• 沒有找到結果。

China Economic Issues

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "China Economic Issues"

Copied!
40
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

Number 1/10, January 2010

China Economic Issues

Monetary stance and policy objectives in China:

a narrative approach

Chang Shu and Brian Ng

The paper undertakes the first study to examine China’s monetary stance using a narrative approach in the tradition of Romer and Romer (1989). Already widely applied for other economies, the narrative approach is conceivably particularly useful for China. The PBoC uses a wide range of monetary tools, including market- or non- market-based, quantity and price-based measures, for some of which information is not available. Therefore, conventional measures, most notably the interest rate, may not fully capture the changes in monetary stance. Based on two key official PBoC reports, this study compiles a number of indices to reflect the direction and intensity of monetary stance. These indices are shown to better gauge China’s monetary stance particularly in the early 2000s when market-based monetary tools were less used, but become increasingly correlated with the interest rate, a market-, price- based tool, in recent years.

The indices are then used to investigate the PBoC’s policy response to macroeconomic developments through estimation of monetary reaction functions using ordered probit and logit models. The empirical analysis shows that the most important policy objectives are economic growth and inflation, which are in fact the PBoC’s dual legal mandate. Unemployment, and monetary and credit growth, for

(2)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

which the Government also announces annual targets, do not have significant impact on the PBoC’s monetary stance. In meeting their mandate, the PBoC appears to follow a rule of thumb, using historical averages as targets rather than the officially announced annual targets, and trend growth derived from the Hodrick-Prescott offers little guidance on monetary stance.

(3)

I. Introduction

Mainland China’s (China) rising impact on global financial and economic developments have attracted a growing number of the ‘People’s Bank of China (PBoC) watchers’ in recent years and the increasing use of approaches employed for monitoring other central banks. The more conventional approach for assessing monetary stance is to analyse the data on macroeconomic indicators and observable policy actions (such as open market operations (OMOs), changes in reserve requirement and benchmark interest rates in China’s case). However, the PBoC watchers, like other central bank watchers, are also increasingly paying attention to official communications with the aim of discerning the PBoC’s monetary stance.

These official communications include meeting notes of the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC), the quarterly Monetary Policy Reports, and speeches of the PBoC’s senior officials and China’s top leaders such as Premier Wen.

The examination of official communications is in the tradition of the narrative approach to studying monetary stance initiated by Romer and Romer (1989). It is motivated by the observation that some of the often used monetary stance indicators, which include monetary aggregates and short-term interest rates, may not best capture changes in monetary stance as they can fluctuate due to factors not related to monetary stance. Since Romer and Romer (1989), the narrative approach to studying monetary stance has gained popularity, and been used in describing and assessing monetary policymaking of many central banks.

Conceivably, the narrative approach to monetary stance can be particularly applicable to China’s case. Taking into consideration factors not related to the domestic economy and the inadequate development of financial markets for transmitting monetary impulse, the PBoC uses a wide range of tools in cyclical management.

These include market- and non-market-based, as well as price- and quantity-based measures. Some of the tools are observable with complete information released through official channels, while only anecdotal reports can be found for others.

(4)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

There has been no formal study following the narrative approach to studying the PBoC’s monetary stance, despite the compelling case for using it in China’s case, and the widespread, yet informal use of official communications by China watchers. The best attempt to date at providing a measure of monetary stance alternative to conventional measures is by He and Pauwels (2008) who compile an index based on a set of observable policy actions such as changes in the interest rate and reserve requirement and OMOs.

This paper represents the first formal analysis on the PBoC’s monetary stance using the narrative approach. In compiling indices of the PBoC’s stance, information is drawn from official records, most notably meeting notes of the MPC and the quarterly Monetary Policy Reports. The PBoC’s assessment of economic developments, policy actions and stated policy stance will be examined for deciphering the PBoC’s underlying monetary stance. The underlying assumption in deriving these indices is that the direction and intensity of policy actions are consistent with those of wording in the reports.

The compiled indices will then be used in investigating the PBoC’s policy objectives.

The PBoC has the legal mandate to maintain stable economic growth and currency stability. At the same time, the Mainland authorities officially announce a range of economic targets annually, including economic growth, inflation, monetary and credit growth and unemployment. The second part of the paper will estimate a monetary reaction function of the PBoC in order to address the questions: what are the important policy objectives of the PBoC? How much importance does the PBoC attach to each objective? What best describes the PBoC’s targets for each economic indicator?

The rest of the paper is arranged as follows. Section II reviews the literature on the narrative approach in studying monetary stance, and the monetary reaction framework which is typically used for evaluating policy responses of central banks. In introducing monetary tools in China, Section III classifies them into a 2 X 2 matrix of market- and non-market-based, and price- and quantity-based sets. This is followed by a detailed account of macroeconomic developments in China and monetary policy actions since 2001 when both meeting notes of the MPC and the quarterly Monetary Policy Reports became available. Section IV explains the rationales for using the

(5)

narrative approach to studying monetary stance in China’s case and the methodology for compiling monetary stance indicators for China. Section V presents the empirical framework for studying the PBoC’s policy response using the compiled indicators.

The findings from estimating the PBoC policy reaction functions and the implications are discussed in Section VI before reaching the concluding remarks in Section VII.

II. Literature review

This study draws from two strands of literature: the narrative approach to monetary stance and monetary policy reaction functions.

The narrative approach to studying monetary stance is motivated by difficulties in accurately identifying monetary policy impulses using the conventional measures such as M2 and a short-term interest rate. As noted by King and Plosser (1984) and Boschen and Mills (1995) among others, these monetary indicators can fluctuate for reasons not related to changes in monetary policy. This motivated Romer and Romer (1989) to build on Friedman and Schwartz (1963) – an influential study in the narrative tradition, and to identify monetary shocks based on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) records. Brunner and Meltzer (1989) extended this approach by compiling an indicator of monetary stance – a numerical index which facilitates the study of the relationship between monetary stance and other economic variables by econometric methods. Subsequently, a number of different monetary stance indices have been compiled for the US (see, for example, Poole (1971), Uselton (1974), Potts and Luckett (1978), Kimelman (1981), Boschen and Mills (1995), and Romer and Romer (2004)). Later studies using the narrative approach have grown substantially, and monetary stance indices have been compiled for many other central banks, such as the European Central Bank (Berger, de Haan and Sturm, 2006, Rosa and Verga, 2005), and the Bank of England (Angelopoulou, 2007). For Asia, Shen and Chen (1996), and Huang and Lin (2006) have applied the approach for Taiwan.

Many of monetary stance indicators take the discrete values of 1, 0, and -1 to indicate the ‘tightening/contractionary, ‘neutral’ and ‘easing/expansionary’, e.g. Poole (1971), Potts and Luckett (1978), and Kimelman (1981). Others including Uselton (1974)

(6)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

and Boschen and Mills (1995), use a wider range of values to indicate the intensity of monetary stance in either directions. For example, the index derived by Boschen and Mills (1995) ranges from 2 to -2, with a value of 2 indicating monetary stance placing a strong emphasis on promoting economic growth while a value of -2 a strong policy emphasis on inflation reduction. There are also studies which derive an index by the combined use of monetary policy records and conventional monetary stance measures.

Romer and Romer (2004) develop a new measure of monetary policy shocks in the US for the period 1969 - 1996 by combining information on the Federal Reserve’s expected funds rate and records of FOMC meetings.

The monetary stance indices have been used in a variety of ways. One is to examine the impact of monetary policy on macroeconomic variables, e.g. Boschen and Mills (1995) and Romer and Romer (2004) for the US and Angelopoulou (2007) for the UK.

Another use of monetary stance indicators is to examine the factors affecting a central bank’s decision on monetary stance. The framework for the quantitative studyof the determinants of monetary stance was initiated by Taylor (1993) in the form of a regression of the federal funds rate on the output gap and inflation. Regressions of this form are now known as monetary reaction functions, or the Taylor rule, an important analytical tool of central banks. The monetary reaction function has been estimated for many economies, both developed and developing, in many different variants of the Taylor rule. More well known studies in this area include Nelson (2000), and Batini and Nelson (2000) for the Bank of England, Judd and Rudebusch (1998) for the Federal Reserve, Gerlach and Schnabel (2000) using pre-EMU data, and Faust et al. (2001) for the European Central Bank. This analysis has also been undertaken for a number of Asian central banks, such as Shen and Chen (1996) and Huang and Lin (2006) for the Central Bank of China in Taiwan, and Liu and Zhang (2007) and He and Pauwels (2008) for the PBoC. Central banks’ policy decisions in response to changing economic conditions have been studied from both descriptive and prescriptive perspectives (Svensson, 2003). A descriptive perspective study focuses on how to best characterise a central bank’s behaviour, while from a prescriptive approach, research examines what kind of rules are best at stabilising output and inflation in different macroeconomic models.

(7)

III. Monetary tools, macroeconomic developments and monetary stance in China since 2000

The PBoC, being responsible for monetary policy in China, has the dual legal mandate of ‘maintaining the stability of the currency, and thereby promoting economic growth’. It also has the responsibility of maintaining financial stability, although not explicitly stated. The PBoC’s MPC was formed in 2000 and is charged with the responsibility to discuss and propose (a) adjustments in monetary stance; (b) aims of monetary policy; (c) use of monetary tools; and (d) macroeconomic policy co- ordination measures. The Committee consists of 11 members including the Governor and Deputy Governors of the PBoC, representatives from government ministries/agencies1, two governors of state-owned banks and an independent financial professional. The MPC meeting is convened quarterly, with a short statement released after the meeting to summarise the Committee’s views on economic and financial developments and proposed monetary stance. The MPC meeting reports will be submitted to the State Council when the PBoC seeks approval on monetary policy decisions. As such, the MPC in China is largely a consultative body, making it different from its counterparts in many other countries. However, its views on economic developments and monetary stance represent the official position.

Separately, the PBoC also releases a quarterly Monetary Policy Report, which gives more details on the PBoC’s review and assessment on macroeconomic and policy developments, as well as its policy intentions.

In conducting monetary policy, the PBoC uses a range of tools, including both quantity- and price-based, market based and non-market based measures (Table 1).

They broadly fall into a few categories.

 Open Market Operations (OMOs). These are market-based and conducted on a regular, high frequency basis. In these operations, the PBoC controls the amount, price, frequency and composition of central bank bill issuance, and repurchase and reverse repurchase arrangements to influence liquidity in the banking system.

1 These institutions include the State Council, National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC), Ministry of Finance (MoF), State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE), National Bureau of Statistics (NBS), China Banking Regulatory Commission (CBRC), China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) and China Insurance Regulatory Commission (CIRC).

(8)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

 Selective transactions. These are used in some episodes of excess liquidity and rapid credit expansion, including targeted bill issuance to selected banks, special deposits from selected banks, and foreign currency swaps between the PBoC and commercial banks.

 Reserve requirement. The required reserve ratio (RRR) is a quantity-based, market tool often used in monetary easing and tightening cycles.

 Interest rates. The adjustment of benchmark lending and deposit rates is a market-, price-based tool that has been used more in macroeconomic management in recent years, although its use has been constrained at times by, for example, concerns over capital inflows.

 Credit controls. The above more market-based tools often have to be supplemented by the use of direct controls on credit expansion, which is a quantity-, non-market based tool.

 Other regulatory means. Examples of these include adjustment in the proportion of down payment in mortgage lending, and the permitted range for interest rates to deviate from the benchmark interest rates.

Information on the more market-based means, including OMOs, reserve requirement, and interest rates is released by the PBoC in a systematic way. Data on targeted bill issuance, special deposits, foreign currency swaps and credit controls are generally not available officially. Partial information may be reported by the media from time to time.

(9)

Table 1. PBoC’s monetary tools

Market based Non-market based Quantity based  Issuance size of central

bank bills

 Size of repurchase and reverse repurchase arrangements

 Reserve requirement

 Targeted central bank bills

 Special deposits from selected banks

 Foreign currency swap

 Control on credit Price based  Issuance rate of central

bank bills

 Rate of repurchase and reverse repurchase arrangements

 Benchmark lending and deposit interest rates

 Some regulatory changes aimed at changing market behaviour, e.g. varying the floating band of interest rates

Sources: Authors’ compilation.

Chronology of macroeconomic developments and monetary stance since 2000

Starting in 2001 when both the press releases and the quarterly Monetary Policy Reports became available, China has undergone several phases of macroeconomic developments (Charts 1-2): (a) an economic recovery from the Asian financial crisis with broadly supportive monetary policy between 2001 and 2002; (b) a gradually increasing tightening bias from the turn of 2003 which cumulated into a relatively brief, strong tightening in the first half of 2004 upon signs of overheating; (c) continuing robust economic growth under monetary policy with a tightening bias during 2004 Q3 and 2007 Q1; (d) intensive tightening in 2007 Q2 – 2008 Q2 due to high inflationary pressures and rapid investment growth; and (e) substantial monetary easing against the background of a global financial crisis from 2008 Q3 to 2009 Q2.

(10)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

Chart 1. Major macroeconomic indicators

a. GDP growth and inflation b. Investment and exports

5 7 9 11 13 15

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10

CPI (RHS) GDP (LHS)

%YoY % YoY

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening

-30 -20 -10 0 10 20 30 40 50

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -30 -20 -10 0 10 20 30 40 50

Export FAI

%YoY %YoY

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening

Chart 2. Selective policy changes

a. OMO and RRR b. Interest rates

-8 -4 0 4 8 12 16 20

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -400 -200 0 200 400 600 800 1000 Open market operations (RHS)

Required reserve ratio (LHS)

% RMB bn

withdrawalinjection

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening Sources: CEIC and authors’ estimates.

4 5 6 7 8

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 0 1 2 3 4 1-year lending rate (LHS)

3-month central bank bill issuance rate (RHS)

%, pa %, pa

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening

2001 – 2002 Q3: policy support for economic recovery

During this period, the Mainland economy gradually recovered from the slowdown caused by the Asian financial crisis. Externally, after a synchronised recession following the September 11th incident, the global economy began to pick up in 2002.

Upon the recovery of the global economy and positive impacts from the entry to the

(11)

WTO, China’s exports rose sharply in 2002 by 31.0%, compared with the average 10.6% between 1997 and 2001. Domestically, private consumption started to return.

As a result of the expansionary fiscal policy and accommodative monetary policy, investment grew by 17.4%, the highest since the outbreak of the Asian financial crisis, although still considered modest when compared with the figures for recent years.

Deflationary pressures persisted due to the impact on domestic prices of the WTO entry and excess supply of consumer goods.

Throughout this period, monetary policy, while defined as ‘sound’ (穩健)2, had an easing bias. With aggregate demand just starting to return and the existence of deflationary risks, monetary policy was aimed at ‘preventing economic growth and prices from further declines’ (PBoC, 2002 Q2). Notably, the PBoC lowered the 1- year lending and deposit rates by 54 and 27 basis points respectively in January 2002.

2002 Q4 – 2004 Q2: gradual tightening cumulated into brief, forceful credit controls

The Mainland economy entered a period of rapid growth. The recovering world economy and China’s continuing expanision in the global market contributed to a rapid export growth at year-on-year rates above 30% throughout the period. Signs of overheating in investment began to surface around the turn of 2003 (PBoC, 2002 Q4 and 2003 Q1), particularly in certain sectors such as the real estate sector, with investment expanding by 28.4% in 2003 and surging by 47.8% in 2004 Q1. This was supported by a surge in credit expansion, as credit growth rose from 15.8% in 2002 to an average of 21.5% between 2003 Q1 and 2004 Q1. With rising international commodity prices, a pick-up in food prices, and easy monetary conditions in the previous years, China quickly shook off deflation that prevailed in 2002. Prices rose sharply from 2003, with headline inflation increasing from 0.5% in 2003 Q1 to 4.4%

in 2004 Q2.

The accommodative stance began to be withdrawn from 2002 Q4. The wording

‘strengthen financial support to economic growth’ found in many previous PBoC Monetary Policy Reports was removed from the report of 2002 Q4. While still termed ‘sound’ (穩健), monetary policy turned to an increasing tightening bias in

2 These are the terms used in the official reports.

(12)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

2003, with the PBoC highlighting the need to ‘control the quantity of money and credit’ in the second half of 2003 (PBoC, 2003 Q4). Tightening was initially achieved principally through quantitative means. OMOs were strengthened in 2003, particularly with the introduction of issuance of central bank bills for sterilisation.

The RRR was raised by one percentage point in 2003 Q3 - the first time since the Asian financial crisis, and then another 50 basis points in 2004 Q2. In 2004 Q1, the surge in investment prompted a more forceful action from the PBoC. Monetary stance was shifted from ‘sound’ (穩健) – a stance maintained since the availability of the MPC record in 2000 – to ‘appropriately tight’ (適度從緊), and credit quotas were implemented.

2004 Q3 – 2007 Q1: continuous, moderate tightening upon persistent overheating pressures

Following the imposition of credit controls, investment plunged in 2004 Q2, with the year-on-year growth halving to 24%, and thus leading to a slight ease of the monetary policy compared with 2004 Q1. In the ensuing years, economic growth remained robust, averaging 11.2% year on year between 2005 and 2007 Q1. During the period, overheating risks of the domestic economy persisted and grew over time. With strong growth impulses at the regional level, investment expanded at rates of close to 30%

during most of the period. This was supported by an acceleration of credit expansion, particularly since 2006. Credit growth, having stayed low for most of 2004-2005, accelerated between 2006 Q1 and 2007 Q1. External imbalances also began to mount.

Exports grew at much faster rates than imports, leading the trade surplus to jump by more than 50% between 2004 and 2006. The large trade surpluses and large capital inflows placed upward pressures on the exchange rate. After easing from the second half of 2004, inflation stayed moderate in 2005-6, but began to rise in early 2007.

While dropping the phrase ‘appropriately tight’ (適度從緊) for monetary stance after just one quarter and re-adopting that of ‘sound’ (穩健) in 2004 Q2, monetary policy in fact had a tightening bias during the period. ‘Macroeconomic adjustment’ (宏觀調控) was the constant tone in policymaking, although the intensity of tightening varied during the period. In 2004 some strong tightening was still implemented, reflected by a further hike of 50 basis points in the RRR in April 2004, and a rise of 27 basis

(13)

points 1-year benchmark interest rates in October 2004. The tightening stance was eased in 2005 and early 2006 with reduced use of policy instruments. However, as the credit growth and inflationary pressures started to pick up in 2006, the PBoC stepped up tightening again. The more intensive tightening was set in train by an increase in the 1-year benchmark lending rate in April 2006, and then followed by successive hikes in required reserves and various interest rates. In particular, the RRR was raised from 7.5% at the start of 2006 to 10% in 2007 Q1. Meanwhile, the 1-year benchmark lending and deposit rates were increased by 81 and 54 basis points respectively. The issuance rate on the 3-month central bank bills was also guided upward by 85 basis points. These were supplemented by several targeted bill issuance, regulations to tighten mortgage lending, and increasingly frequent window guidance meetings.

2007 Q2 – 2008 Q2: intensive monetary tightening to curb overheating and high inflation

The economy continued to grow rapidly despite a weakening in the global economy during this period. Although economic growth in the major economies began to slow when the sub-prime crisis started to unfold in the second half of 2007, growth in China’s exports appeared unfettered and trade surpluses carried on ballooning.

Domestic demand was very strong. In particular, investment growth maintained a 30% growth during most of the period. There were signs of overheating in the property market, as indicated by an acceleration in housing-price inflation and marked increases in transactions. Due to a surge in food prices, inflation began to run away, with headline inflation peaking at 8.0% in 2008 Q1.

This period saw the tightest use of monetary policy with frequent and strong actions by the PBoC. The monetary stance was explicitly shifted from ‘sound’ (穩健) to

‘appropriately tight’ (適度從緊)’ in 2007 Q2, and then further to ‘tight’ (從緊) in the first half of 2008. There was substantial liquidity withdrawal through OMOs. The RRR was raised thirteen times by a total of 700 basis points within the period. The 1- year benchmark lending and deposit rates were raised by 108 and 135 basis points respectively between April and December 2007. In addition, the PBoC also implemented a number of unconventional tools, including special transactions with

(14)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

selected banks, the regulatory and administrative means. Apart from more frequent use of targeted bills, some banks were also requested to place special deposits with the PBoC for a term of three years, and the PBoC is also known to have conducted foreign currency swaps with commercial banks. With the interest rate constrained by concerns over attracting further capital inflows, credit controls were used as the principal means at the later stage of monetary tightening. Reportedly, the annual and quarterly credit quotas were set at the beginning of 2008 – the first time quarterly quotas were used, reflecting the authorities’ determination to control credit expansion.

2008 Q3 – 2009 Q2: massive monetary easing to counter a sharp economic slowdown

The lagged impact of forceful macroeconomic tightening coincided with a collapse of the world economy in the middle of 2008. As the major economies went into a synchronised recession, external demand waned. China’s exports plunged, recording a year-on-year decline of over 20 percent in the first eight months of 2009 – a stark contrast with an expansion of over 20% in the same period in 2008. Domestic production followed suit, and investment weakened. In particular, the year-on-year growth of investment in real estate decelerated sharply from 37.5% in June 2008 to a meagre 1.0% in January - February 2009, contributing significantly to the economic downturn. The easing of domestic food prices, collapse of international commodity prices and weak aggregate demand led consumer prices to decline in early 2009 upon year-on-year comparisons.

Responding to the collapse in external demand and faltering domestic demand, the change in monetary stance was dramatic. After dropping the ‘tight’ (從緊) stance in 2008 Q2, the PBoC stated that monetary policy was turned ‘appropriately loose’ (適 度寬鬆) in 2008 Q3. Unprecedented monetary loosening was undertaken from 2008 Q3. OMOs were dramatically scaled down, with the suspension of issuance of central bank bills with maturities over one year and less frequent issuance of 3-month bills.

The RRR was reduced by 2.0 and 4.0 percentage points for big and small banks respectively between September and December 2008. Special deposits by some banks, which were arranged during 2007 Q4 as another means of locking in liquidity, were allowed to be withdrawn early. Key policy rates were also slashed. Central

(15)

bank bill issuance rates were guided lower, with the 3-month central bank bill rate falling from 3.40% at the end of June 2008 to 0.97% at the end of January 2009. The 1-year benchmark lending and deposit rates were slashed by 2.16 percentage points and 1.89 percentage points to 5.31% and 2.25% respectively in less than four months.

Also, in view of the importance of the property market in the economy, the floor for mortgage rates was lowered from 0.9 to 0.7 of the benchmark lending rate, allowing greater freedom in mortgage pricing. As at the height of monetary tightening in the second half of 2007 and the first half of 2008, administrative measures proved to be useful in monetary easing. Most notably, credit ceilings, which were imposed in the second half of 2007, were removed in November 2008. Then at the beginning of 2009, a target of RMB5 trillion was announced for new loan expansion for the year as a whole, but the figure was soon explained as the floor (rather than the ceiling) by official sources.

IV. An indicator of monetary stance

As the discussions in previous sections have shown, the use of the narrative approach has been motivated by the difficulty in finding an appropriate measure for monetary stance. Lack of a good indicator of monetary stance is a particularly acute problem for China, an observation also made by He and Pauwels (2008). The benchmark interest rate is sometimes not the chosen instrument in monetary control for a number of reasons. First, it is generally recognised that in China, the transmission of policy rate changes to the wider economy is not effective due to the under-developed financial markets (see, for example, Peng et al. (2006), and Liu and Zhang (2007)).

Secondly, the use of the interest-rate tool is sometimes constrained by factors other than domestic considerations such as concerns over capital inflows (Shu et al., 2008).

In addition, the discussion on China’s monetary tools in the earlier sections shows that apart from market-based tools, non-market based tools are also used such as special deposits, foreign currency swaps and more common credit controls. The problem of measuring monetary policy stance is further exacerbated by the PBoC’s reliance on the use of administrative controls, such as window guidance, which is unobservable and not quantifiable in nature. Due to the limited availability of information, it is not possible to directly measure the use of these tools. Despite these known issues,

(16)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

China’s monetary policy is still typically measured by observable changes in the interest rate and other tools. One exception is He and Pauwels (2008) who derive an indicator of the PBoC’s monetary policy stance as a latent variable extracted from the changes in a large number of economic variables.

In this paper, we follow the narrative approach to compile a monetary stance index of the PBoC by drawing information from the quarterly release of the PBoC’s Monetary Policy Report and the announcement of the quarterly meeting of the PBoC’s MPC.

Each issue of the Monetary Policy Report contains the PBoC assessments on the past development of monetary conditions, the use of monetary policy tools, financial market development and macroeconomic development, the prospect of the Mainland economy and the tendency of monetary policy in the periods ahead. The announcement of the quarterly meeting of the PBoC’s MPC also provides similar information but with a much condensed content.

In constructing the monetary policy stance indicator, we take into account, apart from the stated broad policy direction, information such as the PBoC’s assessments on the near-term overall economic performance and the aims of macroeconomic adjustment.

As shown earlier, while the broad policy direction is often stated as ‘sound’ (穩健), monetary stance could have a different bias according to economic conditions. For example, under the ‘sound’ (穩健) policy direction, monetary stance was largely accommodative during 2001-2002, which became more restrictive during 2004 Q2 and 2007 Q1. Thus the concerns emanating from these reports over the state of the economy, inflationary pressures and monetary growth may also help in analysing the direction and intensity of the PBoC’s policy actions.

We construct three monetary stance indices. The values of the first index range from -2 (indicating strong loosening) to 2 (indicating strong tightening), with 0 being a neutral policy stance for each period (Table 2a). Intensive tightening is taken as the periods when the PBoC stated monetary stance to be ‘appropriately tight/tight’ (適度 從緊/從緊), while intensive loosening was given to stated stance of ‘appropriately loose’ (適度寬鬆). For the majority of the periods, the officially stated stance is

‘sound’ (穩健). To code these periods, we further draw on the PBoC’s assessments of economic developments, and assign values of 1 for the existence of greater upside

(17)

risks for growth and inflation, -1 for greater downside risks for growth and deflation, and 0 for broadly balanced risks. We also attempt to further differentiate the degree of intensity in monetary stance, and derive an index with values ranging from -3 (indicating highest degree of loosening) to 3 (indicating highest degree of tightening).

The statements of ‘appropriately tight/tight’ (適度從緊/從緊) and ‘appropriately loose’ (適度寬鬆) take the value of 3 and -3 respectively. It is more challenging to differentiate the intensity of tightening and loosening stance with the stated stance of

‘sound’ (穩健). Table 2b gives examples of the wording in the Monetary Policy Report and the press release of the MPC meeting for the 7-value indicator. A third index, with three values (-1, 0 and 1 for ‘easing’, ‘neutral’ and ‘tightening’

respectively), does not differentiate the intensity of the monetary stance.

One issue in applying the narrative approach is the divergence between ‘words’ and

‘deeds’. The divergence arises either when a central bank does not or is unable to follow its stated policy stance, or when it undertakes measures which are not disclosed to the public. Both types of divergence occur from time to time around the world. The implementation of monetary policy is subject to many constraints, and thus monetary stance inferred from a central bank’s stated stance may reflect the desired rather the true policy stance. This makes it difficult to apply the narrative approach to studying monetary stance. On the other hand, a central bank may employ some monetary tools (e.g. credit controls, foreign currency swaps in the case of China) which are not fully known by the public. This second type of divergence between

‘words’ and ‘deeds’ in fact strengthens the case for using the narrative approach for China.

(18)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

Table 2a. 5-value monetary stance: coding criteria

Criteria

2 (Strong tightening)  Tight (從緊)

 Appropriately tight (適度從緊)

1 (Tightening)  Sound (穩健) with a tightening bias

0 (Neutral)  Sound (穩健)

-1 (Loosening)  Sound (穩健) with a loosening bias

-2 (Strong loosening)  Appropriately loose (適度寬鬆) Sources: Authors’ compilation.

The 5-value index shows that China’s monetary policy cycles since 2001 can generally be categorised into three broad phases – an easing bias before 2002 Q4;

tightening between 2002 Q4 and 2008 Q2; and easing since 2008 Q3 (Chart 3a), with more periods with a tightening bias. Chart 3b displays the 5-value monetary stance index of the PBoC with the benchmark 1-year lending rate. The chart shows that this index is better at picking up changes in monetary stance in the early 2000s. It points to a reverse of monetary stance from loosening to tightening in 2003 with the use of OMOs, required reserve and window guidance, even though there were no changes in the benchmark interest rate. In more recent years, there are increasing co-movements between the index and the interest rate, suggesting that market- and price-based tools, although still supplemented by non-market-based means, are playing an increasing role in China’s monetary policy.

(19)

Chart 3. Monetary stance indicators and interest rates

a. 3- and 7-value indicators b.5-value indicator and interest rate

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

3-value monetary stance indicator 7-value monetary stance indicator

Tightening

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 4 5 6 7 8 9 1-year lending rate (RHS)

5-value monetary stance indicator (LHS)

Tightening

%, pa

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening Sources: CEIC and authors’ estimates.

V. Monetary objectives: an empirical investigation

Empirical framework

Identifying factors that affect the PBoC’s monetary stance can shed light on what the PBoC’s policy objectives are and how important they are. To this end, we can estimate a monetary policy reaction function in which a monetary policy indicator is regressed on factors affecting policy decisions in the spirit of Taylor (1993) who suggests the formulation of monetary policy rule depends on the deviation of real GDP growth and inflation from targets. Although short-term interest rates are often employed as the dependent variable,3 the use of an index of monetary stance, i.e. a discrete variable, as the dependent variable has become more common in recent studies on monetary reactions. It is not just limited to those which follow the narrative approach to derive indices of monetary stance, including Shen and Chen (1996) and Huang and Shen (2002). As interest rates typically move in multiples of 25 basis points, some studies e.g. Vanderhart (2000) and Carstensen (2006), also model interest-rate movements as discrete jumps.

(20)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

In the benchmark model, we include economic growth and inflation – the two objectives defined by the PBoC mandate – as explanatory variables for monetary stance. Following examples of Taylor (1993) and the subsequent studies in this area, the PBoC’s monetary reaction is thus specified as:

(1) MPt01(ytiyt*i)+β2(infti−inft*i)+εt.

In Equation (1), MPt is a monetary policy stance indicator derived from the narrative approach, and the three indicators discussed above will be used as alternatives. The factors considered to affect monetary stance are specified as deviations from a target.

Thus, yt-i and inft-i are actual real GDP growth and CPI inflation, while y*tiand inft−*iare growth and inflation targets respectively. Both β1 and β2 are expected to be positive, implying that the central bank will tighten monetary stance if economic growth and inflation are above their targets.

A number of targets are considered for estimation. One obvious choice in China’s case is the announced annual targets. The economic targets announced every year include those for economic growth, inflation, monetary and credit growth, and unemployment.4 Among the announcements, figures for growth and inflation receive the greatest attention (Chart 4a). It is also important to point out that the announced figures are not targets, although often referred to as such. It is more accurate to describe them as a floor for economic growth, and a ceiling for inflation. The target setting has taken into account the performance of the economy. As China has largely maintained robust economic growth since 2000, the growth target has been largely stable, revised only once in 2005 from 7% to 8%. Price developments have been more varied since 2000, with a period of deflation in the early 2000s, regular, at times intensive, inflationary pressures from 2003 to the first half of 2008, and downward pressures on prices from the second half of 2008 and for most of 2009. Accordingly,

3 See, for example, Taylor (1993) using the federal funds rate for the US, Carstensen (2006), and Gerlach (2007) using the ECB main refinancing rate for the Euro-area.

4 The official targets are obtained from the National People’s Congress report on economic, social development plan, and the PBoC Monetary Policy Reports.

(21)

the inflation target was adjusted downward from 1-2% in 2001-2002 to 1% in 2003,5 but has subsequently been revised upwards for a number of times. Chart 4b shows that the economic growth target is generally conservatively set, as growth outturns exceeded the target in all years. Even in 2009 when at the beginning of the year there were doubts, consensus emerged later that the target would be met given the strength of the rebound in the domestic economy. One reason for the conservative setting of growth targets may be to restrain local governments from excessive investment.

There also have been deviations of actual inflation, in both directions, from the announced ceiling.

Chart 4. Growth and inflation deviations from official targets

a. Official targets b. deviations from official targets

-6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10

Series4 Series5

CPI - official target GDP - official target

%YoY %YoY

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening Sources: NPC reports and Zhang and Liu (2007).

-6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6

CPI - deviation from official target GDP - deviation from official target

%YoY %YoY

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening Sources: CEIC and authors’ estimates.

In addition to the official targets, two measures of the trend development of an economic indicator are considered as alternative measures of targets. Following a common practice of the literature in the area, e.g. Huang and Lin (2006), the Hodrick- Prescott filter is used to derive a trend line. A third measure of trend growth of an economic variable is the historical average, taken as a 5-year moving average in this study. Charts 5a and 5b show the deviations of growth and inflation from historical

5 For most years, the inflation target is specified as “not above” a particular figure. One exception is 2001-2002, when the inflation target was given as the range of 1 - 2%.

(22)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

averages, and trend growth derived from the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Real GDP growth and inflation have shown deviations in both directions from the targets taken as historical averages and the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend. Charts 5a and 5b show that deviations from the official targets and historical averages tally well with the economic cycles described earlier. However, deviations from the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend do not accord well with the swings in economic activity in China, as discussed in the earlier sections. For example, these deviations show a more or less continuous undershoot of economic growth for 2003 – 2006 when there were overheating pressures particularly towards the end of the period.

Chart 5 Deviations of growth and inflation

a. From historical averages b. From trend

-6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6

CPI - deviation from historical average GDP - deviation from historical average

%YoY %YoY

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening

-2 -1 0 1 2 3

2001Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1 2008Q1 2009Q1 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 CPI - deviation from HP filtered trend

GDP - deviation from potential output

ppt ppt

Strong tightening Tightening

Strong loosening Loosening Sources: CEIC and authors’ estimates.

This equation can be extended to include other policy target variables. In China’s case, we also test the significance of other economic targets including unemployment, and monetary and credit growth, as these are included routinely as part of annual announcements. The descriptive statistics of the key explanatory variables are given in Table 3.

(23)

Estimation methodology

Equation 1 can be estimated by the ordered probit and logit model. Since the application by Eichengreen, Watson, and Grossman (1985) on the monetary reaction function of the Bank of England, the ordered probit and logit models have been widely employed in this literature when the monetary stance indicator is a discrete variable. In these models, the observed discrete dependent variable is modelled by a latent variable MP* that has a linear relationship with the explanatory variables:

(2) MPt* = xt'β +εt.

In Equation 2, xt' is a vector of k explanatory variables at time t, including economic growth, inflation, monetary and credit growth, and unemployment, andβ is a k x 1 vector of coefficients and εt is random errors distributed as N(0,1). In the case of the monetary indicator with five values, for example, the latent variable MP* has the following relationship with the observed variable MPt:

(3) MPt =





<

<

<

<

* 4

4

* 3

3

* 2

2

* 1

1

*

2 1 0 1 2

t t t t t

MP if

MP if

MP if

MP if

MP if

λ

λ λ

λ λ

λ λ

λ ,

and has the following probabilities:

) (

) , , 2

Pr(MPt =− xt β λ =Φ λ1xt'β

) (

) (

) , , 1

Pr(MPt =− xt β λ =Φ λ2xt'β −Φ λ1xt'β (4) Pr(MPt =0xt,β,λ)=Φ(λ3xt'β)−Φ(λ2xt'β)

) (

) (

) , , 1

Pr(MPt = xt β λ =Φ λ4xt'β −Φ λ3xt'β )

( 1 ) , , 2

Pr(MPt = xt β λ = −Φ λ4xt'β ,

(24)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

where Φ is the cumulative normal distribution in the case of a probit model, or the cumulative logistic distribution in the case of a logit model. The threshold values

‘λ’s and the coefficients ‘β’s can then be estimated by maximising the following log likelihood function:

(5)

∑ ∑

= =

=

=

=

T

t j

i i

t jx y j

MP l

1 2

2

) ( 1 )) , , log(Pr(

) ,

(β λ β λ ,

where j is the ordered category from -2 to 2, and 1(yi = j) is an indicator function which takes 1 when yi = , and 0 otherwise. j

Using this procedure, Equation 1 will be estimated using quarterly data between 2001 Q1 and 2009 Q2. The dynamics of the model will be determined by a general-to- specific search procedure.

VI. Findings and analysis

Benchmark results

We use the estimations for the indicator with five values (from -2 to 2) as the benchmark results, presented in Table 4.6 In the basic specification with only growth and inflation when the official targets are used (Column 1 of Table 4), the coefficients on economic growth and inflation are highly significant, demonstrating the importance that the PBoC attaches to its legal mandate of maintaining stable economic growth and low inflation. Among the two targets, the policy response for economic growth is stronger than that for inflation.7 This suggests that the PBoC shows stronger reaction to each percentage-point deviation in economic growth from the official target than that for inflation. The stronger policy response to economic growth may suggest that real GDP growth is taken as a good summary indicator of economic developments, and monetary policy is believed to have a strong impact on it.

6 This and all other specifications have been estimated by both the probit and logit models, and the results are very similar. All the results presented are from the logit model estimation, which offers slightly better fit of the data.

(25)

Monetary policy also influences inflation. However, some volatile items in the consumer price index such as food may be influenced by non-monetary factors such as weather conditions, while utility prices are still subject to administrative controls in China. Under the circumstances, other means have been used to complement monetary policy in controlling inflation, and monetary response to inflation movements is thus milder. For example, in early 2008 when there were heightened concerns about inflation, measures were announced by the National Development and Reform Commission and State Council to stabilise prices.

The model has reasonable explanatory power. For 69.7% of the 33 observations, the implied monetary stance based on the estimated model correctly signals the actual stance.

Among the other economic objectives, monetary and credit growth, and unemployment, are largely not statistically significant, and often carry a wrong sign (Columns 2 - 4 of Table 4). The PBoC does not appear to directly react to changes in monetary conditions, or the employment situation.8

The results are broadly similar to the estimation using historical averages as targets (Columns 5 - 7 of Table 4). Both economic growth and inflation are important determinants of monetary stance, with growth being a more significant factor. The basic specification with only growth and inflation improves on the goodness of fit compared with that using the official targets. Monetary stance is correctly signalled in 75.8% of the cases. It is better at accurately signalling tightening stance, being correct in 86.3% of the time (Table 5). The success rate drops to 62.5% for signalling loosening stance, and one third for neutral stance.

The better predictive power of using historical averages in the estimation model may suggest that a rule of thumb in policymaking using historical averages may be a better description of the PBoC’s targets than the annual official announcements. This may be explained by the way official targets are set which is discussed earlier. For

7 The size of policy response to one target is calculated as the coefficient on the target multiplied by the standard deviation of the target.

8 It is possible the estimation is affected by poor unemployment data. They only take into account urban residents who are registered as being unemployed at local employment service agencies. Given the limited coverage, the statistics may not be representative of developments in the labour market.

(26)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

example, with the Central Government’s intention to regulate the growth impulse on the part of local governments, the growth target is typically set conservatively. As the outturns of growth almost always exceed the official targets (with the exception of 2008 Q4 – 2009 Q2 amidst the severe global recession), the latter may not be considered to be binding in policymaking. On the other hand, historical averages may be perceived to be more representative of the underlying growth potential of the economy, and thus be given more attention.

In contrast, the results from using the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend growth as the target are much weaker (Columns 8 - 10 of Table 4). The coefficient on the output gap is not always highly significant, and that of the CPI fails to have any significance.

This perhaps is not surprising. As observed earlier, deviations of economic indicators from the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend do not capture China’s economic cycles well.

Indeed, this may explain our general finding of stronger policy reaction to GDP growth which differs from that of He and Pauwels (2008). They show that the PBoC reacts more strongly towards deviations of inflation from the target than the output gap, where the output gap is derived from applying the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

Robustness check

We also undertake the estimation for the other two monetary stance indicators, one with seven values and the other three values (Tables 6 and 7). The major results from the estimation of the 5-value indicator are broadly born out by those for the 7-value and 3-value indicators. Importantly, real GDP growth and inflation are found to be the most important policy objectives, with a strong policy response to real GDP growth. Other policy objectives such as monetary and credit growth, and unemployment do not have significant impacts on monetary policy. Among the models using different sets of targets, the ones with historical averages as the target have the best fit for the data, while those with the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend growth are the poorest.

Also we have experimented with eight and 10 years as the window for calculating historical averages as monetary targets in estimating monetary reaction functions.

(27)

Again, the results are broadly similar as above. Most notably, using historical averages stays the best way of describing the PBoC’s policy targets.

While the major findings are robust, the explanatory power varies among the three different monetary stance indicators. The explanatory and predictive power rises as the number of values in an index declines, probably reflecting difficulties in differentiating the intensity of monetary stance. The model of the 7-value indicator has the lowest predictive power, making correct predictions in 59.4% of the cases in the benchmark specification with only growth and inflation included as policy objectives, and historical averages as the target set. That rises to 75.8% for the model of the 5-value indicator, and further to over 90.9% for the model of the 3-value indicator. Most notably, the model of the 3-value indicator is 100% correct in predicting tightening stance (Table 8). Also similar to the predictions of the model using the 5-value indicator, the success rate is lower for predicting loosening stance (87.5 percent), and the lowest for neutral stance (one third).

VI. Concluding remarks

The paper is the first attempt to follow a narrative approach to derive indicators of the monetary stance of the PBoC. This is motivated by the observation that the PBoC uses a wide range of monetary tools, including market- or non-market based, quantity- and price-based measures. Under the circumstances, using the benchmark interest rate – a measure of short-term policy rates often used to gauge central banks’

monetary stance – cannot fully capture monetary policy changes in China. Our approach is to utilise public records, specifically the PBoC’s Monetary Policy Reports and press releases of the MPC meeting to assess monetary stance. Based on the PBoC’s stated policy stance, assessments of risks on growth and inflation, and policy actions recorded in these official communications, a number of monetary stance indices are compiled to indicate the direction and intensity of monetary policy. These indices are particularly useful in capturing changes in monetary policy in the early 2000s when often non-market based monetary tools were used. In more recent years, they show more co-movements with the benchmark interest rate, which suggests that

(28)

China Economic Issues – Number 1/10, January 2010

market-, price-based monetary tools are being increasingly used in macroeconomic management.

Utilising these indicators, the determinants of the PBoC’s policy stance are investigated. Our estimated monetary reaction functions for the PBoC’s show that the key factors of monetary policy are economic growth and inflation, which are in fact the PBoC’s stated mandate. Of the two main policy objectives, the PBoC appears to react more strongly to deviations of growth from targets. Among the different targets considered for the key economic variables (including the official targets, historical averages, trend growth derived using the Hodrick-Prescott filter), historical averages appear to best describe the PBoC’s targets, probably because it is more binding than the conservatively set official targets and more transparent than targets derived purely from statistical methods.

This first study using the narrative approach to study monetary stance in China opens up a whole new perspective to macroeconomic and policy developments in China.

Conceivably, many aspects of China’s monetary economics can be usefully studied afresh using this alternative way of measuring monetary stance. The most obvious aspects are to examine the impact of monetary stance on macroeconomic developments, tracing the transmission channels and effects on economic indicators using these alternative monetary stance indicators.

About the Authors

Chang Shu is a Senior Manager and Brian Ng Assistant Manager in the External Department of the Hong Kong Monetary Authority. The authors would like to thank Li Cui and Dong He for helpful comments. The authors are grateful to Christina Li for research assistance. The authors are responsible for the views expressed in this article and any errors.

About the Series

China Economic Issues provide a concise analysis of current economic and financial issues in China. The series is edited by the External Department of the Hong Kong Monetary Authority.

數據

Table 1. PBoC’s monetary tools
Table 2a. 5-value monetary stance: coding criteria
Table 3.  Descriptive statistics
Table 4. Estimation results using 5-value monetary stance indicator
+5

參考文獻

相關文件

In these lessons, students will evaluate the impacts of genetic engineering on our daily life, and analyze the moral issues raised in its development, especially those related

Since huge quantities of transactions are involved in daily operations of a hotel, the accounting department always has to deal with complicated calculations which undoubtedly

• A formal usage policy and procedures should be in place, and appropriate security measures should be adopted to protect against the risks of using mobile computing and

Microphone and 600 ohm line conduits shall be mechanically and electrically connected to receptacle boxes and electrically grounded to the audio system ground point.. Lines in

It is based on the goals of senior secondary education and on other official documents related to the curriculum and assessment reform since 2000, including

The min-max and the max-min k-split problem are defined similarly except that the objectives are to minimize the maximum subgraph, and to maximize the minimum subgraph respectively..

– Successful monetary policy, then, requires that inflation expectations be kept under control... Central

Based on the observations and data collection of the case project in the past three years, the critical management issues for the implementation of