• 沒有找到結果。

3 Proposed Model

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "3 Proposed Model"

Copied!
7
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Contract Bridge Bidding by Learning

Chun-Yen Ho and Hsuan-Tien Lin

Department of Computer Science & Information Engineering, National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan r01922014@ntu.edu.tw, htlin@csie.ntu.edu.tw

Abstract

Contract bridge is an example of an incomplete information game for which computers typically do not perform better than expert human bridge players. In particular, the typi- cal bidding decisions of human bridge players are difficult to mimic with a computer program, and thus automatic bridge bidding remains to be a challenging research problem. Cur- rently, the possibility of automatic bidding without mimick- ing human players has not been fully studied. In this work, we take an initiative to study such a possibility for the specific problem of bidding without competition. We propose a novel learning framework to let a computer program learn its own bidding decisions. The framework transforms the bidding problem into a learning problem, and then solves the problem with a carefully designed model that consists of cost-sensitive classifiers and upper-confidence-bound algorithms. We vali- date the proposed model and find that it performs competi- tively to the champion computer bridge program that mimics human bidding decisions.

1 Introduction

Game-playing is a rich field for artificial intelligence (AI) research. The vast majority of research has focused on full information games such as chess and Othello. On the other hand, a more challenging class of incomplete information games such as poker and bridge continues to be of research interests (Sandholm 2010). A popular research direction is to exploit machine learning to analyze data in an effort to find better game-playing strategies (Bowling et al. 2006;

Ponsen et al. 2008; Te´ofilo et al. 2012).

Contract bridge, or simply bridge, is an incomplete in- formation game that is played with a standard 52-card deck.

The game requires four players, commonly referred to as North, East, West, and South. Players compete on two op- posing teams, North-South and East-West, with the objec- tive of earning the highest score in a zero-sum scenario.

A bridge game consists of several deals, each compris- ing two stages—the bidding stage and the playing stage.

At the beginning of each deal, each player is dealt 13 ran- dom cards. In the bidding stage, the two teams engage in an auction in an attempt to find the most profitable con- tract for the playing stage. During the auction, each player Copyright c 2015, Association for the Advancement of Artificial Intelligence (www.aaai.org). All rights reserved.

can only see their own 13 cards and not those of the other players including their teammate. The auction proceeds around the table, with each player deciding to PASSor to increase the value of the bid from an ordered set of calls {1♣, 1♦, 1♥, 1♠, 1NT, 2♣, · · · , 7NT} or by a more sophis- ticated call, such as doubling the current bid. The auction proceeds until it is terminated by three consecutive PASS

calls, at which time the final bid becomes the contract of the deal. The contract consists of a number and a symbol. The symbol indicates the trump suit and the number indicates the number of rounds that the auction-winning team expects to win during the ensuing playing stage.

The player from the auction-winning team who first called the trump suit becomes the declarer. The playing stage com- prises 13 rounds of a card-strength competition. During the playing stage, the auction-winning team attempts to make the contract, while the auction-losing team aims block the opponent team from making the contract. Ultimately, the scores of the teams are determined by comparing the con- tract with the actual number of winning rounds.

The bidding stage is often regarded as being more diffi- cult to implement than the playing stage. For example, in 1998, the GIB program (Ginsberg 2001) attained 12thplace among 35 human experts in a contest without bidding (Gins- berg 1999). This demonstrates that computer bridge play- ers can compete against expert human players in the playing stage. On the other hand, nearly all the computer bridge programs that are currently available borrow human bidding systems, which contain human-designed rules for commu- nicating information between teammates. Traditional bridge AIs have attempted to convert these rules into computer pro- grams. However, human-designed rules often contain ambi- guities and even conflicts, which complicate the task of pro- gramming a bidding system. In addition, using only human- designed rules limits the capability of the machines.

There have been several successful efforts to improve the bidding AI. For example, a reasoning model for making de- cisions with a rule-based bidding system has been proposed in (Ando and Uehara 2001). By first constructing a deci- sion network from a bidding system, Amit and Markovitch (2006) propose a Monte Carlo Sampling approach to deci- sion making in the presence of conflicting bids. Further, the authors propose a decision tree based learning method for resolving conflicts. In the work of DeLooze and Downey

(2)

(2007), a learning method based on self-organizing maps is proposed for the problem of learning a human bidding sys- tem from examples, rather than from explicit statement of the rules. However, each of the previous work is based on a bidding system that is pre-designed by human experts.

In this work, we consider a different way for improving the bidding AI. We take an initiative to study the possibil- ity that the machines can learn to bid without relying on a human-designed bidding system. In particular, we intend to lay out approaches for the machines to “learn their own bid- ding system” from raw data that contain only random deals.

Our study not only opens a new route for improving the bid- ding AI, but also examines whether a machine-learned bid- ding system can be competitive to a human-designed one.

The incomplete information properties of the bidding stage make this a difficult task. Because each player can see only her/his 13 cards, it is difficult for the player to infer the best contract for the team directly. Thus, the bidding stage itself is usually considered a channel for players to exchange information. However, because the auction follows the rule of using monotonically increasing bids, players must avoid exceeding the optimal contract when exchanging informa- tion. Moreover, each team could interfere with the other’s ability to exchange information. Together, these properties render the design of machine learning approaches for auto- matic bidding a difficult task.

In this paper, we propose a novel framework for ap- plying machine learning approaches to the task of auto- matic bridge bidding without competition. We transform the bidding rules to a formal learning problem along with corresponding scalable data generation steps in Section 2.

Next, in Section 3 we evaluate the potential of machine learning approaches by designing several baseline meth- ods and analyzing the key challenge of solving the prob- lem using machine learning. Then, we propose an inno- vative learning model with layers of cost-sensitive classi- fiers and upper-confidence-bound algorithms for solving the problem. We empirically demonstrate in Section 4 that the performance of the model is competitive to the contempo- rary champion-winning computer bridge software that im- plements a human-designed bidding system.

2 Problem Setup

We first separate the general bidding problem into two sub- problems: bidding with competition, and bidding without competition. Both problems cover considerable amounts of deals in real-world bridge games. For the first initiative toward allowing the machine to learn its own bidding sys- tem automatically, we use settings similar to existing works (Amit and Markovitch 2006; DeLooze and Downey 2007), and study the sub-problem of bidding without competition.

The sub-problem can be formalized as follows. We use x to denote the cards of a player, and a length-` sequence b to denote the bids of that player and the bids of her/his teammate. Each component of b is within an ordered set B = {PASS, 1♣, 1♦, · · · , 7NT}, where b[1] is the first bid made by the team, b[2] is the second bid, etc.. For simplic- ity, we can further assume that the team that is bidding sits at

the North-South positions, and by bidding without competi- tion, the opponent team sitting at the East-West always calls

PASS. The goal is to learn a bidding strategy G(xn, xs) for predicting b given the cards xnof the North player and xs

of the South player.

To meet the rules of bridge bidding, we further de- compose G as follows. Let g(x, bk) 7→ B be the bid- ding function used for predicting bids in the bidding strat- egy G, where bk denotes the bidding sequence until the kth bid. Then for every b = G(xn, xs), we require b[1] = g(x1, ∅), b[2] = g(x2, b1), · · · , b[`] = g(x`, b`−1), such that g(x`+1, b) = PASS, and b[1] < b[2] < · · · < b[`].

The monotonicity constraint makes b[k] 6=PASSfor k > 1.

Note that the x used in g(x, bk) for consecutive bids need to originate from different players. Without loss of generality, we assume that x1= xn: the first player is always the North player.

To learn a good strategy G (or a good g within), we need to provide related data to the learning algorithm. The input (feature) part of the data is easy to generate, because all the relevant information can be obtained from the cards of the players in a deal. The (xn, xs) can then carry some rep- resentation of the cards, and some feature expansion tech- niques can be applied also to achieve better performance.

How can we generate data that relates to the desired out- put? Note that b is not directly available when allowing the machine to learn its own bidding system. However, we can indirectly know the goodness of some b by taking b[`] to the playing stage and obtaining the resulting score. Never- theless, attempting to play each possible contract b[`] of a deal by either computer or human agents can be extremely time-consuming. To overcome this issue, we use the double dummy analysis (Chang 1996) to approximate the playing stage for evaluating the scores for each contract.

The double dummy analysis is a technique that computes the number of tricks taken by each team in the playing stage under perfect information and optimal playing strat- egy. Whereas the best game-playing strategy with only par- tial information might be different from that with perfect in- formation, there are several advantages for using the latter to approximate the former. First, the result is deterministic and independent from the bidding stage. Second, the analy- sis is fast. Applying the double dummy analysis for a deal requires only several minutes. Finally, the approximation is usually good. In real bridge games, the result of a deal is usually close to that of the double dummy analysis when players are sufficiently strong.

After the double dummy analysis, we not only obtain the score of the best contract, but also have the scores of all pos- sible contracts. We can store the differences between the best score and those scores as a cost vector c. Also note that during data generation, we can drop the cards of the East- West team after the double dummy analysis. Then, we can formally define our learning problem as a cost-sensitive, se- quence prediction problem with specialized constraints from bridge bidding rules. Given data D = {(xni, xsi, ci)}Ni=1, where N is the number of instances in the dataset, we want to learn the bidding strategy G(xn, xs) that minimizes the average cost of the predicted contracts (i.e., the final bid).

(3)

For this purpose, the objective function to be minimized in the training stage can be written asN1 PN

i=1ci[bi[`]], where bi= G(xni, xsi).

3 Proposed Model

Baseline and optimistic methods. First, we consider the bidding strategies G that only predict sequences b of length one. That is, we let g(xs, b1) = PASS. Thus, xs

is not needed, and all the constraints are trivially satis- fied. Then, the objective function is reduced to minimize

1 N

PN

i=1ci[bi[`]] given Dbase = {(xni, ci)}Ni=1, which is the standard formulation of the cost-sensitive classification (CSC) problem (Beygelzimer et al. 2005), with many ex- isting algorithms available (Zhou and Liu 2010; Tu and Lin 2010). Here, we consider two regression-based al- gorithms, cost-sensitive two-sided regression (CSTSR) and cost-sensitive one-sided regression (CSOSR) (Tu and Lin 2010), as our baseline methods because of their close con- nections to the model that we shall propose next. The latter is one of the state-of-the-art algorithms for CSC. Both algo- rithms use regression models to estimate the cost for each bid, and predict the bid with minimum estimated cost. The difference is that CSTSR considers the plain-vanilla squared regression objective function, whereas CSOSR considers a more sophisticated function.

The baseline methods hint a lower bound that can be reached by machine learning. How about an upper bound?

One possibility is to “cheatingly” reveal the full information to the learner, which simulates what is seen from the audi- ence. That is, we use Dcheat= {([xni, xsi], ci)}Ni=1to learn a CSC classifier. The performance of this classifier hints an upper bound that can be achieved by machine learning.

The multi-layer bandit model. Next, we use the bidding sequence for better information exchange and better perfor- mance. As a simple start, let us consider extending the base- line methods to produce sequences b of length two. That is, g(xn, ∅) = b[1], g(xs, b1) = b[2] and g(xn, b2) =PASS. We can obtain some insight by considering what two hu- man bridge players will do in this scenario. For simplic- ity, we refer to g(xn, ∅) as gn, and to g(xs, b1) as gs. Consider two human players who are unfamiliar with each other’s bidding strategy and decide to practice together. Af- ter the North player uses his strategy gnto make the first bid b[1] = gn(xn, ∅), the South player has no choice but to use gson xsand the given b[1] to make the final bid b[2]. Then, after the score c of the contract is revealed, the South player can now improve her strategy gswith ((xs, b[1]), b[2], c).

The very same c indicates how good gn is in helping gs. Then, gncan improve his strategy with ((xn, ∅), b[1], c).

Nevertheless, if the North player is lousy and starts with a bad gn (for instance, some gn that always callsPASS), he might never know whether some alternative bids can help the South player better. This hints to the need for him to explore other possible bids, rather than sticking to his own strategy.

On the other hand, the North player should not make ex- haustive random predictions for exploration, because a uni- formly random b[1] gives the South player almost no in-

formation to further improve her strategy gs. That is, the North player should also use gnto exploit some “good” bids that are known to work well with gs. By balancing explo- ration (for improvement) and exploitation (for maintaining the team’s chemistry), the two players can build a better bid- ding system together.

Our proposed model hinges on two aspects of the discus- sions above. First, the cost of the final contract (i.e., the last bid) can be re-used to hint the cost of intermediate bid- ding decisions. Second, players need to explore other bid- ding choices while exploiting the known good bids. The two aspects lead us to consider the Upper Confidence Bound (UCB) algorithms in the contextual bandit problem.

The contextual bandit problem has recently become a popular research topic in machine learning (Li et al. 2010;

Chu et al. 2011; Langford and Zhang 2007). In this problem, we hope to earn the maximum total reward within some it- eration by strategically pulling a bandit machine from M given ones subject to a dynamic environment context within some iterations. Since there is no additional information available about the M given bandit machines in the be- ginning, balancing exploration (of other bandit machines) and exploitation (of knowingly good machines) is important.

The UCB algorithms (Chu et al. 2011) are some of the most popular contextual bandit algorithms. The algorithms clev- erly use the uncertainty term to achieve balance.

We can now pose an analogy of a player’s decision to the contextual bandit problem. The possible bids b[k + 1] corre- spond to the bandit machines, and the context corresponds to the cards x on hand and the earlier bids bk. The reward can simply be considered as the maximum possible cost minus the cost calculated from the final contract.

Whereas each player’s decision making can be modeled by the contextual bandit problem, recall that our goal is to obtain a bidding strategy G that produces a sequence of deci- sions that satisfy bridge rules. We propose to represent each player’s decision making with layers of “bidding nodes” V . With a careful design to structure these nodes, we can ensure that the bridge rules are all satisfied.

We define a bidding node V as a pair (b, g), where b ∈ B is called the bid label that V represents, and g is the bid- ding function subject to x and bk. We propose to structure the bidding nodes as a tree with ` + 1 layers, where the first layer of the tree contains a single root node with the first bidding function g(xn, ∅) and b = NIL indicating the en- tering of the bidding stage. At each V , g is only allowed to predictPASSor something higher than b to satisfy the bridge rules. Every prediction of its g connects V to a child bidding node V0at the next layer such that the prediction equals the bid label of V0. We restrict only the lowest M predictions of g to connect to non-terminal nodes to control the model complexity. Other nodes are designated as terminal nodes, which contain a constant g that always predicts PASS. In addition, all nodes at layer ` + 1 are terminal nodes.

Since we form the nodes as a tree, each unique path from the root to V readily represents a bidding sequence bk. Thus, the classifier g of V only needs to consider the cards x.

We call such a structure the tree model, as illustrated in Fig- ure 1(a). A variant of the tree model can be performed by

(4)

NIL

1♣

PASS

1♥

1♦

1♦

1♣ 1♠ 7NT

1♦ 7NT

1♦ 7NT 1♠ 7NT

· · ·

· · ·

· · · ·

(a) Tree model

NIL

1♣

PASS

1♥

1♦

1♣ 1♠ 7NT

1♦ 7NT

1♦ 7NT 1♠ 7NT

· · ·

· · ·

· · · ·

(b) Layered model

Figure 1: Tree model and layered model with ` = 3 and M = 2, the terminal nodes are not fully drawn

combining the non-terminal nodes that represent the same bid label in each layer. The combination allows the nodes to share their data to learn a better g. We call the variant the layered model, as illustrated in Figure 1(b).

Given the model above, a bidding strategy G can be formed by first inputting xn to g at the root node, follow- ing the prediction of g to another node that represents b[1]

in the next layer, then inputting xsto the node, and so on.

The process ends when aPASScall is predicted by some g of a non-root node.

After a particular model structure is decided, the remain- ing task becomes learning each g from data. We propose using CSTSR with ridge regression, which is among the baseline methods that we discussed earlier, as the learning algorithm, because it is a core part of the LinUCB algo- rithm that we adopt from the contextual bandit problem. Fol- lowing the notations that are commonly used in the contex- tual bandit problem, we consider the reward r, which is de- fined as the maximum possible cost minus the cost, instead of the cost c. For each possible bid bm, ridge regression with parameter λ > 0 is used to compute a weight vector wm= (XTmXm+ λI)−1(XTmrm) for estimating the poten- tial reward wTmx of making the bid, where rmcontains all the rewards gathered when the m-th bid bmis made by g, Xmcontains all the x associated with those rewards, and I is the identity matrix. During prediction, CSTSR predicts the bid associated with the maximum potential reward.

Our final task is to describe the learning algorithm for the

Algorithm 1 The Proposed Learning Algorithm

Input: Data, D = {(xni, xsi, ci)}Ni=1; a pre-defined model structure with all weights wmwithin all CSTSR ridge regression classifiers initialized to 0.

Output: A bidding strategy G based on the learned wm. 1: repeat

2: Randomly select a data instance (xni, xsi, ci) 3: Set V to the root node of the structure, and x to xni

4: UPDATE(V , xni, i) 5: until enough training iterations 6: procedure UPDATE(V , x, i)

7: For each possible bm, compute the UCB reward wTmx + α · uncertainty term

8: Select the bid bmwith the maximum UCB reward 9: if bm=PASSthen

10: Compute reward r from ciusing bm

11: else

12: Set x to the feature of the other player 13: Call r = UPDATE(V0, x, i)

14: end if

15: Update wmwith (x, r) 16: return r.

17: end procedure

model structure with ridge regression. As discussed, we use the cost of the final contract (i.e., the last bid) to form the rewards for intermediate bidding decisions. Then, we fol- low the UCB algorithms in the contextual bandit problem to update each node. The UCB algorithms assume an online learning scenario in which each x arrives one by one. First, we discuss the LinUCB algorithm (Chu et al. 2011) to bal- ance between exploration and exploitation. During the train- ing of each node, LinUCB selects the bid that maximizes wTmx + αpxT(XTmXm+ λI)−1x, where the first term is the potential reward on which CSTSR relies, and the second term represents the uncertainty of x with respect to the m-th bid. The α > 0 is a parameter that balances between ex- ploitation (of rewarding bids) and exploration (of uncertain bids). After LinUCB selects the bid for the root node, we follow the bid to the bidding node in the next layer, until a

PASScall is predicted by LinUCB. Then, we know the cost of the bidding sequence, and all the nodes on the bidding sequence path can be updated with the calculated rewards using ridge regression. The full algorithm is illustrated in Algorithm 1.

Another choice for the UCB algorithms is called UCB1 (Auer, Cesa-Bianchi, and Fischer 2002), which re- places the uncertainty term√

· · · in LinUCB withq

2 ln(T ) Tm , where T is the number of examples used to learn the entire g, and Tmis the number of examples used to update wm.

In addition to the model and the core algorithms intro- duced above, we adopt several additional techniques to im- prove the performance and computational efficiency.

Full update. In the proposed model, whenever a bidding sequence b is sampled from the UCB algorithms for an in-

(5)

stance x, the reward r can be calculated from c[b[`]], and the example ((x, bk), b[k + 1], r) is formed to update the bidding nodes. A closer look shows that some additional examples can be calculated easily with b. In particular, the cost for callingPASSimmediately after k bids can be calcu- lated by c[b[k]], and the cost for selecting a terminal node with a bid label b can be calculated by c[b]. Thus, we con- sider forming additional examples based on the above anal- ysis, and include those examples in updating the associated bidding nodes. Such an update scheme is called FULLUP-

DATE.

Penetrative update. We consider the UCB algorithms to balance the need for exploration in the proposed model. In some ways, the UCB algorithms are not properly designed for the multi-layer model, and thus can lead to some caveats.

For example, in the tree model, the number of instances that pass through a classifier in the top layer can be much more than those in the bottom layer. If the classifiers in the top lay- ers often result in an earlyPASS, the ones in the bottom layer might not receive enough examples, which result in a worse learning performance. To solve this problem, we consider a probabilistic “penetrative” scheme to continue bidding dur- ing training. That is, whenever a classifier predicts a bid that results in an earlyPASS, we select another bid and call the corresponding UPDATEwith some probability p. We require that the selected bid comes with a next bid (i.e., not result- ing in an early PASS) and to be of the highest UCB term.

In other words, with some probability, we hope to generate longer (but good) sequences b to help update the lower lay- ers of the model in this PENETRATIVEUPDATEscheme.

Delayed update. We adopt the contextual bandit algo- rithms in our model, which were designed for the online sce- nario where examples arrive one by one. Somehow updating instantly per example becomes the computational bottleneck of the algorithms. In view of the efficiency, we consider a DELAYEDUPDATEscheme that updates wmuntil gathering a pile of examples.

4 Experiments

Next, we study the proposed model and compare it with the baseline and optimistic methods. We also compare the model with a well-known computer bridge software, Wbridge5 (Costel 2014), which has won the computer bridge championship for several years. A randomly- generated data set of 100, 000 instances (deals) is used in the experiment. We reserve 10, 000 instances for validation and another 10, 000 for testing, and leave the rest for training.

We consider the condensed features for x, which contain two parts that are widely used in real-world bridge games and human-designed bidding systems, high card points and number of cards in each suit. We have considered sparse bi- nary features for representing the existence of each card, but find that they do not work better than condensed ones.

We obtain the cost vectors c from International Match Points (IMP), an integer between 0 and 24 that is widely used for comparing the relative performance of two teams

Method Dimensions Baseline Optimistic

CSOSR - condensed 6 3.8329 1.8985

CSTSR - condensed 6 3.9428 2.7697

CSTSR - 2nd POLY 21 3.8465 2.1106

CSTSR - 3rd POLY 56 3.8272 1.9228

Wbridge5 N/A 2.9550 N/A

Table 1: Results of baseline and optimistic methods

in real-world bridge games (ACBL 2005). We obtain c by comparing the best possible contract of the deal to each con- tract and calculate the IMP. When transforming the costs to the rewards in the proposed model, we take 24 minus the cost as the reward to keep the rewards non-negative.1

Baseline and optimistic methods. First, we present the performance of the baseline and the optimistic methods in Table 1. In CSOSR, SVM with the Gaussian kernel im- plemented with LIBSVM (Chang and Lin 2011) is used as the base learner. In CSTSR, ridge regression is used as the base learner. For balancing the time spent of the two algorithms, we only sub-sample 20, 000 instances for CSOSR. For CSTSR with condensed features, we also ex- tend its capability by considering simple polynomial ex- pansion (POLY) of the features (Abu-Mostafa, Magdon- Ismail, and Lin 2012). For parameters, we consider C ∈ {100, 101, 102, 103} and γ ∈ {10−3, 10−2, 10−1, 100} for CSOSR, and λ ∈ {10−6, 10−5, · · · , 103} for CSTSR. We choose the best parameters based on the validation set and report the average test cost in Table 1.

Unsurprisingly, we find that the performance of the opti- mistic methods to be much better than their baseline coun- terparts. This justifies that the information in both players are valuable, and it is important to properly exchange in- formation via bidding. In addition, note that the optimistic methods can often achieve lower test cost than the Wbridge5 software. This suggests that the human-designed bidding system within the computer software may not be perfect yet.

Comparing over all the baseline methods, we see that using the 2nd order expansion with the condensed features reach decent performance by the baseline CSTSR with only 21 ex- panded features. Thus, we will take those features within the proposed model in the next experiments.

Full and delayed updates. Next, we study two of the techniques proposed in Section 3 to improve the model. We first compare FULLUPDATEwith SINGLEUPDATE.

Iterations (105) 2 4 6 8 10

Single Update 5.50 4.00 3.92 3.81 3.77 Full Update 3.33 3.26 3.23 3.24 3.25 The table above shows how the average validation cost varies with the number of iterations on a tree model with

` = 4, M = 5 coupled with ridge regression with λ = 10−3 and UCB1 with α = 10. We can easily observe that FULL

UPDATEoutperforms SINGLEUPDATE, which justifies that

1One technical detail is that c is generated by assuming that the player who can win more rounds for the contract is the declarer.

(6)

0 100 200 300 400 500 3

3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 4

Average cost per deal

Number of Iterations (x104) instant pile=10 pile=100 pile=1000

(a) α = 10

0 100 200 300 400 500

3 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 4

Number of Iterations (x104)

Average cost per deal

instant pile=10 pile=100 pile=1000

(b) α = 100

Figure 2: DELAYEDUPDATEversus INSTANTUPDATE

the additional examples used for FULL UPDATE captures valuable information to make the cost estimation more pre- cise. Thus, we adopt FULLUPDATEin the next experiments.

Then, we study DELAYEDUPDATE. Figure 2 shows how the average validation cost varies with the number of iter- ations on the same tree model used for the previous exper- iment. We consider piles of size {10, 100, 1000} instances per update and α ∈ {10, 100}. We find that when α is small, INSTANT UPDATE or a small pile reaches the best perfor- mance, while larger α could use a larger pile. Overall, DE-

LAYEDUPDATEdoes not lead to much loss of performance.

Note that INSTANTUPDATEtakes more than 4 hours to train a decent model, while DELAYEDUPDATEwith piles of size 100 only need less than 1 hour. In view of the efficiency needed for extensive parameter selection, we take DELAYED

UPDATEwith piles of size 100 in the next experiments.

Different model structures. Next, we compare the per- formance of different model structures to the Wbridge5 soft- ware. We consider the tree model and the layered model with ` ∈ {2, 4, 6}, fix M = 5, and equip them with either UCB1 or LinUCB. For each model/algorithm com- bination, we take grid search on (p, α) with the valida- tion set to choose the penetration probability parameter p ∈ {0, 0.25, 0.5, 0.75, 1}, and the UCB parameter α ∈ {20, 22, 24, 26, 28}. Note that the tree model and the layered model is equivalent when ` = 2.

Table 2 lists the average training/validation/test cost on all the model/algorithm combinations. The results suggest that the tree model with ` = 4 or 6 coupled with UCB1 performs the best among all models. Furthermore, those best perfor- mance are competitive to the result reached by the Wbridge5 software. This marks a successful initiative toward learning to bid without relying on a human-designed bidding system.

Also, all the proposed models in Table 2 perform better than the baseline methods in Table 1. The results justify that the proposed models successfully make use of the bidding se- quence for information exchanging between teammates.

Comparison with Wbridge5. Table 2 readily lists the competitive performance of the proposed model to Wbridge5. Next, we make a more detailed comparison to understand the strengths and weaknesses of the proposed model. In real-world bridge games, a contract can roughly be divided into five categories based on its raw score from

low to high, namely PASS, PARTIAL, GAME, SLAM, and

GRAND SLAM. Because categoriesGAMEand beyond result in higher scores, human players (and hence human bidding systems) often prefer bidding towards those. The table be- low shows the total cost of Wbridge5 minus the total cost of the proposed model in each category.

Best Contract Type Cost Difference # Deals

PASS 828 1816

PARTIAL 5014 5165

GAME -2424 2339

SLAM -2152 521

GRAND SLAM -586 159

We see that the proposed model performs much better than Wbridge5 inPARTIALcontracts, which contribute to the ma- jority of the deals. This shows that the proposed model is in- deed guided by data rather than human design (that prefers

GAME and beyond). On the other hand, a human-played bridge game often contains competition when the best possi- ble contract isPARTIAL. Thus, the strength of the proposed model on PARTIALcontracts will need to be compensated with future studies on automatic bidding with competition.

Lastly, the weakness of the proposed model on GAMEand beyond may be due to the fact that there is insufficient data to warrant decent learning performance in those categories.

Some sampling techniques can be applied in the future to focus on those categories of contracts.

5 Conclusions and Future Works

We formally defined the problem of bridge bidding without competition by learning, and proposed an innovative model for undertaking this problem. The model predicts a bid- ding sequence with layers of classifier (bidding) nodes, and trains each classifier with the aid of UCB algorithms for con- textual bandit. The UCB algorithms allow the machines to learn their own bidding system by balancing the exploration for less-considered bids and the exploitation of well-learned bids. We show in experiments that the proposed model can achieve a performance similar to the champion-winning pro- gram in the computer bridge. Our initiative justifies the pos- sibility that machine learning may be able to do better than human-designed bidding systems on bridge bidding prob- lem.

One possible direction to improve the model is to use more data to train a deeper model towards valuable contracts such as the Grand Slam. The ultimate challenge is the other sub-problem: bidding with competition by learning. Such a challenge might require a mixture of the proposed model (collaboration between teammates) and well-studied models for competition-based games like Chess.

6 Acknowledgments

We thank Profs. Yuh-Jye Lee, Shou-De Lin, the anony- mous reviewers and the members of the NTU Computational Learning Lab for valuable suggestions. This work is par- tially supported by the Ministry of Science and Technology of Taiwan via the grant MOST 103-2221-E-002-148-MY3.

(7)

model UCB train validation test Tree/Layered, ` = 2 UCB1 3.1197 ± 0.0177 3.1981 ± 0.0268 3.0755 ± 0.0173

LinUCB 3.1242 ± 0.0089 3.2190 ± 0.0121 3.0933 ± 0.0112 Tree, ` = 4 UCB1 2.9013 ± 0.0079 3.0769 ± 0.0118 2.9672 ± 0.0096

LinUCB 3.0918 ± 0.0344 3.1804 ± 0.0298 3.0672 ± 0.0379 Tree, ` = 6 UCB1 2.9025 ± 0.0210 3.0484 ± 0.0226 2.9616 ± 0.0234

LinUCB 3.0124 ± 0.0249 3.1301 ± 0.0264 3.0477 ± 0.0243 Layered, ` = 4 UCB1 3.0779 ± 0.0179 3.1656 ± 0.0198 3.0561 ± 0.0230 LinUCB 3.0492 ± 0.0214 3.1325 ± 0.0218 3.0290 ± 0.0252 Layered, ` = 6 UCB1 3.1366 ± 0.0176 3.2451 ± 0.0208 3.1214 ± 0.0168 LinUCB 3.0825 ± 0.0209 3.1781 ± 0.0268 3.0660 ± 0.0224

Wbridge5 N/A N/A 3.0527 2.9550

Table 2: Average Cost Using Different Model Structures

References

Abu-Mostafa, Y. S.; Magdon-Ismail, M.; and Lin, H.-T.

2012. Learning from Data: A Short Course. AMLBook.

ACBL. 2005. Introduction to bridge scoring.

http://www.acbl.org/learn/scoreTeams.html.

Amit, A., and Markovitch, S. 2006. Learning to bid in bridge. Machine Learning 63(3):287–327.

Ando, T., and Uehara, T. 2001. Reasoning by agents in computer bridge bidding. In Computers and Games. 346–

364.

Auer, P.; Cesa-Bianchi, N.; and Fischer, P. 2002. Finite- time analysis of the multiarmed bandit problem. Machine learning47(2-3):235–256.

Beygelzimer, A.; Dani, V.; Hayes, T.; Langford, J.; and Zadrozny, B. 2005. Error limiting reductions between clas- sification tasks. In Proceedings of the 22nd International Conference on Machine Learning, 49–56.

Bowling, M.; F¨urnkranz, J.; Graepel, T.; and Musick, R.

2006. Machine learning and games. Machine learning 63(3):211–215.

Chang, C.-C., and Lin, C.-J. 2011. LIBSVM: A library for support vector machines. ACM Transactions on Intelligent Systems and Technology2:27:1–27:27. Software available at http://www.csie.ntu.edu.tw/ cjlin/libsvm.

Chang, M.-S. 1996. Building a fast double-dummy bridge solver. Technical report.

Chu, W.; Li, L.; Reyzin, L.; and Schapire, R. E. 2011.

Contextual bandits with linear payoff functions. In Inter- national Conference on Artificial Intelligence and Statistics, 208–214.

Costel, Y. 2014. Wbridge5 bridge software.

DeLooze, L. L., and Downey, J. 2007. Bridge bidding with imperfect information. In IEEE Symposium on Computa- tional Intelligence and Games, 368–373. IEEE.

Ginsberg, M. L. 1999. Gib: Steps toward an expert-level bridge-playing program. In Proceedings of International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence, 584–593.

Ginsberg, M. L. 2001. Gib: Imperfect information in a computationally challenging game. Journal of Artificial In- telligence Research14:303–358.

Langford, J., and Zhang, T. 2007. The epoch-greedy al- gorithm for contextual multi-armed bandits. Advances in Neural Information Processing Systems20:1096–1103.

Li, W.; Wang, X.; Zhang, R.; Cui, Y.; Mao, J.; and Jin, R. 2010. Exploitation and exploration in a performance based contextual advertising system. In Proceedings of the 16th ACM SIGKDD International Conference on Knowl- edge Discovery and Data Mining, 27–36.

Ponsen, M. J.; Ramon, J.; Croonenborghs, T.; Driessens, K.; and Tuyls, K. 2008. Bayes-relational learning of oppo- nent models from incomplete information in no-limit poker.

In Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelli- gence, 1485–1486.

Sandholm, T. 2010. The state of solving large incomplete- information games, and application to poker. AI Magazine 31(4):13–32.

Te´ofilo, L. F.; Passos, N.; Reis, L. P.; and Cardoso, H. L.

2012. Adapting strategies to opponent models in incomplete information games: a reinforcement learning approach for poker. In Autonomous and Intelligent Systems. 220–227.

Tu, H.-H., and Lin, H.-T. 2010. One-sided support vector re- gression for multiclass cost-sensitive classification. In Pro- ceedings of the 27th International Conference on Machine Learning, 1095–1102.

Zhou, Z.-H., and Liu, X.-Y. 2010. On multi-class cost- sensitive learning. Computational Intelligence 26(3):232–

257.

參考文獻

相關文件

vs Functional grammar (i.e. organising grammar items according to the communicative functions) at the discourse level2. “…a bridge between

Now, nearly all of the current flows through wire S since it has a much lower resistance than the light bulb. The light bulb does not glow because the current flowing through it

which can be used (i) to test specific assumptions about the distribution of speed and accuracy in a population of test takers and (ii) to iteratively build a structural

Experiment a little with the Hello program. It will say that it has no clue what you mean by ouch. The exact wording of the error message is dependent on the compiler, but it might

Community of practice provides a platform for knowledge workers to share, learn and discuss the knowledge related to a particular topic, thus, the performance of the community

A digital color image which contains guide-tile and non-guide-tile areas is used as the input of the proposed system.. In RGB model, color images are very sensitive

This study has analyzed 13 bidding cases of different bidding mechanisms in high tech plant construction projects in the past, and hoping to establish a fair mechanism in

When designing the highway bridge expansion joints, a designer usually will review domestic and international bridge design examples to assess his/her design and determine