• 沒有找到結果。

租賃契約,銀行借款,與債券融通

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "租賃契約,銀行借款,與債券融通"

Copied!
12
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

行政院國家科學委員會專題研究計畫 成果報告

租賃契約,銀行借款,與債券融通

研究成果報告(精簡版)

計 畫 類 別 : 個別型 計 畫 編 號 : NSC 95-2415-H-002-013- 執 行 期 間 : 95 年 08 月 01 日至 96 年 07 月 31 日 執 行 單 位 : 國立臺灣大學經濟學系暨研究所 計 畫 主 持 人 : 陳南光 計畫參與人員: 博士班研究生-兼任助理:鄭宜玲 處 理 方 式 : 本計畫可公開查詢

中 華 民 國 96 年 10 月 30 日

(2)

行政院國家科學委員會補助專題研究計畫

V 成 果 報 告

□期中進度報告

租賃契約,銀行借款與債券融通

計畫類別:V 個別型計畫 □ 整合型計畫

計畫編號:NSC

95-2415-H-002-013-執行期間: 95 年 8 月 1 日至 96 年 7 月 31 日

計畫主持人:

陳南光

共同主持人:

計畫參與人員:

成果報告類型(依經費核定清單規定繳交):V 精簡報告 □完整報告

本成果報告包括以下應繳交之附件:

□赴國外出差或研習心得報告一份

□赴大陸地區出差或研習心得報告一份

□出席國際學術會議心得報告及發表之論文各一份

□國際合作研究計畫國外研究報告書一份

處理方式:除產學合作研究計畫、提升產業技術及人才培育研究計畫、

列管計畫及下列情形者外,得立即公開查詢

□涉及專利或其他智慧財產權,□一年□二年後可公開查詢

執行單位:

國立臺灣大學經濟學系暨研究所

(3)

1

Introduction

Brounen and Eichholtz (2005) survey a large number of corporations across different countries and find that the overall real estate ownership appears to be decreasing over time, due to the gaining popularity of lease alternative. Leasing has the advantage that a lessor is able to repossess control of an asset easier than for a secured lender, which relaxes the credit constraints of borrowers. However, leasing is subject to agency problem due to a separation of ownership and control. On the other hand, the sources of financing for investing in capital equipment, whether leasing or buying, have been the focus of studies in corporate finance (Meyers and Majluf (1984), Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1994), Boot and Thakor (1997), Repullo and Suarez (2000), and Bolton and Freixas (2000, 2004)).

The purpose of this paper is to bring together these two strands of literature and In the model, firms determine whether to lease or buy capital and then acquire external finance from bank lending or securities issues. We study whether there is a connection between the choice of leasing/buying capital and the financing structure of firms, and how the fluctuations of asset prices play a role in affecting the firms’ tenure choice as well as the financing structure.

When a firm plans to make an investment for production, it can raise funds to purchase capital either from bank financing or bond issues; alternatively it can simply lease capital. Eisfeldt and Rampini (2005) argue that there are several advantages for firms to lease rather than to buy the capital. First, according to the U.S. bankruptcy code (Chapter 11), it is much easier for a lessor to repossess control of an asset than it is for a secured lender to repossess it; and second, this makes the debt capacity of a firm that leases its capital exceeds the debt capacity of a firm that purchases an asset and then collateralizes it for bank loans. On the other hand, however, leasing is subject to agency problem due to a separation of ownership and control. Evidence shows that small and medium firms opt for leasing more than large firms because leasing relaxes the credit constraint of small and medium firms.

Next, when seeking for external financing, a firm can choose either bank financing or securities issues. The importance of bank loans for certain bank-dependent firms have been studied extensively in the literature (e.g., Kashyap et al. (1993), Bernanke and

(4)

Gertler (1995)). However, the development of financial markets has prompted research on the interactions of bank financing and securities issues, which provides a rationale for firms to use mixed finance on bank loans and bonds. The main difference between bank and bond financing is that debt restructuring is not possible due to wide dispersion of ownership of corporate bonds (Bolton and Scharfstein (1996)), however, financial interme-diation is costly. Recent empirical evidence also demonstrate that there is a substitution effect between bank credit and securities issues following a change in monetary policy (e.g., Kashyap et al. (1993), Gertler and Gilchrist (1994)). In this project we add another twist on the interactions of bank lending and bond financing by considering the tenure choice of buying/leasing assets by firms and also fluctuations of asset value. This leads to the third element of our model: collateral is recognized in recent studies as a pri-marily important factor in determining external financing and investment (Kiyotaki and Moor (1997), Chen (2001), Iacoviello (2005)). Thus, when bank loans are collateralized, fluctuations of the value of collateralized assets affect the firm’s ability to obtain external financing, thus magnifying business fluctuations through this “collateral channel.”

How does the choice of tenure affect firms’ credit constraints, investments, and cap-ital structure? When buying capcap-ital, an entrepreneur seeks for external finance (either borrowing from banks or issuing bonds) while contributing his own capital. Apparently, the choice of leasing/buying will affect the amount of liquid asset that the entrepreneur can hold on hand and thus the entrepreneur’s expected net worth (due to fluctuations of asset prices). The entrepreneur’s net worth position then affects his choice of financing structure. Some evidence show that real estate ownership and a firm’s stock returns are related negatively (Liow (2004)). Brounen and Eichholtz (2005) find the same pattern, however, after controlling for the variation in risks no significant return patterns remain. Thus, it is not justifiable why firms would like to buy real estate if their sole objective is to maximize their stock returns. Furthermore, some find that real estate leasing raises stock returns (e.g., Allen et al. (1993)). We will investigate whether and under what conditions the (ex post) returns of the initial investment are higher for firms which buy rather than lease real estate capital.

We find that the decisions of tenure choice and the capital structure of a firm depend on the interactions of agency costs and the fluctuations of asset prices. When the risk in the

(5)

resale value of capital increases, the tenure choice of fixed capital leads to a substitution effect between bank loans and securities. Furthermore, when the moral hazard problem worsens and thus raises agency costs, the credit constraints affect capital structure and leads to a shift in leasing/buying choices. Our model thus characterizes a wider spectrum of firms’ financing decisions under credit constraints.

2

Relation to the Literature

The literature on leasing mostly focuses on the tax-incentives for leasing (e.g., Miller and Upton (1976)). The benefit of repossession were informally discussed by Smith and Wakeman (1985), Krishnan and Moyer (1994), and Sharpe and Nguyen (1995). Krishnan and Moyer (1994) and Sharpe and Nguyen (1995) provide evidence that credit-constrained firms lease more. Krishnan and Moyer (1994) provide evidence that leasing has lower expected bankruptcy costs to the lessor than borrowing has to the lender, resulting in lower financing costs for the lessee than the borrower, ceteris paribus. The results indicate that lease financing is an attractive financing option for those firms with higher bankruptcy potentials. Similarly, Sharpe and Nguyen (1995) find evidence that firms facing high information-cost premiums for external funds finance a significantly greater proportion of their balance sheet fixed assets with leases. Eisfeldt and Rampini (2005) argue that the debt capacity of a firm that leases its capital exceeds the debt capacity of a firm that purchases an asset and then collateralizes it for bank loans. This makes leasing valuable to credit constrained firms. However, leasing is subject to agency problem due to a separation of ownership and control (the financier retains the ownership). They find that the benefit of leasing outweighs the cost for credit-constrained firms and thus these firms prefer leasing capital. For less credit-constrained firms, the ownership of capital minimizes the agency cost and it is thus better for them to purchase capital. Their results are confirmed by the U.S. micro data.

The project is also related to a recent theoretical literature concerned with the co-existence of bank lending and bond financing, notably, Besanko and Kanatas (1993), Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1994), Boot and Thakor (1997), Holmstrom and Tirole (1997),

(6)

and Repullo and Suarez (2000), and Bolton and Freixas (2000, 2004).1 Diamond (1991) examines the interactions between reputational capital (a good track record) and monitor-ing, and find that the typical bank borrowers will be the entrepreneurs with intermediate credit ratings. Holmstrom and Tirole (1997) examine the role of net worth in financial structure when both entrepreneurs and banks are subject to moral hazard problems vis-a‘-vis their respective lenders. They demonstrate that smaller firms have to rely on bank financing because their own net worth at stake is so small that they have an incentive to commit moral hazard by opting for bad projects (which give entrepreneurs some private benefits but have a lower probability of success). While larger firms with abundant own capital provides them an incentive to choose good projects and they are able to obtain investors’ direct financing without being monitored. Repullo and Suarez (2000) use a model of entrepreneurs’ financing choices to analyze the two strands of the credit view — balance sheet channel and bank lending channel. Bank finance involves a higher moni-toring intensity than market finance, which ameliorates the entrepreneurial moral hazard problem. They show that in equilibrium the set of firms can be divided according to the value of their net worth ratio (the ratio of their internal funds to the investment required by their projects) into three groups. Firms with large net worth prefer market financing, firms with intermediate net worth get bank lending, and firms with little net worth are unable to obtain credit.

Bolton and Freixas (2000) build a model of financial markets and corporate finance with asymmetric information, in which firms endogenously determine their financial struc-ture. They borrows from Hart and Moore (1995) that bank debt is more easily renegoti-ated than a dispersed bond (Lummer and McConnell (1989), Gilson et al. (1990)), and from Diamond (1994) that even though bank loans are easier to restructure, there exists intermediation costs. A main feature of this paper is that equity issues, bank debt, and 1This may be considered to be a distinct subset of research of the literature on capital structure.

In general, Meyers and Majluf (1984) proclaim that there exists a pecking order on corporate external financing, with bank loans first, bonds the next, and equities as the last resort. The idea is that firms raising equities bear informational dilution cost when there is asymmetric information between firms and investors (Calomiris and Wilson (1998)). Here we abstract from equities issues. See below for the justifications.

(7)

bond financing co-exist in equilibrium. They find that in equilibrium the financing struc-ture of firms are segmented into three categories: (i) the riskiest firms (e.g., start-ups) are either unable to obtain funding or constrained to issue equity; (ii) the safest firms finance from securities markets and thus avoid paying the intermediation cost; and (iii) the ones in between take out bank loans.

Finally, recent studies have demonstrated the importance of collateral channel in ex-plaining the dynamics of macroeconomic aggregates through the interaction of credit con-straints and the value of collateralized assets (Kiyotaki and Moor (1997), Chen (2001), Iacoviello (2005)). Furthermore, collateralization of loans may also distort the investment decision of firms and/or loan renewal decision of banks (Allen and Gale (2000), Lorenzoni (2005)). Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) investigate exogenous shocks’ transmission mecha-nism of collateral channel through the interaction of credit constraints and the value of collateralized assets. Fluctuations in asset prices change the value of the collateral and af-fect the firm’s ability to obtain external financing, thus magnifying business fluctuations. Chen (2001) extends the connection of collateral value and bank loans by taking banks’ financial characteristics into consideration, emphasizing the role of banks in affecting the amount of collateral-secured loans. Their models hence provide a theoretical link between fluctuations of collateral value, firms’ credit constraint, and the capacity of bank lending. Iacoviello (2005) contributes to the literature on financial frictions and the macroecon-omy by tying housing values to collateral constraints on both the firm and the household side. He shows that the collateral effects allow the model to match some key aggregate time-series data. Lorenzoni (2005)) considers a model with endogenous asset prices and fire sales to study the effect of asset price movements on the entrepreneurs balance sheet and on the feedback between net worth and asset prices. He first demonstrates that the economic environment may lead to excessive borrowing and over-investment. During a fire sale, the “asset price channel” implies that a decline in asset prices exerts a negative effect on entrepreneurs balance sheet. This pecuniary externality arising from fire sales can be reduced if entrepreneurs commit to reduce initial borrowing and investment.

(8)

3

The Model

To study the interactions of the choice of leasing/buying capital, the firms’ credit con-straints, and financing structure, we consider a model where entrepreneurs choose between buying capital and leasing capital, and at the same time choose between bank financing and bond financing. The equilibrium interest rates of bank lending and bond issue will be determined in equilibrium. We modify the model by Bolton and Freixas (2000, 2004) to incorporate the above-mentioned features.

Consider a three period model, t = 0, 1, and 2. There are three type so agents: entrepreneurs, intermediaries, and lessors, each with population one. The agents consume only at date 2. There are two types of goods: consumption goods and a productive asset. The technology uses only the asset as an input, y = f (k). Each entrepreneur is endowed with w units of goods. The asset market opens at time 0 and 1. We denote q0 and q1 as

the date 0 and 1 prices of capital respectively.

When capital is leased, the entrepreneur leases kl units of capital and pays a rental

rate ul up-front. At date 2 the depreciated capital is returned to the lessor. Since leasing

involves a separation of ownership and control, which is costly due to agency problems. We thus assume that the depreciation rate under lease δl is larger than that under buying,

δl > δ (Alchian and Demsetz (1972). When the entrepreneur buys the capital at date 0,

the entrepreneur can raise funds either from banks or bond issue.

If the entrepreneur chooses to borrow from a bank, he can at most borrow a fraction of the resale value of his capital,

Rb≤ φ (1 − δ) E (q1) k0

where b is the amount of funds raised, k0 is the amount of capital invested by buying

capital, δ is the depreciation rate of owned capital, and R is the gross rate of interest. Financial intermediation is more costly than bond issues. If the investment is financed by issuing securities, the bond issue specifies a repayment schedule RB. We distinguish

bank credit from bond financing by assuming that bank credit is easier to restructure than bond financing. We will specify the details later.

Lessors are credit unconstrained agents who own and lease capital. We assume that leased capital is more easily repossessed by the lessor. The lessors are competitive so that

(9)

their expected profits are zero. Taking the time 0 capital price, expected resale value of capital, rental rate of leasing as given, the lessors determine the amount of capital leased to the entrepreneur

max ulkl− q0kl+ (1− δl) E (q1) kl/R

where ul is rental rate of capital, kl is the amount of capital to the lessee, and δl is the

depreciation rate of leased capital. The first order condition is given by

ul= q0−

(1− δl) E (q1)

R .

We then specify the maximization problems of entrepreneurs and banks later, and solve the problem backwards: given date 0 decisions, banks decide whether to restructure the bank debt or not at date 1, and then return to the date 0 decisions.

4

Reference

Alchian, Armen, and Harold Demsetz (1972), “Production, Information Costs, and Eco-nomic Organization,” American EcoEco-nomic Review, 62, 777- 795.

Allen, Marcus T., Ronald C. Rutherford, and Thomas M. Springer (1993), “The Wealth Effects of Corporate Real Estate Leasing,” Journal of Real Estate Research, 8(4), 567-578.

Bernanke, Ben and M. Gertler (1995), “Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 27-48.

Besanko, David, and George Kanatas (1993), “Credit Market Equilibrium with Bank Monitoring and Moral Hazard,” Review Financial Studies, 6(1), 213—32.

Bolton, Patrick and Xavier Freixas (2004), “Corporate Finance and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism,” Review of Financial Studies, Forthcoming.

Bolton, Patrick and Xavier Freixas (2000), “Equity, Bonds and Bank Debt: Capital Structure and Financial Market Equilibrium under Asymmetric Information,” Journal of Political Economy, 108(2), 324-51.

(10)

Bolton, Patrick, and David S. Scharfstein (1996), “Optimal Debt Structure and The Number of Creditors,” Journal of Political Economy, 104, 1-25.

Boot, Arnoud W. A., and Anjan V. Thakor, (1997), “Financial System Architecture,” Review of Financial Studies, 10, 693—733.

Brounen, Dirk and Piet M.A. Eichholtz (2005), “Corporate Real Estate Ownership Implications: International Performance Evidence,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 30(4), 429-445.

Calomiris, Charles W. and Berry Wilson (1998), “Bank Capital and Portfolio Man-agement: The 1930’s Capital Crunch and Scramble to Shed Risk,” working Paper no. 6649.

Chemmanur, Thomas J., and Paolo Fulghieri (1994), “Reputation, Renegotiation, and the Choice between Bank Loans and Publicly Traded Debt,” Review of Financial Studies, 7, 475—506.

Chen, Nan-Kuang (2001), “Bank Net Worth, Asset Prices and Economic Activity,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 48(2), 415-436.

Diamond, D. (1991), “Monitoring and Reputation: The Choice between Bank Loans and Directly Placed Debt,” Journal of Political Economy, 99, 689-721.

Eisfeldt, Andrea L. and Adriano A. Rampini (2005), “Leasing, Ability to Repossess, and Debt Capacity,” manuscript.

Gertler, Mark and Simon Gilchrist (1994), “Monetary Policy, Business Cycles and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 309-340. Gilson, Stuart C., John Kose, and Larry H. P. Lang (1990), “Troubled Debt Restruc-turing: An Empirical Study of Private Reorganization of Firms in Default,” Journal of Financial Economics, 27, 315—53.

Hendel, Igal and Alessandro Lizzeri (2002), “The Role of Leasing under Adverse Se-lection,” Journal of Political Economy, 110(1), 113-143.

Holmstrom, Bengt, and Jean Tirole (1997), “Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 663—91.

Iacoviello, Matteo (2005), “House prices, Borrowing Constraints and Monetary policy in the Business Cycle,” American Economic Review, 95(3), 739-764.

(11)

Credit Conditions: Evidence from the Composition of External Finance,” American Eco-nomic Review, 78-98.

Kiyotaki N. and J. Moor (1997), “Credit Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211-48.

Krishnan, V. Sivarama, and R. Charles Moyer (1994), “Bankruptcy Costs and the Financial Leasing Decision,” Financial Management, 23 (2), 31-42.

Liow, Kim Hiang (2004), “Corporate Real Estate and Stock Market Performance,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29(1), 119-140

Lummer, Scott L. and John J. McConnell (1989), “Further Evidence on the Bank Lending Process and the Capital-Market Response to Bank Loan Agreements,” Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 99—122.

Meziane Lasfer (2005), “Why do Companies Lease their Real Estate Assets?” manu-script.

Miller, Merton, and Charles Upton (1976), “Leasing, Buying, and the Cost of Capital Services,” Journal of Finance, 31, 761-786.

Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf (1984), “Corporate Financing and Invest-ment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187—221.

Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan (1994), “The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data,” Journal of Finance, 49, 3—37.

Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan (1995), “The Effect of Credit Market Competition on Lending Relationships,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 407—43.

Repullo, Rafael, and Javier Suarez (2000), “Entrepreneurial Moral Hazard and Bank Monitoring: A Model of the Credit Channel,” European Economic Review, 44, 1931-1950. Sharpe, Steven A., and Hien H. Nguyen (1995), “Capital Market imperfections and the Incentive to Lease,” Journal of Financial Economics, 39, 271-294.

Smith, Clifford W., Jr., and MacDonald L. Wakeman (1985), “Determinants of Cor-porate Leasing Policy,” Journal of Finance, 40, 895-908.

(12)

5

Main Findings and Assessments

We have the followning preliminary findings. We find that the decisions of tenure choice and the capital structure of a firm depend on the interactions of agency costs and the fluc-tuations of asset prices. When the risk in the resale value of capital increases, the tenure choice of fixed capital leads to a substitution effect between bank loans and securities. Furthermore, when the moral hazard problem worsens and thus raises agency costs, the credit constraints affect capital structure and leads to a shift in leasing/buying choices. Our model thus characterizes a wider spectrum of firms’ financing decisions under credit constraints.

In this paper, we concentrate on the land (real estate) as the sole capital. This is because liquidity of the resale market of capital depends on the specificity of that capital.2 In order to focus on the role of fluctuations of asset prices played in determining

the interaction of leasing/buying decision and corporate financing structure, we focus on the type of capital that has a well-developed resale market and has a easily discernible market value, that is, land or real estate, which serves as both collateral and production input.

Furthermore, we abstract from several aspects which are common in the literature of corporate finance. In particular, we omit the role of equities in the model. One justification is that evidence shows that the pecking order appears to break down for risky start-up firms, for these firms equity financing is the only option available (Petersen and Rajan (1994, 1995)). Bolton and Freixas (2000) show that adding equities allows the model to explain why the pecking order breaks down in the start-up firms. Therefore, we exclude the financing choice of issuing equity for the current project. Here our focus is on how the potential fluctuations of asset prices affect the choice of leasing/buying as well as financial structure. We will leave the choice of equities for future research. We will need to provide some more results and polish the manuscript before submitting to a journal.

2Krishnan and Moyer (1994) find that leasing is significantly less used for external financing for firms

in manufacturing industries, where asset specificity is greater, than for firms in most other major industry groupings.

參考文獻

相關文件

• One technique for determining empirical formulas in the laboratory is combustion analysis, commonly used for compounds containing principally carbon and

You are given the wavelength and total energy of a light pulse and asked to find the number of photons it

substance) is matter that has distinct properties and a composition that does not vary from sample

The Secondary Education Curriculum Guide (SECG) is prepared by the Curriculum Development Council (CDC) to advise secondary schools on how to sustain the Learning to

- Informants: Principal, Vice-principals, curriculum leaders, English teachers, content subject teachers, students, parents.. - 12 cases could be categorised into 3 types, based

Wang, Solving pseudomonotone variational inequalities and pseudocon- vex optimization problems using the projection neural network, IEEE Transactions on Neural Networks 17

volume suppressed mass: (TeV) 2 /M P ∼ 10 −4 eV → mm range can be experimentally tested for any number of extra dimensions - Light U(1) gauge bosons: no derivative couplings. =>

◆ Understand the time evolutions of the matrix model to reveal the time evolution of string/gravity. ◆ Study the GGE and consider the application to string and