. More importantly, after ridding itself of the economically burdensome Min Sheng Daily, will the United Daily group necessarily stop losing money? After the closing of the Min Sheng Daily, what will happen to Taiwan’s newspaper industry?

The main purpose of this paper is to address these questions in an industrial economics model. We provide a game-theoretic analysis to explain the current competition in the industry as well as provide management insights into the future development of existing firms. Our paper starts by modifying Judd’s (1985) model of multiple products when considering the property of heterogeneous competition in Taiwan’s newspaper industry, and concludes that the closing of the Min Sheng Daily is indeed an optimal decision for the United Daily group in the short run. However, when we consider disruptive innovations (Christensen & Raynor, 2003) by extending the model to a four-stage framework where the entrant can strategically invest in R&D, we show that the United Daily group’s withdrawal from the entertainment market will induce severe competition in the general news market. Based on this model, we provide some recommendations for management in regard to the current crisis in Taiwan’s newspaper industry.

Notice first that since our purpose is to provide managerial insights into the present situation and future development of Taiwan’s newspaper industry, Judd’s model provides us with an easy and straightforward setup to focus our concerns, rather than distract readers with complicated mathematical calculations. We hope that by adopting a multiple product model which incorporates the possibility of ‘disruptive innovation’ mentioned by Christensen and Raynor (2003), the theoretical discussion of our paper can provide insightful explanations regarding recent developments in Taiwan’s newspaper industry and provide recommendations to the management of the incumbent news firms.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the current status of Taiwan’s newspaper industry, our purpose being to understand the fundamental properties of the market’s structure, which serve as empirical justifications for our model’s setup. Sections 3 and 4 present the modified Judd

(5)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

(1985) model, incorporating the heterogeneous competition in the news industry and the possibility of ‘disruptive innovation.’ We will derive the short-term equilibrium first and then the long-term equilibrium, where we will also provide some managerial suggestions for the incumbent news firms. Section 5 concludes the paper.

Taiwan’s newspaper industry

This section first describes the multiple product properties of Taiwan’s newspaper industry, and then summarizes the incumbents’ strategic reactions to the rapid change in the industry. The history of the industry reviewed will serve as empirical justification for our assumptions in the basic model, and will help us provide more realistic management suggestions.

Multiple products

Taiwan’s newspapers can be classified into six categories: general newspapers (e.g., the China Times, the Liberty Times, and the United Daily), business newspapers (e.g., the Commercial Times and the Economic Daily News), entertainment newspapers (e.g., the Da Cheng Daily and the Min Sheng Daily), evening newspapers (e.g., the China Times Evening and United Daily Evening), English language newspapers, and regional newspapers (e.g., Hualien’s Keng Sheng Daily and Tainan’s Chung Hwa Daily). It is important to notice that, to both the public and academia (So, 1997; Tsai, 2005), the Apple Daily is considered to be an undisputed provider of entertainment and recreational news. Hence, our model will treat the Apple Daily as a newspaper providing soft information or entertainment news.1

Declining newspaper demand, substitutes, and readership changes

Cable TV and the Internet have provided plenty of substitutes for newspapers, causing the demand for these to decline. In addition, these diverse, plentiful, cheap, and accessible media have rapidly changed people’s media consumption habits. The cable TV law was passed in 1992, and cable penetration rose from 26% in 1992 to the current 85%. Furthermore, according to AC Nielsen’s survey in December 2006, the percentage of the population using the Internet had risen from 40.8% in 2002 to 51.3% by the end of September 2006.

The ‘television culture’ is slowly replacing the culture of written language and, for some, free information on the Internet is displacing newspapers. With declining interest in public affairs, most consumers seek gossip-oriented recreational information instead of spending time and money on newspapers (Denton, 1993; Kurtz, 1993). According to Nielsen’s media survey (Nielsen Media Research, 2007) since the early 1990s Taiwan’s newspaper readership rate had slipped from its peak of 76% to a low of 46% by March 2007. In other words, more than 50% of Taiwan’s population does not read newspapers. In another survey conducted by Rainmaker Company, the advertising revenue of newspapers has been continuously declining from near NT$16,514 million in 2001 to NT$14,450 million in 2006. From a holistic point of view, the golden age of newspapers in Taiwan has already passed.

(6)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

Competitive entry into a heterogeneous product market

The Apple Daily was launched on May 2, 2003, by Hong Kong businessman Jimmy Lai Chee Yin. Six months later, the Apple Daily had reached an impressive 10% of total newspaper readership, ranking fourth behind the three major newspapers: the United Daily, the China Times, and the Liberty Times. In the first half of 2005, the Apple Daily took second place in terms of circulation to the top selling paper, the Liberty Times. In what follows, we will briefly describe how the Apple Daily provided differentiated products that turned consumers away from the incumbent firms, the management strategy that they adopted to quickly meet consumers’ requirements, and the resulting impact that the newspaper had on the incumbents in the industry. The Apple Daily adopts a reader-first attitude in deciding on the content of its news; the content of the news is chosen to satisfy the consumers’ preferences, rather than to educate the public.2 The Apple Daily interacts enthusiastically with consumers by instantly responding to consumers’ suggestions on its layouts and, most of all, by conducting ‘focus group interviews’ with readers on a daily basis. The Apple Daily was the first of Taiwan’s newspaper industry to establish an ‘exposure hotline,’ asking readers to provide potentially newsworthy material and suggestions. ‘These flexible strategies to fulfill the market demand and to provide a completely market-oriented content have successfully closed the gap between the consumers and media content’ (Tsai, 2005).

When faced with the competition from this new entrant, there were mainly three types of reactions from the incumbents: to give up and close down their papers, to restructure and provide new and differentiated products, and to fight back. As described, the entertainment news market was the first to encounter the competition from the Apple Daily. Local newspapers and evening papers were the first victims to stop publication, to be followed by the Da Cheng Daily, the Star News, and the Evening China Times.

Second, in the name of ‘restructuring,’ the incumbents introduced new products or changed their layouts in order to differentiate themselves from the Apple Daily’s sensational style. For example, after the launch of the Apple Daily in 2003, the market share of Min Sheng Daily, whose overall readership rates originally ranked it in fourth place, began to decline from 3.1% in 2003. In April 2005, the Min Sheng Daily introduced the ‘Sunday News,’ issued every Sunday as a 24-page, octavo-format delicate tabloid. In late March 2006, the Min Sheng Daily underwent an overall revamp that turned its focus to boutique consumption, comprising in-depth features on entertainment and sports that were aimed mainly at the social elite. However, these efforts did not provide sufficient differentiation to insulate the Min Sheng Daily from the Apple Daily’s competitive threat. When the Min Sheng Daily ceased publication in December 2006, it had a circulation of merely 80,000 copies (The Min Sheng Daily with, 2006).

Third, the major newspapers (i.e., the United Daily, China Times, and Liberty Times) adopted a more aggressive attitude to fight the Apple Daily, including offering sales discounts, making layout and content adjustments, and featuring much more sensational news (Sun, 2005). However, such ‘Apple-ization’ or ‘tabloidization’ was unable to prevent readers from turning to the fresher and newer Apple Daily. Since the three major papers could not both differentiate themselves from each other and mimic the Apple Daily, they fell into a fierce competition amongst themselves

(7)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

(Li & Mai, 2003), while the Apple Daily established a loyal readership and differentiated itself from the other papers right from the beginning. Within 3 years, the China Times had lost 36% of its readers, the United Daily had lost 14%, and the Liberty Times had lost 23%. This forced the China Times and the United Daily to turn back to their original styles to keep their loyal readers. The Liberty Times, on the other hand, ventured further down the path of Apple-ization by further investing in providing paparazzi-type news and sharper sensationalism. In addition, the Liberty Times distributed a large quantity of free papers and published extra recreational issues as weekend supplements.

In sum, Taiwan’s newspaper industry is characterized by multiple products and heterogeneous competition. To correctly describe these two properties, in the next section we will modify Judd’s (1985) model of multiple products by considering the nature of heterogeneous product competition in Taiwan’s newspaper industry. Then the model will be extended into a four-stage framework to capture the long-term development of the market equilibrium, considering that the new entrant is capable of working on R&D to increase demand in the general news market (i.e., disruptive innovations).

The basic model

Judd (1985) examined a sequential game in which a multiproduct incumbent firm, when facing competition from an entrant offering a substitute for one of its products, needs to decide whether to continue or withdraw from the invaded market. Then each firm will determine its prices in each market accordingly. Judd characterized an equilibrium where it can be optimal for the incumbent firm to withdraw from the invaded market. This is similar to the evidence in Taiwan’s newspaper industry, where the entrant started invading in the low-end entertainment news market. As our purpose is to provide managerial insights into the present situation and the future development of Taiwan’s newspaper industry, Judd’s model provides us with an easy and straightforward setup to derive the equilibrium and to focus our attention on the development of the newspaper industry, rather than distracting readers with complicated mathematical calculations.3

We will modify Judd’s model by considering the property of heterogeneous competition; that is, we assume that, except for the invaded market, the incumbent firm will also compete with other firms in another market (e.g., the general news market). This setup can generally fit similar situations being faced in other industries. For example, Yahoo is competing with eBay in the E-auction market, while Yahoo is also providing other services that are competing with Google. Another example is the telecommunications industry, where the entrants have invaded the long-distance calls market and the incumbents are competing with other firms in local phone services.

The model setting

The structure of the basic model is given as follows. First, to simplify the analysis, we assume that there are three news firms: 1, 2, and 3. There are two kinds of products in the newspaper industry: general newspaper (G) and entertainment newspaper (E). Firm 1 and firm 2 are in the general newspaper market,4and firm 1 and firm 3 are in

(8)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

the entertainment newspaper market. To see the correspondence to the Taiwan newspaper industry, assume that firm 1 is the United Daily, firm 2 is the China Times or Liberty Times, firm 3 is the entrant Apple Daily, and the United Daily’s entertainment-oriented product is the Min Sheng Daily. Here, in order to focus on the firms’ market choices, we follow Judd (1985) in normalizing the firms’ operating costs to zero, and leave for later discussion cases where this assumption is relaxed.

To capture heterogeneity among consumers, we modify Judd’s (1985) assumption by considering three types of consumers: G1, G2, and E, where Gi, for i 1 or 2,

represents a consumer oriented toward firm i in the general news market and E identifies a consumer oriented toward any entertainment newspaper, for the reasons given below. Without loss of generality, we follow Judd (1985) in assuming that there is only one consumer for each type, and each consumer purchases only one newspaper. The consumers’ utilities are given as Equations (1) and (2):

UGi

apG

i; if buys Gfrom firm i;

alpG

j; i " j; if buys G from firm j;

agpE

i; i 1; 3; if buys E from firm i:

8 <

: (1)

UE apEi; if buys E from firm i;

agpG

i; i 1; 2; if buys G from firm i:



(2)

/pGi and pEi denote firm i’s prices in the G and E markets, respectively. a reflects the

benefit in terms of the satisfaction derived from reading the most preferred news; l denotes the slight reduction in utility a consumer experiences if she buys her favorite type of news from a less preferred newspaper firm that still specializes in her favorite type of news; and g denotes the greater loss in utility experienced if a consumer buys a less favored type of newspaper (one that specializes in providing the less preferred type of news).

Take consumer G1as an example. G1is the consumer oriented toward firm ‘1’ in

the ‘general’ news market, and firm 1 denotes the United Daily. The interpretation of UG1 is as follows. If G

1buys her favorite United Daily, then her satisfaction will be

the highest a. Her overall utility will be the benefit in terms of the satisfaction derived from reading the paper minus the purchase price, i.e., apG

1; If G1buys general news

from a less preferred general news firm such as the China Times or Liberty Times, then the satisfaction from reading the paper will be reduced by l, so that the overall utility will be the benefit in terms of the satisfaction (/al) derived from reading it

minus the cost of purchasing general news from firm j (for j " i); i.e., alpG j:

However, if she buys the entertainment newspaper, then there will be a larger reduction in utility, g, and the overall net utility gain will be the benefit in terms of the satisfaction derived from reading the paper of ag minus the cost of purchasing the entertainment news from either firm 1 or firm 3, i.e., agpE

i for i  1; 3: To

simplify the analysis, we will assume that l B g B a B 2l to capture the fact that even within the general news market, there is still heterogeneous competition.

The specification of consumer E’s utility is different in order to reflect the current situation in Taiwan’s entertainment news market. That is, for consumer E, the satisfaction from consuming the product of either firm 1 or firm 3 is the same (i.e., a), but if she is forced to read the general news, there will be a loss of utility of g compared to the satisfaction derived from reading an entertainment-oriented newspaper.5 This is assumed to be so because, comparatively speaking, Taiwan’s

(9)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

entertainment news is small and both of the main providers (i.e., the Min Sheng Daily and Apple Daily) have focused on the same consumer-related and entertain-ment news. The readers exhibit a less strong loyalty toward the news firms than they do in the general news market. This can be justified by the observation that, when the Apple Daily entered the market, its experimenting with a low price of NT$5 successfully turned most readers from the Min Sheng Daily to the Apple Daily. In the case of strong loyalty, a low price strategy should not permanently move the readers to another provider.

Hence the interpretation of consumer E’s utility function is that, if she buys entertainment news, her net utility gain will be the benefit from satisfaction a, minus the purchasing price pE

i for i  1; 3: If she buys the general news from either firm

1 or firm 3, there is a dissatisfaction loss g, and hence the overall utility will be agpG

i;for i  1; 3:

Sequential stages of the basic game

At the start of the game, firms 1 and 2 are in the G market, and firms 1 and 3 are in the E market. In the game, the firms make decisions sequentially as follows: at stage 1, firm 1 first decides whether to continue or withdraw from the E market. Then, at stage 2, each of the firms competitively sets the price(s) of its newspaper(s). Accordingly, there are two subgames after stage 1, namely, (1) firm 1 simultaneously operates in the G and E markets, and (2) firm 1 withdraws from the E market. 6

Deriving the equilibrium

Since the game is a sequential one, the subgame perfect equilibrium (Selten, 1975) of the game will be derived by backward induction. For this end, we first calculate the equilibrium prices in each of the two subgames with respect to firm 1’s stage-1 decision possibilities and then determine firm 1’s equilibrium decision.

The subgame if Firm 1 stays in the E market

The equilibrium prices in this subgame are the prices where no consumer or firm will find it beneficial to unilaterally deviate. We now demonstrate that the equilibrium prices for this subgame will be pG

1 pG2 g and pE1 pE3 0: 7

Consumers G1and G2

will purchase from firm 1 and firm 2, respectively, and consumer E will be indifferent between buying from firm 1 or from firm 3.

First, since the E market is homogeneously competitive, firm 1 and firm 3 will charge competitive prices, i.e., marginal cost pricing will prevail. Since we have assumed a zero marginal cost of operation, the equilibrium prices will hence be/

pE

1 pE3 0: Second, given pE1 pE3 0 in the E market, we need to demonstrate that

consumers G1 and G2 will make choices consistent with this equilibrium and

purchase product G from firm 1 and firm 2, respectively. Notice first that if both of them deviate by purchasing product E, their utilities will be the same, i.e., ag0: For both G1and G2to adhere to the equilibrium and not deviate to purchase

product E, the highest possible prices that firm 1 and firm 2 can charge must be set at the levels where G1and G2are indifferent between buying product G and product E.

(10)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

This requires the utilities to be the same in these two cases, that is, apG

i /ag0;

for i 1, 2. Therefore, we have/pG1 pG2 g:

In addition, we need to consider the following deviation where, say, firm 1 could charge a lower price so that even G2finds it beneficial to purchase from firm 1. To

attract G2, firm 1 must reduce its price to pG1 gl; so that consumer G2will be

indifferent between purchasing from firm 1 and firm 2. In this case, firm 1 will have the payoff 2(gl): Since we have assumed earlier that l B g B aB 2l; this deviation cannot be profitable as 2(gl) is less than the equilibrium payoff l. We have restricted the range of parameters to simplify the discussion,8 so that a unilateral deviation will not be profitable. Since our main purpose is to study the current situation and future development of Taiwan’s newspaper industry, we need this assumption to avoid burdening readers with a complicated discussion, and this also applies to the following discussion and Note 12.

Finally, we can calculate each player’s payoff in this subgame. Under these prices, consumer Giwill not unilaterally change her consumption decision, and since she

can purchase from her most favored firm, the utility will be ag: Next, since consumer E is indifferent between buying from firm 1 and firm 3, her utility will be/

a0: Since both firm 1 and firm 3 will be operating in the E market, the competition among firms offering homogeneous products will drive the profits down to zero. In addition, as consumers rationally compare prices, the competition in the E market will influence the profits in the G market. To sum up, the firms’ profits in this subgame will be p1 g; p2 g; and p3 0:

The subgame given Firm 1’s exit from the E market

We will demonstrate that the equilibrium prices in this subgame are: pG

1 pG2 a and/

pE

3 a: Consumers G1and G2will purchase from firm 1 and firm 2, respectively, and

consumer E will buy from firm 3. First, notice that since firm 1 has withdrawn from the E market, firm 3 will be the monopolist and hence the profit maximizing price will be pE

3 a:

Next, given pE

3 a in the E market, we need to demonstrate that consumers G1

and G2will follow the equilibrium and purchase product G from firm 1 and firm 2,

respectively. Notice first that if both of them deviate by purchasing product E, their utilities will be the same, i.e., agaB 0. This enables firm 1 and firm 2 to charge the profit maximizing prices, i.e., pG

1 p G

2 a; without worrying that consumers will

turn to product E and derive a negative utility.

In addition, we need to consider the following deviation where, say, firm 1 could charge a lower price so that even G2finds it beneficial to purchase from firm 1. To

attract G2, firm 1 must reduce the price to pG1 al; so that consumer G2will be

indifferent between purchasing from firm 1 and firm 2. In this case, firm 1 will have the payoff 2(al): This deviation will not be profitable, as 2(al) is less than firm 1’s equilibrium payoff a.

Finally, we can calculate each player’s payoff in this subgame. Since all three firms have charged the profit maximizing prices, i.e., pE

3 pG1 pG2 a; the utilities

for all consumers will be zero, that is, aa: Similarly, the equilibrium profits for each firm are p1 a; p2 a; and p3 a:

(11)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

Subgame perfect equilibrium of the game

Given the equilibrium profits for firm 1 in the two subgames, respectively, we now determine firm 1’s decision in the first stage. To do this, we can simply compare firm 1’s payoffs from these two subgames. Because the payoff to the firm from continuing in the E market (g) is smaller than that from withdrawing (a), firm 1 will choose to withdraw from the invaded E market.

To sum up, in the unique subgame perfect equilibrium, firm 1 will choose to withdraw from the E market. Then, all three firms will charge the same price pG

1

pG

2 a and p E

3 a: Consumers G1 and G2 will purchase from firm 1 and firm 2,

respectively, and consumer E will buy from firm 3. In this equilibrium, all consumers derive zero utility, and the equilibrium profits for each firm are/p1 a; p2 a; and/

p3 a: Proposition 1 summarizes the above discussion.

Proposition 1. In the unique subgame perfect equilibrium described above, the United Daily (firm 1) is better off withdrawing from the entertainment market (E) when faced with the competition from the Apple Daily (firm 3).

The intuition as to why firm 1 can benefit from withdrawing from the E market is that, after exiting the market, it will be able to raise its price in the general news market because the price of an imperfect substitute (entertainment-oriented news-papers) will increase. This can increase firm 1’s profit in the G market, where firm 2 will also benefit. Moreover, according to our analysis, after closing down the Min Sheng Daily, the entertainment news market will become a monopoly and such news will be provided by the Apple Daily only.

The extended model considering disruptive innovation

This section examines the situation where firm 3 is capable of innovating and developing new demand in the general news market. Our purpose is to see whether withdrawing from the entertainment news market is still an optimal decision for firm 1 in the long term. We extend the basic model to a four-stage game, in which firm 3 can develop new demand in the general news market through R&D financed from profits. We assume that only firm 3 will work on R&D, as this reflects an earlier observation that the Apple Daily is more aggressive and innovative than the incumbents. We will leave for a later discussion the cases where all firms have the R&D ability.

Subsequent stages of the extended game

The first two stages of the extended game are the same as the basic game above. That is, at stage 1, firm 1 first decides whether to continue or withdraw from the E market. Then, at stage 2, each of the firms competitively sets the price(s) of its newspaper(s). At stage 3, firm 3 decides how much to invest in an uncertain innovation to develop new customers (i.e., demand) in the general news market if the firm realizes a positive profit at stage 2. However, if firm 3 does not profit at stage 2, it will not invest in innovation and then do nothing but proceed to stage 4. At stage 4, each of the firms sets the price(s) of its newspaper(s) and competes with the other firms.

(12)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

R&D technology

Let x denote firm 3’s R&D investment and let p(x) denote the probability of being successful in creating enough heterogeneous demand (and hence loyal readers) in the general news market. p(x) is a nondecreasing convex function of x. To simplify the analysis, we assume 0 5 (p’)1( 1

2ag) 5a 9

, where -1 denotes the inverse of the first-order derivative p’(:):

If the innovation is successful, then there will be a new consumer G3who is loyal

to firm 3’s general news, and the utility received is defined in a similar way to Equation (1). Otherwise, if the innovation fails, there are two possibilities regarding whether film 3 enters the G market or not. If firm 3 does not enter the G market, there is no effect on the other incumbents’ pricing strategies at stage 4. If firm 3 does enter the G market, firm 3’s G product is homogeneous with products G1or G2(as a

result of the failure in creating a heterogeneous product). Therefore, firm 3’s entry to the G market will affect the other firms’ pricing decisions. A rigorous way of incorporating these two possibilities is to use a probability for each case to take place. However, in the first case, only firm 1’s decision about withdrawal will be affected and the other firms’ pricing strategies will remain unchanged. For analytical ease, we assume away the first possibility and presume by default a homogeneous competition in G between firm 3 and firms 1 and 2, if firm 3’s innovation is not successful.

Deriving the equilibrium

We now derive the subgame perfect equilibrium by solving backward the sequence of the stages. That is, we first derive the stage-4 subgame equilibria, respectively, given that firm 3 succeeds in its G-product innovation and that it fails. Then we decide firm 3’s R&D input. Finally, we characterize the equilibrium prices at stage 2, and then firm 1’s withdrawal decision.

Subgame equilibrium for stage 4

Remember that firm 3 will participate in the stage-4 market competition only if firm 1 has already withdrawn from the E market. If firm 1 stays in the E market, firm 3’s profit in the E market will be zero due to competition in homogeneous products (see the basic model). Firm 3 will not have the ability to invest in R&D and enter the general news market. Therefore, the equilibrium profits will be p1 p2 g and/

p3 0:

However, if firm 1 withdraws from the E market, so that firm 3 has a chance to make a positive profit, the equilibrium will depend on whether firm 3 is successful in R&D. First, if firm 3 can successfully develop new demand in the G market, then the calculation of the equilibrium prices of the G products will be similar to that in the basic model. That is, in this case, firm 3 will develop the loyal reader G3, whose

greatest benefit from reading firm 3’s general news will be a. There will be a reduction in utility g if she purchases the general news from firm 1 or firm 2. With the assumption that l B g B aB 2l; the equilibrium prices will be pG

1 pG2 pG3 a:

Since the general news firms all charge, there is no need to prevent consumer E from switching to the general news and hence firm 3 will charge the monopolistic price

(13)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

pE

3 a: To sum up, the equilibrium profit for each firm will be p1 a; p2 a; and

p3 2a:

Moreover, if firm 3 fails to create new demand for G, then the homogeneous competition will drive the prices down to pG

1 pG2 pG3 0: 10

Furthermore, to prevent consumer E from switching to the G market, pE

3 must be set at a level where

consumer E is indifferent between consuming products E and G, that is, apE 3/

ag0: Hence, pE

3 g: In this situation, the equilibrium profits will be p1 0;

p2 0; and p3 g:

Firm 3’s R&D decision at stage 3

Given stage 4’s market equilibrium as above, firm 3 needs to decide the level of R&D (i.e., x), given the probability p(x) for innovation success (thus firm 3 will have a profit of/2a at stage 4). Of course, the likelihood that the innovation fails is 1-/p(x);

and when this happens, firm 3 will have a profit of g at stage 4. Therefore, given a withdrawal decision already made by firm 1, firm 3 will maximize its expected profit as described below11:

max

x fp(x)2a(1p(x))gxg

subject to 0 5 x 5 a: (3)

Since g B 2a and p(x) is a non-decreasing convex function, the maximization problem is well defined and the optimal x will exist. Let x*denote this optimal R&D level. x*must satisfy p’(x)(2ag)  1;12

and firm 3’s optimal profit at stage 4 will be p(x)2a(1p(x))gx:However, we will eschew a more detailed discussion on

the optimal R&D level, as our focus is on the firm’s market choice. It is obvious from the first-order condition that, when a is greater or g is smaller, the R&D input is higher.

Subgame equilibrium at stage 2 and firm 1’s decision about withdrawal at stage 1 Notice that the subgame equilibrium profits from the E product competition at stage 2 of this extended game are the same as those in the basic game. That is, the equilibrium profits at this stage will be p1 a; p2 a; and p3 a if firm 1 withdraws

from the E market or p1 g; p2 g; and p3 0 if firm 1 stays in the E market. We

now can identify firm 1’s decision about withdrawal or not, after we have characterized the subgame equilibria at stages 2, 3, and 4. To this end, we compare firm 1’s total profits from the decisions to withdraw and to stay. As stated earlier, if firm 1 remains in the E market, then firm 3’s profit in the E market will be zero due to the homogeneous products competition. Then firm 3 will not invest in R&D and enter the G market. Therefore, firm 1’s profit from the G product sales at stage 4 is also p1 g: Its combined profits from stage 2 and 4 will be 2g.

However, if firm 1 withdraws from the E market, firm 1’s profit at stage 2 is a as derived. Meanwhile, firm 3 will have a positive profit, with which it can invest in developing new demand in the G market. If the innovation is successful, then firm 1 still has a profit of a from stage 4. If the innovation fails, then homogeneous product competition will drive firm 1’s profit down to zero. Given the optimal R&D level x* determined in Equation (3) and the probability of success p(x); the expected sum of

(14)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

By comparison, it follows that if1p(x)

2 a B g; then withdrawing from the E market

is no longer an optimal decision, when the invading firm can extend its entry to the G market by disruptive innovation. With this condition, the unique subgame perfect equilibrium of the whole game is that firm 1 stays in the E market competing with firm 3. The equilibria for stage 2 and 4 will be the same, i.e., pE

1 p E 3 0 and/ pG 1 p G

2 g: Hence, the firms’ total profits are p1 2g; p2 2g and p3 0:

Proposition 2 summarizes the above discussion.

Proposition 2. From the unique subgame perfect equilibrium derived above, given

1p(x)

2 aBg; if the Apple Daily (firm 3) is R&D-capable while entering the general news

market, the withdrawal of the United Daily (firm 1) from the entertainment news market will diminish its profit earned from the general news market and hence reduce its overall long-term profit.

Withdrawing from the invaded market is a short-term optimal decision for firm 1, but it can be non-optimal or even harmful in the long term. The intuition behind this is that, in the short term, firm 1 has ignored the fact that partially withdrawing can give the new entrant the opportunity to work on R&D and develop new demand in the higher-level market. Next, we will address some comparative statistics and provide several management insights to the incumbent news firms.

Discussion

If a positive operating cost is taken into consideration, then the competitive prices will be set at a higher cost (instead of zero). For example, it has been reported that the family that owned Min Sheng Daily was less efficient than the owners of the Apple Daily, and hence the operational cost was higher in the case of the Min Sheng Daily. When the Apple Daily entered the E market by charging an experimental low price of NT$5, most consumers switched to this new entrant, resulting in a reduction in demand for the Min Sheng Daily. This loss in demand and the comparatively higher operating costs drove the profits of the Min Sheng Daily down into negative figures. Even after the Apple Daily raised its price to the competitive price of NT$15, the long-term deficit forced the United Daily group to close the Min Sheng Daily.

Second, the results of the R&D can be expressed in terms of increasing the satisfaction of the existing (instead of new) consumers, so as to increase satisfaction from to a’( a) or to decrease the utility losses l and g. For example, a successful invention by the Apple Daily is the ‘focus group interviews,’ through which consumers’ suggestions are taken directly to ensure that the content of the news can provide more satisfaction. A counter example will be the fact that both the United Daily and the China Times have also invested in diversification, including issuing magazines, books, evening news, and even network news. However, since these inventions (by diversification) have not created enough heterogeneity and hence have not provided enough satisfaction to consumers, the small profits from only part of these subsidiary businesses are insufficient to cover the losses from their newspapers. Even worse, similar to their competition in newspapers, the two news firms are being confronted by each other in the diversified markets and between their nearly homogeneous newspapers are driving their profits down.

(15)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

Based on this line of reasoning, we can provide two possible expectations for the Liberty Times, which became fully Apple-ized following the Apple Daily’s launch. First, the Liberty Times and the Apple Daily will become more homogeneous in the general news market, and this will drive their profits down to competitive levels. Second, since the Apple Daily has pre-empted the entertainment news market, imitation by the Liberty Times will not create enough heterogeneity for consumers and, as a result, it is expected that Apple-izing the Liberty Times will cause it to lose its original demand.

Third, the results of R&D can also be broadly expressed so as to develop new markets. A successful example is the case where the China Times invested in cable television in May 2002, by acquiring CTI TV (Chen & Cheng, 2003).13The new owner turned the ‘money loser’ CTI TV into a profit-maker within 3 years and, in 2005, CTI TV had a profit of more than NT$100 million (Liao, 2005). Moreover, on December 26, 2005, the China Times bought the wireless China TV from the KMT, hoping to make a handsome profit like they did with CTI TV. Fourth, since the revenue from advertising will be positively related to market share, if we assume that each firm charges a competitive price for advertising space (denoted by A), then each firm’s unit revenue will be PG

i A or PEi A for i 1, 2, 3. Then, with minor modifications to the

equilibrium conditions, our main conclusions above will still apply.

Concluding remarks

Taiwan’s newspaper industry is now at a saturated stage. The popularity of cable TV and the Internet has attracted huge numbers of consumers who had previously been oriented toward newspapers, and the new entrant, the Apple Daily, has worsened the situation by attracting consumers with its fresher content and more efficient management. While most of the attention has focused on the concern expressed that newspapers will become more and more sensational, this study, starting with the United Daily’s decision to shut down the Min Sheng Daily, attempts to provide an economic interpretation for the current status of the industry. We first modified Judd’s (1985) model of multiple products by taking into account the heterogeneous products competition in Taiwan’s newspaper industry. Then we extended the basic model by considering disruptive innovations (Christensen & Raynor, 2003).

Our main conclusion is as follows. Closing the Min Sheng Daily is optimal in the short term but could lead to further reductions in profit in the general news market in the long term. The various diversifications will not necessarily result in profits if they cannot provide enough product diversity to consumers. Finally, since adver-tisements and networks have been very important topics in the mass media, we will leave their detailed discussion to further research. However, as demonstrated above, our model can still provide a simple analysis explaining how advertising or the Internet can change the news firms’ market choices.

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge the constructive suggestions made by Wayne Fu and one anonymous referee of this journal. The second author is grateful to Ping-Hung Chen, Chien-San Feng, Shih-Hung Luo, Kuo-Feng Tseng, and participants at the 2007 annual conference of the Chinese Communication Society.

(16)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

Notes

1. If this assumption is violated, two of our main conclusions still apply with slight modifications in the requirements for equilibrium.

2. Educating the public was a mission of the mainstream newspapers.

3. For example, see Baumol, Panzar, and Willig (1982) for more complicated multiple product setups.

4. Although there are in fact more than two competitors in each market, for example, there are three main newspapers in the general news market (the China Times, United Daily, and Liberty Times), the assumption of two firms is sufficient to describe the competitive environment.

5. If this assumption is violated, two of our main conclusions will still apply with slight modifications regarding the requirements for equilibrium.

6. Since this paper focuses on the news firms’ strategic choices for multiple markets, we do not consider advertising in our model. However, as the revenue from advertising is normally positively related with the readership (see Increasing newspaper revenue, 2005), our model can provide a simple analysis of advertising’s effect (see Discussion). Since the effect of advertisement has been an important issue in the media literature (e.g., Gabszewicz, Laussel, & Sonnac, 2001), we will leave detailed discussion to further research.

7. This is a standard price competition equilibrium.

8. Otherwise, we need to discuss the equilibrium for every possible range for a and l. 9. Otherwise, we need to discuss various cases of corner solutions.

10. Here, for modeling simplicity, the homogeneity among all of the three G products is assumed given the failure of firm 3 in the innovation. A more general or realistic assumption can be that firm 3’s G product becomes substitutable only to either firms 1 or 2 but not both, where firms 1 and 2 remain heterogeneous. It follows that with firms 3 and 1 substitutable, the competitive prices will be pG

1pG30 and pG2g: Otherwise, with

firms 3 and 2 substitutable, then the competitive prices will be pG 2p

G

30 and p G 1g:

Nonetheless, the results derived in the text still apply to these two situations with slight modifications to the condition that characterizes the results of the game.

11. 2a and g are derived as above. Notice that firm 3 will not deviate by reducing its price to al to generate a profit 3(al); since 3(al) is less than 2a (since lBaB2l): 12. The second-order condition will be p??(x)(2ag)B0:

13. CTI TV, originally named Chuan Hsun TV, was founded by Hong Kong businessman Ping Hai Yu, and later taken over by the Hsiang Shan group. The China Times is the third owner.

Notes on contributors

Shirley J. Ho is associate professor at the Department of Economics, National Chengchi University. Her research interests cover all topics in microeconomics and industrial organization.

Mine Ping Sun is associate professor at the Department of the Journalism, College of Communication, National Chengchi University in Taiwan. Her research interests cover the areas of media studies, newspaper industry of Taiwan and Malaysia, information commu-nication technology and family, media use of adolescents, and community commucommu-nication. Her works on the ICT and family, media and newspapers industry in Taiwan have appeared in Journal of Mass Communication Research (in Chinese), Journal of Radio and Television Studies (in Chinese), Chinese Journal of Communication Research, and Asian Journal of Communica-tion.

(17)

Downloaded By: [Shih Hsin University] At: 01:01 9 May 2008

References

Baumol, W.J., Panzar, J.C., & Willig, R.D. (1982). Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

Chen, P., & Cheng, L. (2003). The relationship between market structure and performance in Taiwan’s television industry. Mass Communication Research, 75, 3771 (in Chinese). Christensen, C.M., & Raynor, M.E. (2003). The innovator’s solution: Creating and sustaining

successful growth. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

Denton, F. (1993). Old newspapers and new reality: The promise of the marketing of journalism. In F. Denton (Ed.), Reinventing the newspaper (pp. 158). New York: Twentieth Century Fund Press.

Gabszewicz, J., Laussel, D., & Sonnac, N. (2001). Press advertising and the ascent of the ‘pense´e unique’? European Economic Review, 45(46), 645651.

Judd, K. (1985). Credible spatial preemption. Rand Journal of Economics, 16, 153166. Kurtz, H. (1993). Yesterday’s news: Why newspapers are losing their franchise. In F. Denton

(Ed.), Reinventing the newspaper (pp. 158). New York: Twentieth Century Fund Press. Li, C., & Mai, P. (2003). The impact of the Apple Daily News on three traditional newspapers

in Taiwan: A niche analysis (in Chinese). Globalization and News Reporting Symposium, Graduate School of Journalism, National Taiwan University, Taipei, November 2930. Liao, I. (2005). Tremendous changes in the territory of newspapers: The lonely prince, Albert

Yu. Business Today, 452, 4851 (in Chinese).

Next Media Limited Corporation. (2007). 2006/07 financial report of Next Media. Retrieved March 14, 2007, from http://hk.biz.yahoo.com/p/hk/prospect/index.html?s 0282 (in Chinese).

Nielsen Media Research. (2006, December). Nielsen media index. Taipei: The Nielsen Company.

Nielsen Media Research. (2007, June). Nielsen media index. Taipei: The Nielsen Company. Selten, R. (1975). Re-examination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in

extensive games. International Journal of Game Theory, 4, 2555.

Shy, O. (1996). Industrial organization: Theory and applications. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. So, C.Y.K. (1997). The complete market-driven journalism: A case study of Apple Daily News of Hong Kong. In T. Chen, L. Chu, & C. Peng (Eds.) Mass communication and market economy (pp. 215233). Hong Kong: Lu-fong Association (in Chinese).

Sun, M. (2005). The impact of the Apple Daily News on Taiwan’s mainstream newspapers (in Chinese). In J. Feng (Ed.), Retrospect: The 70th anniversary of the department of journalism (pp. 244252). Taipei: Department of Journalism, National Chengchi University.

The Min Sheng Daily ceases today with a honorable period. (2006, November 30). United Daily News, p. A5.

The Min Sheng Daily with a history of 28 years, ceased today. (2006, November 30). Apple Daily, p. A2. (in Chinese).

Tsai, C. (2005). Stylish chameleon: An exploratory examination of the Apple Daily in Taiwan. MA dissertation, National Taipei University (in Chinese).

Young, S. (2006). Taiwan’s media industry in the past decade: A viewpoint from capital loss. Contemporary, 228, 3645 (in Chinese).

(18)

表 Y04

98 年 8 月 10 日

報告人姓名

何靜嫺

服務機構

及職稱

國立政治大學經濟學系

時間

會議

地點

August 2nd – August 9st

2009,

Tokyo and Singapre

本會核定

補助文號

NSC 97-2410-H-004 -060

會議

名稱

1. (中文) 2009 年遠東及南亞經濟計量協會年會

(英文) 2009 Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometric Sciety,

2. (中文) 2009 年新加坡經濟評論會議

(英文) Singapore Economic Review Conference 2009

發表

論文

題目

(中文) 銀行產業下的資本結構與市場競爭:理論與實證

(英文) Capital Structure and Competition in the Banking Industry: Theory

and Empirics,

(19)

表 Y04

一、參加會議經過

8/2 自 台 北 出 發 , 參 加 東 京 2009 Far East and South Asia Meeting of the

Econometric Society 的報告。東京大學不愧為第一學府, 舉辦這種大型學術

研討會之經驗豐富, 所有行程緊湊, 且各科分類程度正好,同一場報告者也

有良好的經驗交換。

由 於 8/5 日 剛 結 束 東 京 , 8/6 日一早由台灣到新加坡時已經錯過開幕講

題。由於大會是在 Stamford Hotel 舉行, 當我們正在繞來繞去的大廳中找下

午第一場 talk 時, 我飄見我在英國熟識的一位同學(目前任教伯明罕大學經

濟系)正在招手跟我打招呼,從這開始三天有趣且內容豐富的會議。

二、與會心得

東京的會議在每天會議中穿插如 Roger Myerson 等國際知名大師演講, 行程

緊湊, 且分類細密. 且由於大會是在校園裡舉辦, 在小節中可以到校園逛

逛,相較於新加坡把會議場所拉到市中心的大飯店舉辦,感覺親切許多。

大飯店的會議型態比較像一般商業會議, 對一般的學術界人士好像不太適

合。

三、建議

大型會議的通病是小組行動,熟的朋友更熟. 如何以團體活動的方式,讓大家

在極短期內能夠熱絡,是成功的要素.

四、攜回資料名稱及內容

東京部分:

1. conference 各篇文章摘要

2. 東京之展覽簡介

新加坡部分:

所 有 議 程 及 文 章 全 文 , 主 辦 單 位 都 將 之 公 布 於 下 列 網 頁 中 ;

http://editorialexpress.com/conference/serc2009/program/serc2009.html

五、其他

新加坡大部分費用由政治大學研發處補助不足處。

本次發表論文屬於 97 年度計畫之 extension 部分。

數據

表 Y04                                                               98 年 8 月 10 日 報告人姓名 何靜嫺 服務機構及職稱 國立政治大學經濟學系      時間 會議      地點 August 2nd – August 9st 2009,

參考文獻

相關文件

Murphy.Woodward.Stoltzfus.. 17) The pressure exerted by a column of liquid is equal to the product of the height of the column times the gravitational constant times the density of

 Promote project learning, mathematical modeling, and problem-based learning to strengthen the ability to integrate and apply knowledge and skills, and make. calculated

• Introduction of language arts elements into the junior forms in preparation for LA electives.. Curriculum design for

◦ The Statue of Liberty is a gift that France presented to America to celebrate its one hundred years of independence from the United Kingdom.. The full height of the monument is

Using this formalism we derive an exact differential equation for the partition function of two-dimensional gravity as a function of the string coupling constant that governs the

Courtesy: Ned Wright’s Cosmology Page Burles, Nolette &amp; Turner, 1999?. Total Mass Density

This kind of algorithm has also been a powerful tool for solving many other optimization problems, including symmetric cone complementarity problems [15, 16, 20–22], symmetric

Two cross pieces at bottom of the stand to make a firm base with stays fixed diagonally to posts. Sliding metal buckles for adjustment of height. Measures accumulated split times.