• 沒有找到結果。

庫藏股制度實施前後證券相關稅收的影響:家計單位投資行為與公司股利政策之分析(II)

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "庫藏股制度實施前後證券相關稅收的影響:家計單位投資行為與公司股利政策之分析(II)"

Copied!
41
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

行政院國家科學委員會專題研究計畫 成果報告

庫藏股制度實施前後證券相關稅收的影響:家計單位投資行

為與公司股利政策之分析(2/2)

計畫類別: 個別型計畫 計畫編號: NSC94-2416-H-004-005- 執行期間: 94 年 08 月 01 日至 95 年 07 月 31 日 執行單位: 國立政治大學財務管理學系 計畫主持人: 劉玉珍 報告類型: 完整報告 報告附件: 出席國際會議研究心得報告及發表論文 處理方式: 本計畫涉及專利或其他智慧財產權,2 年後可公開查詢

中 華 民 國 95 年 7 月 31 日

(2)

Taxes and Dividend Clientele:

Evidence from Trading and Ownership Structure

Yi-Tsung Lee* Yu-Jane Liu* Richard Roll** Avanidhar Subrahmanyam** July 8, 2006 JEL Classifications: G12, G35 Keywords: Dividends, clientele effect

Abstract

Previous support for a dividend clientele effect has been inferred mainly from asset pricing models, market price behavior on ex-dividend days, and other indirect phenomena. Although dividend clientele have been studied over several decades, their existence remains controversial. In this paper, we study the interaction of dividends and taxes by exploiting a unique dataset from Taiwan, where the capital gains tax is zero, and which categorizes individual investors by their likely tax bracket. We report how investors respond to changes in dividend payout policy and to what extent they hold heterogeneous portfolios. There is strong evidence of a clientele effect. Agents subject to high rates of taxation on dividends (and zero taxation on capital gains) tend to hold stocks with lower dividends and sell (buy) stocks that raise (lower) dividends. Agents in lower tax brackets behave in the opposite manner. When share repurchases became legal in Taiwan in 2000, many firms responded. Firms with higher concentrations of more heavily taxed shareholders were more apt to begin repurchase programs.

Lee Liu Roll Subrahmanyam

Address

National Chengchi University 64, Chi Nan Road., Sec. 2

Mucha, Taipei 11623 Taiwan, R.O.C.

The Anderson School at UCLA 110 Westwood Plaza Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481

U.S.A.

E-mail actytl@nccu.edu.tw finyjl@nccu.edu.tw rroll@Anderson.ucla.edu subra@Anderson.ucla.edu

Voice 886-2-2939-3091 1-310-825-6118 1-310-825-5355

(3)

Taxes and Dividend Clientele:

Evidence from Trading and Ownership Structure

Abstract

Previous support for a dividend clientele effect has been inferred mainly from asset pricing models, market price behavior on ex-dividend days, and other indirect phenomena. Although dividend clientele have been studied over several decades, their existence remains controversial. In this paper, we study the interaction of dividends and taxes by exploiting a unique dataset from Taiwan, where the capital gains tax is zero, and which categorizes individual investors by their likely tax bracket. We report how investors respond to changes in dividend payout policy and to what extent they hold heterogeneous portfolios. There is strong evidence of a clientele effect. Agents subject to high rates of taxation on dividends (and zero taxation on capital gains) tend to hold stocks with lower dividends and sell (buy) stocks that raise (lower) dividends. Agents in lower tax brackets behave in the opposite manner. When share repurchases became legal in Taiwan in 2000, many firms responded. Firms with higher concentrations of more heavily taxed shareholders were more apt to begin repurchase programs.

(4)

I. Dividends, Taxes, Asset Pricing and Clientele.

Whenever dividends and capital gains are differentially taxed, it seems plausible that

equity investors would arrange themselves into heterogeneous classes, or “clientele,” by

their effective tax brackets. In many countries, dividends are more heavily taxed than

capital gains, so highly taxed investors should favor firms with lower dividend payout

ratios, ceteris paribus. Investors subject to lower effective tax rates should behave in a

complementary fashion and thus favor firms with higher payout ratios.

Differential taxation of dividends might impact equilibrium asset prices. Rational

investors should be attracted only by after-tax returns, so it seems possible that firms with

higher dividend payout ratios might have higher pre-tax expected returns, ceteris paribus,

(unless firms can arrange themselves in perfect correspondence with clientele.) Brennan

[1970] was probably the first to derive a formal asset pricing theory that accommodated

the differential taxation of dividends and capital gains. Early empirical papers by Black

and Scholes [1974] and Litzenberger and Ramaswamy [1979], which reached different

conclusions, typify the controversy surrounding dividend taxation and asset pricing that

continues to the present day; see, for example, Litzenberger and Ramaswamy

[1980,1982], Fung [1981], Elton and Gruber [1970], Elton, Gruber, and Rentzler [1983],

Haugen, Senbet, and Talmor [1986], Blose and Martin [1992], Fama and French [1998],

Harris and Kemsley [1999], Naranjo, Nimalendran, and Ryngaert [2000], Demsey [2001],

(5)

Whether or not it has an impact on asset pricing, dividend taxation represents a

conundrum with respect to the financial policy of corporations: if firms can distribute

cash through lower-taxed methods such as share repurchase, why are dividends ever paid?

Black [1976] referred to this as the “dividend puzzle.”

Indirect evidence does suggest some sort of connection between dividend policy and

taxes. Firms appear to change payout ratios in response to changes in relative dividend

tax rates; (See Briston and Tomkins [1970], Bolster and Janjigian [1991], Papaioannou

and Savarese [1994], and Casey, et al. [1999].) Fama and French [2001] document a

secular decline in dividend paying American firms accompanied by an increase in the

rate of share repurchases. Although it is technically illegal for American firms to evade

dividend taxes, the tax authorities appear to be winking at the actual evasion. More

recently, the Bush administration succeeded in reducing the tax rate on dividends

dramatically, avowedly to encourage an increase in dividend payouts and also to reduce

any distortion caused by differential taxation.

Dividend clientele have been studied for several decades. They are part of the asset

pricing debate because heterogeneous clientele are implied by a dependence of expected

returns on dividend taxes.1 The opposite is not true; clientele could still exist even with no asset pricing effect of taxation. Without relying on asset pricing, Elton and Gruber

[1970] devised an ingenious test for the existence of clientele by comparing dividends

against price declines on dividend dates. For an investor to hold a stock over the

1

See Allen, Bernardo, and Welch (2000) and Allen and Michaely (2004) for theoretical models of dividend clientele.

(6)

dividend date, the ex-dividend price decline must be less than the dividend by an amount

that depends on the relative difference between the marginal effective dividend and

capital gains tax rates. Elton and Gruber find that dividends are generally larger than

ex-dividend date price declines. Booth and Johnston [1984] study the ex-day effect in

Canada, and find the ex-day return generally is smaller than the dividend level, indicating

a market preference for capital gains, which are not subject to tax in Canada. Nonetheless,

the Elton/Gruber test has been challenged on several grounds. 2

First, there is the practice of dividend “capture” and its impact, (see, e.g., Karpoff and

Walkling [1988] and Grammatikos [1989].) In dividend capture, a tax-paying investor

effectively enters into a repurchase agreement with a non tax-paying entity such as a

pension fund, selling a stock before the ex-dividend date and buying it back afterward. If

this practice were unfettered, it would tend to reduce or even eliminate the Elton/Gruber

ex-dividend effect, thereby making it unlikely to detect heterogeneous clientele even

when they actually exist. But there is a fetter: the “wash sale” rule, which dictates that a

sale followed soon by a repurchase of the same asset will be taxed at ordinary rates, not at

capital gains rates. It is unclear whether the wash sale rule is sufficient to materially

mitigate the impact of dividend stripping.

Eades, Hess, and Kim [1994] and Naranjo, Nimalendran, and Ryngaert [2000] find time

variation in the ex-day return behavior, with a regime shift around 1975, the year in

which minimum commissions were eliminated on the NYSE. They suggest the lower

2

Barclay [1987] finds that prior to the enactment of income taxes, prices appear to generally have fallen by the full amount of the dividend, supporting the notion that without taxes, investors view capital gains and dividends as close substitutes.

(7)

day return post-1975 is consistent with the notion that dividend capture trades (which are

subject to transaction costs) play a big role in determining the size of the ex-day return.

Michaely and Vila [1995] argue that the ex-day return is determined by the interaction of

multiple classes of investors in different tax brackets. Boyd and Jagannathan [1994]

show that such a multitude of classes along with dividend capturers leads to a

complicated non-linear relationship between the size of the dividend and the ex-day

return.

A second question about Elton and Gruber’s test arises from considerations of market

microstructure and/or information. For example, Bali and Hite [1998], and Frank and

Jagannathan [1998], argue that microstructure effects such as bid-ask bounce and a

minimum tick size will also assure that the dividend exceeds the ex-dividend price

decline on average. Siddiqi [1997] argues that the ex-dividend day return depends not

only on the differential taxes levied on dividends and capital gains, but also on the

transaction costs involved in executing dividend capture trades. Graham, Michaely, and

Roberts [2003] argue that ex-dividend day price drops have increased after

decimalization, suggesting that discreteness-related microstructure effects do not explain

the magnitude of such drops.

Kalay [1982] challenges Elton and Gruber’s original finding based on an argument that

arbitrage motivated trading clouds evidence of a clientele effect. He argues that

transaction cost bounds faced by arbitrageurs determine the extent of the ex-day price

(8)

costs are erroneous. Kalay [1984] responds in turn, claiming that the estimation error is

too small to affect his original inference.

In summary, these contributions taken in their entirety reveal the controversial nature of

dividend clientele. This controversy would be resolved by direct observation of either

investor portfolios or trading around dividend policy changes. If investors in higher

(lower) tax brackets hold fewer (more) stocks with high dividend payout ratios, the

existence of clientele would be proved. A corollary would find heavily (lightly) taxed

investors selling (buying) after a firm increases its payout ratio, and vice versa.

Heretofore, such direct observation has been difficult because neither portfolio holdings

nor trading has been available by investor tax bracket. Lewellen, et al. [1978], Scholz

[1992], Dhaliwal, Erickson, and Trezevant [1999], and Graham and Kumar [2003] are the

exceptions of which we are aware. The first paper possessed trading data for several

hundred clients of a single brokerage firm. They estimated taxation rates by a survey

questionnaire sent out to these individuals but were ultimately unable to find any

evidence of dividend clientele based on the survey responses concatenated with the

trading.

In contrast, Scholz [1992] did report evidence of dividend clientele. His data were based

on a sample of about 4,000 households in the 1983 Survey of Consumer Finances and he

was obliged to construct a rather elaborate econometric model to estimate the marginal

(9)

ownership by aggregate institutional ownership, which is found to increase after dividend

initiations, suggesting that tax-exempt institutions buy shares from tax-disadvantaged

individuals. In a related paper, Graham and Kumar [2003] use data on accounts at a

discount brokerage firm and find that low-income investors prefer high dividend yield

stocks.3

Conflicting results are reason enough for further research. Our paper uses data from

Taiwan that is comprehensive in its coverage of all individual traders and includes good

estimates of tax rates. Moreover, Taiwan offers an excellent laboratory for studying

clientele because the capital gains tax is zero and share repurchases were prohibited for

most of our sample period. If dividend clientele exist anywhere, Taiwan seems a likely

location.

3

Barclay, Holderness, and Sheehan [2003] observe that dividends are not higher in firms with significant corporate blockholders; which is evidence against dividend clientele. Related work includes Strickland [1996], Jain [1999], and Perez-Gonzalez [2000], who restrict attention to a subset of investors. Unlike Graham and Kumar [2003] and our work, they do not examine multiple classes of individual investors.

(10)

II. The Data.

Our data sources are the Taiwan Economic Journal (TEJ) data bank and the Taiwan Stock

Exchange (TWSE).

All orders executed on the TWSE from January 1, 1995 thorough December 31, 1999, a

period of 1,357 trading days, are included. The accompanying information discloses

whether an order is buyer- or seller-initiated and it identifies the initiator. There are no

officially designated market makers on the TWSE. To retain confidentiality, we identify

traders as individuals or institutions and then break down these categories further into

institutions and groups of individuals with different wealth levels (and hence with

different tax incidence).

There are two main types of institutional investors in Taiwan, domestic and foreign.

Domestic institutions include government entities, financial institutions (securities firms

and banks), corporations, tax-exempt institutions, and mutual funds. During our sample

period, individual investors did more than 90% of the trading by dollar volume. Foreign

institutions accounted for only 2% of the trading.

The TEJ data bank contains two kinds of ownership information each year from 1995

through 2003 inclusive. One kind provided the fractions of shares held by different types

of institutions and by individual investors. The other kind gives the number of shares

(11)

1-5 lots, 5-10, 10-15, 15-20, 20-30, 30-50, 50-100, 100-200, 200-400, 400-600, 600-800,

800-1,000 lots, 1,000 lots and above. Under the assumption that most institutions

generally hold large positions, at least 1,000 lots, we can estimate the proportion of a

firm’s shares held by “wealthy” individuals as the fraction of shares held in lots above a

given size by all investors, less the fraction held by institutions.

The TEJ data bank also contains supplementary information such as daily trading

volumes, daily prices, cash dividends, dates of dividends announcements, earnings per

share, book values, and the number of shares outstanding.

In Taiwan, the maximum ordinary income tax rate is 40% for individuals, 25% for

domestic tax-paying institutions, 20% for foreigners, and zero for nonprofit organizations.

The highest individual rate, 40%, is the marginal rate for incomes above three million

Taiwan dollars (about US$101,351.4) For all investors, the tax rate on capital gains is zero.

In the early years of our sample, 1995 through August 2000, share repurchases were

prohibited in Taiwan. Consequently, a company that wished to distribute cash was

obliged to do so in the form of taxable dividends. This prohibition was removed in

September 2000, so we are able to study the behavior of firms as they became able to

evade dividend taxes.

4

Based on an average exchange rate during our sample period of $NT29.6/US$. In January 2004, the Taiwan dollar had fallen to $NT33.4/US$, so the highest marginal tax rate became effective at an income level of approximately US$89,820.

(12)

To estimate marginal tax rates for individuals, we used both data sources. From the

TWSE, we add together all the buys and sells for a particular individual trader over the

entire sample (i.e., 1995-1999.) An individual trader above the 75th percentile of the aggregate trading distribution is denoted a “wealthy” individual while anyone below the

75th percentile is a “less-wealthy” individual. Admittedly, this does not isolate traders’ marginal tax brackets directly, but it seems likely to be closely related.

Alternatively, we used the ownership structure of each traded company provided annually

by the Taiwan Economic Journal and described above. We used the fraction of total firm

shares owned by institutions of various types and also the fraction of total shares owned

by individuals who own at least 1,000 lots (i.e., 1,000,000 shares), less than 100 lots, and

less than 10 lots. Again, individuals who own a million shares would likely be in higher

tax brackets than individuals who own less than 100,000 or 10,000 shares.5

5

As a justification for our tax proxy based on ownership, we use data for 1998 and 1999 from the Ministry of Finance in Taiwan to relate average share holdings of households with their effective tax brackets. The shareholdings increase monotonically with the tax bracket. Thus, the [effective tax rate range, average shareholdings in lots] pairs for different tax brackets are [0%, 35.6], [0%-13%, 35.6],[13%-21%,66.7], [21%-30%, 200.1], [>30%, 1136.7]. While such categorization is not possible for the trade-based proxy, it appears reasonable to assume that wealthier investors with larger shareholdings will receive larger liquidity shocks (or income flows) and thus will submit larger orders. For details, please see appendix.

(13)

III. Empirical Results.

III.A. Dividends, trading behavior and ownership structure.

Summary information about dividend behavior in the no-repurchase period (1995-1999)

is shown in Table 1. Panels A and B list all the dividend announcements by Taiwanese

firms in these five years, Panel A for levels and Panel B for changes in dividends. The

vast majority of announcements are for no change in the dividend, 701 out of 1,064.

Dividend increases and decreases are roughly equal in number, which is probably

unusual and attributable to the overall bear market of this calendar period.

When dividends are not zero, dividend changes are relatively large. The right side of

Panel B shows that mean dividend decreases per share are actually larger in absolute

value than the corresponding mean dividend. Similarly, the standard deviations of

dividend changes are only moderately smaller than the standard deviations of dividends

(for non-zero dividends.)

As shown in Panel A of Table 1, most of the no-change announcements must have been

for firms that paid no dividend at all, for 762 out of 1,064 announced a zero dividend.

This is also indicated by the fact that the median dividend is zero for the no-change

(14)

Table 2 presents some summary information about the owners of stocks in Taiwan. It

shows that wealthy individuals own about 35% of the average firm’s outstanding shares

while institutions own about 31%. Individuals with lower wealth levels own the

remainder. Individuals who own less than 100 lots (100,000 shares) own about 20% of

the total. Individuals who have more than 100 lots but less than 1,000 own the rest.

Among institutions, corporations predominate, with almost 19% of the total on average.

Tax-exempt institutions have about seven percent.

Table 3 provides a first look at how various investor types react to dividend changes. For

institutions, wealthy individuals, and less-wealthy individuals, (based on TWSE trading

data) we compute the total purchases less sales for the firms in question during the 30

days prior to a dividend announcement and in the 30 days subsequent to the

announcement. In each trader class and period, we then tabulate the fraction of traders

who bought more shares than they sold and then divided this by the fraction with positive

net buying for all traders. For example, in the 30-day window before dividend increases,

wealthy individuals who were net buyers constitute 62.74% of all traders who were net

buyers.

Institutions as a group display an insignificant response to dividend changes, but

individuals appear to respond in the direction predicted by the clientele hypothesis.

Wealthy individuals decrease (increase) their net buying after dividend increases

(decreases) while less-wealthy individuals do just the opposite. All four responses are

(15)

These results are buttressed by the cross-sectional regressions in Table 4, which use the

alternative definition of wealth based on the TEJ ownership data. There is a strong

negative relation between dividend increases and the proportion of shares held by

wealthy individuals. This relation has the opposite sign (positive) for medium- and

lower-wealth individuals and the significance is higher for the former. All these patterns

are completely consistent with the existence of dividend clientele.

In contrast to individuals, institutions do not seem to respond very much to changes in

dividends. In Table 4, institutions as a whole show no significance. When broken into

various institutional types (Panel B) only foreign institutions seem to have a significant

response to dividend increases. Their response is positive. Recall that foreign

institutions are subject to a flat 20% tax rate in Taiwan, half the highest marginal tax rate

for individuals and probably somewhat closer to medium- or lower-wealth individuals.

Surprisingly, even lower-taxed institutions such as government entities and tax-exempt

organizations, which might have been expected to absorb shares sold by wealthy

individuals after dividend increases, display no statistical significance at all.

Table 5 gives further evidence of the relation between dividends and clientele by

tabulating ownership structure by firm dividend categories, zero dividend payers,

dividend payers less than the median level (“small” payers,) and those payers of “large”

(16)

based on cash dividends per share while Panel B uses payout ratios (i.e.,

dividends/earnings.)

Institutions as a whole seem to like higher dividends and dislike firms that pay no

dividends at all. Wealthy individuals appear to have the opposite preferences. For

example, wealthy individuals own about 36 percent of the zero dividend paying firms and

only 30% of firms paying relatively “high” dividends. For both institutions and wealthy

individuals, these patterns are statistically significant. For medium- and lower-wealth

individuals, there is no discernible pattern.

Among institutional types, both tax exempts and corporations significantly prefer higher

dividends per share. They also prefer higher payout ratios (Panel B) and are joined in

this preference by financial institutions. Government entities6 and foreign institutions show some preference for lower but positive dividends per share and payout ratios. This

suggests the possibility of several clientele, highly taxed individuals who prefer low or

zero dividends, very low-taxed entities such as tax exempts who prefer firms with high

dividends, and medium-taxed groups such as foreign institutions who eschew both

dividend extremes and concentrate more on medium-level dividend payers.

6

The government is tax exempt but its motivation is not clear. Some of the listed companies were in the process of privatizations during our sample period but the government still owned a modest number of shares. It seems doubtful that the government would sell low dividend payers and buy high payers just to take advantage of its tax exemption.

(17)

III.B. Share repurchasing.

Beginning in September 2000, Taiwanese firms were allowed to repurchase shares for

cash. Since the tax rate on capital gains is zero, this relaxation of the rules effectively

allows firms to help their investors evade dividend taxes entirely. We thought that this

might materially alter the payout policies of Taiwanese firms and that firms with more

highly taxed shareholders would be more likely to begin a program of share repurchases.

The legalization of share repurchases appears to have had a material impact on the

behavior of some firms. As shown in Table 6, more than forty percent of all firms (166

out of 394) actually repurchased shares during 2000-2003 once they were allowed to do

so. Of these, 83 firms had been zero dividend payers in the 1995-1999 pre-repurchase

era while 83 had been previous positive dividend payers.

Among the previous positive payers, 43 (23.2%) stopped paying dividends entirely, 38

(20.5%) reduced dividends and repurchased shares, while 45 (24.3%) repurchased shares

even though they also increased dividends. This seems to reveal an inclination by some

previous positive payers to substitute share repurchases for dividends and perhaps to

retard dividend growth in favor of repurchasing.

Taxation is not, of course, the only determinant of dividend policy. For example, we also

see in Table 6 that 65 firms that had been paying dividends (35.1%) both decreased

(18)

on hard times or discovered some promising new investment projects. Perhaps for the

opposite reasons, roughly 38% of the previous zero dividend payers (i.e., 79 of 209)

began paying dividends after repurchasing was allowed. Of these, almost 20% both

repurchased and paid positive dividends. Again, if non-tax considerations prompted an

initiation of cash distributions for previous non-payers, the fact that more than half also

made share repurchases seems to reveal an effort to minimize taxes for shareholders.

To test whether a firm’s ownership structure influences the propensity to engage in share

repurchases, we begin by constructing a firm-specific measure of shareholder tax

incidence from the TEJ ownership data. Averaging over the pre-share repurchase period,

1995-1999, this measure is the difference in the proportion of shares owned by wealthy

shareholders (variously defined as those holding at least 1000 lots, 600 lots or 400 lots)

and the proportion owned by less wealthy shareholders (holding less than 10 lots.) This

measure is denoted “tax incidence” in the tables to follow.

Tax incidence is included along with other possible determinants of share repurchasing

behavior (i.e., as control variables) in a logit model whose dependent variable is 1.0 if the

firm actually did make a share repurchase during 2000-2003, and otherwise zero. Since

initial runs suggested nonlinearity in the relation between repurchasing and tax incidence,

both linear and quadratic terms are included for the latter variable.

The results, presented in Table 7, indicate that firms previously paying dividends are

(19)

highly taxed, for two of the three tax incidence measures. However, there is no

significant effect of tax incidence among firms that previously did not pay dividends.

The control variables include market/book ratio, returns over the previous six months

(using the previous three- and twelve-month returns made no substantive difference in the

results), and returns one year after the repurchase for firms that did repurchase and one

year after repurchasing was permitted for firms that did not.7

Motivation for the controls comes from previous findings. For example, Vermaelen

[1981] and Stephens and Weisbach [1998] suggest that past returns could matter because

firms may repurchase stocks when managers believe their stock prices have suffered an

unwarranted decline and are now undervalued. But contrary to this idea, past returns are

significantly positive for previous dividend payers, which seems to suggest that some

repurchases are motivated by previous good times.

For a similar reason, the post repurchase return was included because managers might

repurchase shares to exploit undervaluation (e.g., Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam

[1998]). In fact, post repurchase returns are is consistently significant and positive, thus

supporting the undervaluation hypothesis. The effect is larger and more significant for

previous dividend payers.

7

We also included the dividend payout ratio in some unreported logits. The payout ratio is a direct measure of dividends versus capital gains, so it might control for low dividend-paying firm substituting share repurchasing for dividends (Jagannathan, Stephens and Weisbach [2000]). But the payout ratio might also proxy for the tax incidence of a firm’s shareholders, so we only report results without it. The results are very similar, whether or not the payout ratio is included. Details are available from the authors upon request.

(20)

The market to book ratio is included because it should be related to investment

opportunities. One would expect a lower lever of cash disbursements, ceteris paribus,

with better growth opportunities. The sign of M/B is negative as expected, but the

coefficient is not statistically significant.

To provide some further tests of significance for the tax clientele effect while controlling

for cash disbursements, Table 8 examines the impact of shareholder wealth (and thus

their implicit tax bracket) on the propensity to repurchase shares when such activity

became legal in Taiwan. As in Table 7, the main explanatory variable of interest is the

one that measures tax incidence. Separate tests are conducted for firms that increased,

decreased, and maintained the same dividend during the repurchase era.

Table 8 shows there is a tendency to repurchase shares when stockholders are in higher

tax brackets. The coefficients of tax incidence are positive in all cases and are marginally

significant for two of the three measures of tax incidence among dividend decreasing

firms, and for one of the three measures among dividend increasing firms.

Repurchases are very likely to be followed by high returns over the subsequent year,

again an indication that managers tend to engage in share repurchases when they believe

(correctly) that shares are undervalued. This effect is largest for dividend decreasing

firms. One is tempted to think that managers of these firms are particularly adept because

they evidently can judge valuations well but also seem to adopt more tax-advantaged

(21)

Previous returns have a significantly positive influence on repurchasing only for firms

that make no change in cash dividends paid. Such firms experienced good times before

the repurchasing era and they responded sensibly with cash disbursements that avoided

taxation.

(22)

IV. Conclusion.

Our evidence supports the view that Taiwanese shareholders arrange themselves into

dividend clientele. Highly taxed individuals tend to hold firms that pay low or zero

dividends and they trade out of firms that increase dividends. The opposite is true of

individuals and institutions in lower tax brackets.

When share repurchasing became legal in Taiwan (in September 2000), firms with higher

concentrations of highly taxed shareholders were significantly more likely to commence

repurchase programs. More than forty percent of Taiwan firms actually engaged in share

repurchasing after it became possible. A significant fraction (23%) of firms that had

previously been paying dividends ceased paying them entirely and 21% reduced

dividends and began repurchasing. The tendency to engage in these practices is

significantly related to the proportion of a firm’s shareholders in higher tax brackets.

We have not attempted to ascertain whether the unequivocal existence of dividend

clientele in Taiwan has an influence on asset pricing. This would depend on whether the

arrangement of dividend policies across individual firms is isomorphic to the tax

arrangement of shareholders, a difficult question but one that is certainly worthy of

continuing research.

(23)

References

Allen, Franklin, Antonio Bernardo, and Ivo Welch, 2000, “A Theory of Dividends Based on Tax Clientele,” Journal of Finance 55, 2499-2536

Allen, Franklin, and Roni Michaely, 2004, “Payout Policy,” forthcoming in North-Holland Handbook of Economics, edited by George Constantinides, Milton Harris, and René Stulz.

Bali, Rakesh, and Gailen L. Hite, 1998, “Ex Dividend Day Stock Price Behavior: Discreteness or Tax-Induced Clienteles?,” Journal of Financial Economics 47, 127-159.

Barclay, Michael J., 1987, “Dividends, Taxes and Common Stock Prices: The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of Common Stock Prices Before the Income Tax,” Journal of Financial Economics 47, 127-159.

Barclay, Michael J., Clifford Holderness, and Dennis Sheehan, 2003, “Dividends and Dominant Corporate Shareholders,” working paper, University of Rochester.

Bell, Leonie, and Tim Jenkinson, 2002, “New Evidence of the Impact of Dividend

Taxation and on the Identity of the Marginal Investor,” Journal of Finance 57, 1321-1346.

Black, Fischer, 1976, “The Dividend Puzzle,” Journal of Portfolio Management 2, 5-8.

Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes, 1974, “The Effects of Dividend Yield and Dividend Policy on Common Stock Prices and Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics 1, 1-22.

Blose, Laurence E., and John D. Martin, 1992, “Capital Gains Preference and the Prices of Dividend Paying Securities: A Test of the Dividend Tax Aversion Hypothesis,” International Review of Economics and Finance 1, 73-87.

Bolster, Paul J., and Vahan Janjigian, 1991, “Dividend Policy and Valuation Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986,” National Tax Journal 44, 511-518.

Booth, L. D. and D. J. Johnston, 1984, “The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of Canadian Stock Prices: Tax Changes and Clientele Effects,” Journal of Finance 39, 457-476.

Boyd, John, and Ravi Jagannathan, 1994, “Ex-dividend Price Behavior of Common Stocks,” Review of Financial Studies 7, 711-741.

Brennan, Michael J., 1970, “Taxes, Market Valuation and Corporate Financial Policy,” National Tax Journal 23, 417-427.

Briston, R. J., and C. R. Tomkins, 1970, “The Impact of the Introduction of Corporation Tax upon the Dividend Policies of United Kingdom Companies,” Economic Journal 80, 617-637.

(24)

Casey, K. Mike, Dwight C. Anderson, Hani I. Mesak, and Ross N. Dickens, 1999, “Examining the Impact of the 1986 Tax Reform Act on Corporate Dividend Policy: A New Methodology,” Financial Review 34, 33-46.

Daniel, Kent, David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 1998, “Investor Psychology and Security Market Under- and Overreactions,” Journal of Finance 53, 1839-1885.

Demsey, Mike, 2001, “Investor Tax Rationality and the Relationship Between Dividend Yields and Equity Returns: An Explanatory Note,” Journal of Banking and Finance 25, 1681-1686.

Dhaliwal, Dan S., Merle Erickson, and Robert Trezevant, 1999, “A Test of the Theory of Tax Clienteles for Dividend Policies,” National Tax Journal 52, 179-194.

Eades, Ken, Patrick Hess, and E. Han Kim, 1994, “Time-series Variation in Dividend Pricing,” Journal of Finance 49, 1617-1638.

Elton, Edwin J., and Martin J. Gruber, 1970, “Marginal Stockholder Tax Rates and the Clientele Effect,” Review of Economics and Statistics 52, 68-74.

Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber, and Joel Rentzler, 1984, “The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of Stock Prices: A Reexamination of the Clientele Effect: A Comment,” Journal of Finance 39, 551-556.

Elton, Edwin, Martin Gruber, and Joel Rentzler, 1983, “A Simple Examination of the Empirical Relationship Between Dividend Yields and Deviations from the CAPM,” Journal of Banking and Finance 7, 135-146.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1998, “Taxes, Financing Decisions, and Firm Value,” Journal of Finance 53, 819-843.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 2002, “Testing Trade-Off and Pecking Order Predictions About Dividends and Debt,” Review of Financial Studies 15, 1-33.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 2001, “Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay?,” Journal of Financial Economics 60, 3-43.

Frank, Murray, and Ravi Jagannathan, 1998, “Why do Stock Prices drop by Less than the Value of the Dividend? Evidence From a Country Without Taxes,” Journal of Financial Economics 47, 161-188.

Fung, William K. H., 1981, “Taxes, Clientele Effect of Dividend and Risk, Return Linearity,” Journal of Banking and Finance 5, 405-424.

(25)

Gentry, William M., Deen Kemsley, and Christopher J. Mayer, 2003, “Dividend Taxes and Share Prices: Evidence from Real Estate Investment Trusts,” Journal of Finance 58, 1 (February), 261-282.

Graham, John, and Alok Kumar, 2003, “Do Dividend Clienteles Exist? Evidence on Dividend Preferences of Retail Investors,” working paper, University of Notre Dame.

Graham, John, Roni Michaely, and Michael Roberts, 2003, “Do Price Discreteness and Transactions Costs Affect Stock Returns? Comparing Ex-Dividend Pricing Before and After Decimalization,” Journal of Finance 58, 2611-2635.

Grammatikos, Theoharry, 1989, “Dividend Stripping, Risk Exposure, and the Effect of the 1984 Tax Reform Act on the Ex-Dividend Day Behavior,” Journal of Business 62, 157-174.

Harris, Trevor, and Deen Kemsley, 1999, “Dividend Taxation in Firm Valuation: New Evidence,” Journal of Accounting Research 37, 275-292.

Haugen, Robert A., Lemma W. Senbet, and Eli Talmor, 1986, “Debt, Dividends, and Taxes: Equilibrium Conditions for Simultaneous Tax Neutrality of Debt and Dividend Policies,” Research in Finance 6, 1-28.

Hubbard, Jeff, and Roni Michaely, 1997, “Do Investors Ignore Dividend Taxation? A Reexamination of the Citizens Utilities Case,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32, 117-135.

Jagannathan, Murali, Clifford P. Stephens, and Michael J. Weisbach, 2000, “Financial Flexibility and the Choice Between Dividends and Stock Repurchases,” Journal of Financial Economics 57, 355-384.

Jain, Ravi, 1999, “Institutional investors do not prefer dividends: Individual investors do,” working Paper, Temple University, Philadelphia, PA.

Kalay, Avner, 1982, “The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of Stock Prices: A Re-Examination of the Clientele Effect,” Journal of Finance 37, 1059-1070.

Kalay, Avner, 1984, “The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior Of Stock Prices: A Reexamination of the Clientele Effect: A Reply,” Journal of Finance 39, 557-561.

Karpoff, Jonathan, and Ralph A. Walkling, 1988, “Short-term trading around ex-dividend days – Additional Evidence,” Journal of Financial Economics 21, 291-298.

Lewellen, Wilbur G., Kenneth L. Stanley, Ronald C. Lease, and Gary G. Schlarbaum, 1978, “Some Direct Evidence on the Dividend Clientele Phenomenon,” Journal of Finance 33, 1385-1399.

(26)

Litzenberger, Robert H., and Krishna Ramaswamy, 1979, “The Effect of Personal Taxes and Dividends on Capital Asset Prices: Theory and Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Financial Economics 7, 163-196.

Litzenberger, Robert H., and Krishna Ramaswamy, 1980, “Dividends, Short Selling Restrictions, Tax-Induced Investor Clienteles and Market Equilibrium,” Journal of Finance 35, 469-482.

Litzenberger, Robert H., and Krishna Ramaswamy, 1982, “The Effects of Dividends on Common Stock Prices: Tax Effects or Information Effects?,” Journal of Finance 37, 429-443.

Michaely, Roni, and Jean-Luc Vila, 1995, “Investors’ Heterogeneity, Prices, and Volume Around the Ex-dividend Day,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 30, 171-198.

Naranjo, Andy, M. Nimalendran, and Mike Ryngaert, 1998, “Stock Returns, Dividend Yields, and Taxes,” Journal of Finance 53, 2029-2057.

Naranjo, Andy, M. Nimalendran, and Mike Ryngaert, 2000, “Time Variation of Ex-Dividend Day Stock Returns and Corporate Ex-Dividend Capture: Reexamination,” Journal of Finance 55, 2357-2372.

Papaioannou, George J., and Craig M. Savarese, 1994, “Corporate Dividend Policy Response to the Tax Reform Act Of 1986,” Financial Management 23, 56-63.

Perez-Gonzalez, Francisco, 2001, “Large Shareholders and Dividends: Evidence from U.S. Tax Reforms,” working paper, Columbia University.

Scholz, John Karl, 1992, “A Direct Examination of the Dividend Clientele Hypothesis,” Journal of Public Economics 49, 261-286.

Siddiqi, Mazhar A., 1997, “Using Ex-day Returns to Separate the Tax and Information Effects of Dividend Changes,” Journal of Economics and Finance 21, 83-92.

Stephens, Clifford P., and Michael J. Weisbach, 1998, “Actual Share Reacquisitions in Open-Market Repurchase Programs,” Journal of Finance 53, 313-334.

Strickland, Deon, 1996, “Determinants of Institutional Ownership: Implications for Dividend Clienteles,” working paper, Ohio State University.Vermaelen, Theo, 1981. “Common Stock Repurchases and Market Signaling: An Empirical Study,” Journal of Financial Economics 9, 139-183.

(27)

Table 1. Dividends for Taiwan Firms, 1995-1999

Dividend information from the Taiwan Economic Journal (a data bank) is reported for the period January 1995 through December 1999. There is no tax on capital gains in Taiwan and firms were not allowed repurchase shares during this period. In Panel A, sample firms are grouped by the level of dividends on each dividend announcement date; zero or non-zero, less than or equal to first quartile of all dividend-announcements, greater than or equal to the third quartile, less than or greater than the median. Columns four to six report the mean, median and standard deviation of dividends per share within each group of firm-announcements. The means, medians and standard deviation of changes in dividends from the previous announcement are reported in the last three columns. Panel B classifies firms into three announcement categories: dividend increases, dividend decreases and no change. Columns four to six give the dividend levels per share after the change while the last three columns give the corresponding statistics for changes from the previous announcement.

Number of Dividends per share Changes in dividends per share

Firms

Announce-ments Mean Median

Standard

Deviation Mean Median

Standard Deviation Panel A. Dividend Levels

No Dividends 293 762 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.035 0.000 0.104

Dividends greater than zero 146 302 0.368 0.333 0.247 0.107 0.096 0.291

Dividends in lower quartile 56 78 0.146 0.155 0.038 -0.006 0.032 0.210

Dividends in upper quartile 49 76 0.684 0.584 0.279 0.233 0.167 0.409

Dividends below median 95 145 0.199 0.200 0.067 0.031 0.050 0.207

Dividends at or above median8 92 157 0.524 0.474 0.251 0.177 0.148 0.337

Panel B. Dividend Changes

Dividend Increases 125 183 0.398 0.333 0.277 0.272 0.250 0.219

Dividend Decreases 125 180 0.148 0.000 0.200 -0.245 -0.220 0.168

No Change 288 701 0.017 0.000 0.085 0.000 0.000 0.000

8

There are 39 announcements exactly at the median, which explains the asymmetry in numbers “below” and “at or above” the median.

(28)

Table 2. The Ownership Structure of Taiwan Stocks

Panel A presents aggregate ownership by investor type (institutions, wealthy individuals who own at least 1000 lots, medium-wealth individuals who own less than 100 lots, and lower-wealth individuals who own less than 10 lots). One lot is 1000 shares. Panel B reports shares held by classes of institutions. The mean and medians are taken over all individual firm-years, (i.e., all firms over 1995-2003.) The percentages total less than 100% because investors are not included if they own more than 100 but less than 1000 lots.

Panel A: Ownership structure by Institutions and by Individuals with different wealth levels

Means Medians Shares (millions) (% ) Shares (millions) % Institutions 199.77 30.73 69.412 28.37 Wealthy Individuals (>1000 lots) 222.89 35.08 78.848 32.15 Medium-Wealth Individuals (<100 lots) 108.15 20.33 43.892 17.22 Lower-Wealth Individuals (<10 lots) 47.10 9.06 19.631 7.38

Panel B: Ownership breakdown by type of institution

Government 12.16 1.00 0.00 0.00 Financial Institutions 15.44 1.73 0.70 0.24 Corporations 108.54 18.92 41.17 14.56 Mutual Funds 7.05 1.49 0.25 0.07 Foreign Institutions 0.39 0.20 0.00 0.00 Tax-exempt Institutions 56.19 7.41 6.76 2.32

(29)

Table 3. Trading before and after Dividends Increases/Decreases by Investor Category This table reports the relative net share purchasing by three types

of investors around announcements of dividend increases and decreases. Shares purchased and sold by each trader are recorded during two event windows, days –30 to -1 and +1 to +30 on either side of a dividend announcement on day zero. If purchases exceed sales, the trader is counted as a net buyer. Then, the fraction of net buyers within each investor category is taken as a percentage relative to the fraction of net buyers over all categories.

Type of traders Before After Difference t-value p-value

Dividend Increases: 183 observations

Institutions 0.549 0.581 0.033 0.863 0.389

Wealthy Individuals 62.74 61.41 -1.333 -2.57 0.011

Less-Wealthy Individuals 36.71 38.01 1.301 2.49 0.013

Dividend Decreases: 180 observations

Institutions 0.634 0.628 -0.006 -0.111 0.912

Wealthy Individuals 61.51 62.87 1.361 2.51 0.013

(30)

Table 4. Dividends and Changes in Ownership Structure

For Taiwan during 1995-1999, changes in dividends are related to changes in the ownership of various investor groups. In Panel A, the independent variable is the announced change (first difference) in cash dividends per share, while the separate dependent variables are first differences (from before the announcement until afterward) in the proportions of shares held by Institutions, Wealthy individuals (who own more than 1000 lots), Medium-Wealth individuals (<100 lots), and Lower-Wealth individuals (<10 lots), respectively. A lot is 1,000 shares. Panel B’s dependent variables are changes in the percentages of shares owned by various types of institutions. The .1, .05, and .01 levels of significance are indicated by *, **, and *** respectively. Adjusted R-squares are low, only one to two percent, even in significant regressions.

Panel A: Change in Ownership: Institutions and Individuals

Panel B: Change in Ownership: Type of Institution

Intercept Slope Intercept Slope

Institutions 0.594 -0.819 Government 0.073 0.226

t-value 1.44 -0.63 t-value 0.82 0.81

Wealthy Individuals (>1000 lots)

-2.660** -7.136*

Financial

Institutions -0.063 0.181

t-value -2.16 -1.86 t-value -0.66 0.6

Medium-Wealth Individuals (<100 lots) 0.561 2.459** Corporations 0.281 0.210

t-value 1.44 2.03 t-value 0.42 0.1

Lower-Wealth Individuals (<10 lots)1.658***5.044*** Mutual Funds -0.312 -1.190*

t-value 2.73 2.76 t-value -1.46 -1.78 Foreign Institutions 0.155 1.723** t-value 0.66 2.34 Tax-exempt Institutions 0.689 -0.019 t-value 0.99 -0.01

(31)

Table 5. Dividends and Ownership structure for Taiwan, 1995-1999 inclusive

Using dividends (Panel A) and payout ratios (Panel B), Taiwan companies are classified into non-paying firms, and, among firms paying dividends, those paying less than the median and those paying greater than or equal to the median. The payout ratio is the total dividend divided by net income. The proportion of shares held by each type of investor is tabulated after dividend announcements in each year, then averaged across the five sample years. Investor types include institutions (as a whole and broken down into type), wealthy individuals (who own at least 1000 lots), medium wealth individuals (<100 lots), and lower wealth individuals (<10 lots.) One lot is 1,000 shares. Column five gives an F- test that the same proportions are held in all firms regardless of dividend policy, while column six gives an F-test for the proportions held in non-paying firms and firms whose payouts are greater than the median. The 0.1, 0.05, and 0.01 significance levels are denoted by *, **, and *** respectively.

Panel A

Dividend Payments F-Tests

None Below Median Above Median All three Groups None vs. > Median Wealthy Individuals (>1000) 36.12 31.30 30.04 6.15*** 8.58*** Medium-Wealth Individuals (<100) 21.07 18.03 18.66 3.41** 2.90* Lower-Wealth Individuals (<10) 9.24 8.00 8.36 2.54* 1.85 All Institutions 29.26 38.46 40.92 29.19*** 42.45*** Government 0.85 2.12 0.93 4.20** 0.04 Financial Institutions 1.74 2.38 2.17 2.03 1.45 Corporations 18.40 20.52 24.35 7.44*** 14.40*** Mutual Funds 1.83 1.81 1.12 2.94* 5.68** Foreign Institutions 0.02 0.16 0.00 3.45* 0.43 Tax-exempt Institutions 6.42 11.47 12.35 22.18*** 32.97***

(32)

Table 5. Dividends and Ownership structure for Taiwan, 1995-1999 inclusive, (continued)

Panel B

Payout Ratios F-Tests

Zero Below Median Above Median All three Groups Zero vs. > Median Wealthy Individuals (1000) 36.12 32.03 28.64 7.56*** 13.04*** Lower-Wealth Individuals (10) 9.24 7.38 8.84 3.49* 0.38 Medium-Wealth Individuals (100) 21.07 16.40 20.45 5.73** 0.19* All Institutions 29.26 40.37 39.40 29.91*** 31.13*** Government 0.85 2.15 0.91 4.42** 0.03 Financial Institutions 1.74 1.87 2.73 3.74** 6.91*** Corporations 18.40 21.46 23.57 6.40*** 10.99*** Mutual Funds 1.83 1.96 0.98 4.50** 8.18*** Foreign Institutions 0.02 0.16 0.00 3.44** 0.42 Tax-exempt Institutions 6.42 12.77 11.20 23.24*** 20.89***

(33)

Table 6. Dividends and the Legalization of Stock Repurchases

The table examines firm dividend policies after Taiwan legalized stock repurchases in September, 2000. Firms are classified as non-paying and paying based on actual dividends during 1995-1999, before stock repurchases were allowed. Panels A reports whether dividends were zero or positive during the repurchase period and gives the mean dividend per share. Panel B provides the mean change in dividends per share before and after stock repurchasing was allowed. Some firms that were part of the sample in previous tables were delisted during after 2000.

Panel A. Dividend levels after September 2000 Dividends before Repurchase Period

Zero Positive Dividends during Repurchase Period N 9 (%) Mean Dividend N (%) Mean Dividend Zero 130 62.20 0 43 23.24 0 Positive 79 37.80 0.292 142 76.76 0.528

Panel B. Dividend changes after September 2000

Dividends before Repurchase Period

Zero Positive Shares Repurchased Dividends during Repurchase Period N (%) Dividend Change N (%) Dividend Change Increase 41 19.62 0.219 45 24.32 0.297 Yes Decrease/NC10 42 20.10 0 38 20.54 -0.267 Increase 38 18.18 0.370 37 20.00 0.466 No Decrease/NC 88 42.11 0 65 35.14 -0.299 9 Number of firms. 10

(34)

Table 7. Ownership Structure, Prior Dividend Policy, and the Propensity to Repurchase Shares

Share repurchases were allowed in Taiwan beginning in September 2000. This table examines whether the repurchase policies of individual firms depend on their ownership structure. The sample is divided into non-paying and dividend-paying firms for the five years prior to September 2000. A logit model is estimated with dependent variable equal 1.0 or zero depending on whether a firm did or did not engage in at least one share repurchase during 2000 to 2003. The main explanatory variable is a proxy for the tax incidence of firm shareholders. It is the difference of the proportion of shares held by wealthy individual shareholders (those holding at least 1000 lots, 600 lots or 400 lots in three separate logit models) and the proportion held by less wealthy shareholders (holding less than 10 lots in all three reported logits.) Control variables include (1) M/B, the market value of equity on August 31, 2000 divided by the book value of equity; (2) Pre-ret, the six-month holding period return before repurchasing was permitted, and (3) Post-ret, the one-year return after repurchase for repurchasing firms or the one-year return after repurchasing was permitted (September 2000) for non-repurchasing firms. The 0.1, 0.05, and 0.01 significance levels are denoted by *, **, and *** respectively.

(Table continued on next page)

Prior Dividends N 11 Intercept Tax Incidence Square of Tax

Incidence*100 M/B Pre-ret Post-ret LRT

12

Panel A: In tax incidence variable, wealthy individuals hold more than 1000 lots.

Positive 164 0.271 0.0305 -0.083**

-52.78 -1.569 13.31*** 83.27***

11

Number of observations (firms.) 12

(35)

s.e. 0.688 0.0207 0.034 179.6 1.375 2.188 Zero 1.128* 0.0311 -0.041 -154.0 2.261** 5.683*** s.e. 163 0.604 0.0218 0.034 119.5 1.04 1.141 43.51***

Panel B: In tax incidence variable, wealthy individuals hold more than 600 lots.

Positive 0.081 0.0409* -0.089*** -56.18 -1.647 13.45*** s.e. 166 0.687 0.0220 0.034 177.8 1.367 2.188 84.50*** Zero 164 1.019* 0.0359 -0.040 -157.8 2.366** 5.765*** s.e. 0.611 0.0239 0.034 120.2 1.040 1.151 44.87***

Panel C: In tax incidence variable, wealthy individuals hold more than 400 lots.

Positive -0.005 0.0457** -0.092*** -55.51 -1.633 13.45*** s.e. 167 0.694 0.0226 0.034 177 1.376 2.182 85.10*** Zero 0.919 0.0389 -0.040 -160.2 2.383** 5.780*** s.e. 164 0.619 0.0257 0.035 120.9 1.042 1.155 45.17***

(36)

Table 8. Dividend Increases, Share Repurchases, and Tax Incidence

Share repurchases were allowed in Taiwan beginning in September 2000. This table examines whether the repurchase policies of individual firms depend on their ownership structure. A logit model is estimated with dependent variable equal 1.0 if the firm repurchases stock after September 2000 and zero if the firm does not repurchase stock. We divide the sample into three groups based on the change in dividend before and after September 2000: dividend increase, dividend decrease and no change in dividend. The main explanatory variable is a proxy for the tax incidence of firm shareholders. It is the difference of the proportion of shares held by wealthy individual shareholders (those holding at least 1000 lots, 600 lots or 400 lots in three separate logit models) and that of less wealthy shareholders (holding less than 10 lots in all three logits.) Control variables include (1) M/B, the market value of equity on August 31, 2000 divided by the book value of equity; (2) Pre-ret, the six-month holding period return before repurchasing was permitted, and (3) Post-Pre-ret, the one-year return after repurchase for repurchasing firms or the one-year return after repurchasing was permitted (September 2000) for non-repurchasing firms. The 0.1, 0.05, and 0.01 significance levels are denoted by *, **, and *** respectively.

(Table continued on next page)

Table 8. Dividend Increases, Share Repurchases, and Tax Incidence (continued) Dividends N13 Intercept Tax

Incidence

Square of Tax

Incidence*100 M/B Pre-ret Post-ret LRT

14

Panel A: In tax incidence variable, wealthy individuals hold more than 1000 lots. Dividend Increase 0.169 0.0282 -0.051 -60.02 -1.156 8.245*** s.e. 128 0.555 0.0221 0.033 125.4 1.248 1.827 34.88*** Dividend 90 -0.009 0.0442 -0.131** 7.685 -1.940 10.97*** 38.55*** 13

Number of observations (firms.) 14

(37)

Decrease s.e. 1.099 0.0282 0.0602 264.1 2.073 2.663 No Change 1.810* 0.0197 -0.027 -269.9 3.323** 6.310*** s.e. 106 0.978 0.0307 0.050 218.4 1.448 1.589 29.06***

Panel B: In tax incidence variable, wealthy individuals hold more than 600 lots. Dividend Increase 0.055 0.0386 -0.056* -72.89 -0.946 8.158*** s.e. 129 0.566 0.0236 0.033 123.9 1.243 1.818 34.70*** Dividend Decrease -0.157 0.054* -0.138** -5.368 -2.084 11.40*** s.e. 92 1.087 0.0299 0.060 246.2 2.059 2.673 40.10*** No Change 1.679* 0.0200 -0.021 -263.2 3.257** 6.383*** s.e. 106 0.994 0.0339 0.051 218 1.437 1.592 29.14***

Panel C: In tax incidence variable, wealthy individuals hold more than 400 lots. Dividend Increase -0.072 0.046* -0.061* -76.87 -0.872 8.233*** s.e. 130 0.578 0.024 0.033 124.1 1.244 1.826 35.93*** Dividend Decrease -0.153 0.057* -0.140** -21.49 -2.009 11.20*** s.e. 92 1.099 0.031 0.062 266.6 2.078 2.645 40.19*** No Change 1.593 0.022 -0.021 -262.6 3.231** 6.390*** s.e. 106 1.022 0.037 0.052 218.5 1.429 1.593 29.21***

(38)

Appendix

In the appendix, we calculate the effective tax rate for each household and get the numbers and holding shares of households in six tax brackets(>=30%, <30% and >=21%, <21% and >=13%, <13% and >=6%, <6% and >0%, 0%). The data are from the data center, and sample period covers from 1998-1999. Wealthy and Unwealthy are defined as follows:

1. Wealthy Households I (effective tax rate >= 30%) 2. Wealthy Households II (effective tax rate >= 21%) 3. Medium-Wealth Households II (effective tax rate < 13%) 4. Medium-Wealth Households I (effective tax rate < 6%) 5. Lower-Wealth Households (effective tax rate=0%)

Table 1 presents summary stat6istics about the owners of stocks in Taiwan stock exchange. We measure the number of households and the shares owned by various classifications of wealthy/ unwealthy households.

The results of Table1 show that wealthy households I (tax rate >=30%) contribute to only 0.6% (0.48%) of number of firm's outstanding on average. However, in terms of shares, wealthy households (tax rate >=30%) own 64.86% (24.54%) of the total outstanding shares. In contrast, lower wealth households (tax rate =0%) own less than 7% of total outstanding shares.

Table 2 replicates the Table 4 in the main context, in that we de-trend the ownership and add firm size as a Control in the independent variable. The finding of this table is basically similar, yet weaker, to what we have found in Table 2, in the main context.

(39)

Table 1 Ownership structure: household-based

Means Medians

Number % Number %

Wealthy Households I (effective tax rate >= 30%) 96 0.60 45 0.48

Wealthy Households II (effective tax rate >= 21%) 384 2.07 171 1.79

Medium-Wealth Households II (effective tax rate < 13%) 19778 91.05 8853 91.58

Medium-Wealth Households I (effective tax rate < 6%) 11173 51.50 5002 51.76

Lower-Wealth Households (effective tax rate=0%) 3400 15.53 1553 15.76

Shares

(Million) % Lots %

Wealthy Households I (effective tax rate >= 30%) 64.86 19.31 24.54 12.91

Wealthy Households II (effective tax rate >= 21%) 91.50 29.37 42.68 24.60

Medium-Wealth Households II (effective tax rate < 13%) 394.68 54.61 86.53 56.70

Medium-Wealth Households I (effective tax rate < 6%) 255.86 25.18 38.79 24.93

(40)

Table 2 Dividends and Changes in ownership Structure: De-trend and size control Panel A: Change in Ownership: Institutions and Individuals

Intercept Slope Size

Institutions 0.191 ** -0.048 -0.091

Wealthy Individuals (>1000 Lots) 0.026 -0.118 -0.196

Medium-Wealth Individuals (<100 Lots) -0.026 0.210 * 0.154

Lower-Wealth Individuals (<10 Lots) 0.009 0.293 ** 0.156

Panel B: Change in Ownership: Type of Institution

Intercept Slope Size

Government -0.267 -0.141 0.271 Financial Institutions -0.468 -0.534 1.650 Corporations 0.266 0.266 * -0.250 * Mutual Funds -0.546 0.211 0.431 Foreign Institutions -1.359 *** 0.234 0.203 Tax-exempt Institutions -0.459 ** 0.179 0.617 **

(41)

數據

Table 1.  Dividends for Taiwan Firms, 1995-1999
Table 2.  The Ownership Structure of Taiwan Stocks
Table 3. Trading before and after Dividends Increases/Decreases by Investor Category  This table reports the relative net share purchasing by three types
Table 4. Dividends and Changes in Ownership Structure
+7

參考文獻

相關文件

The encoding complexity of our BIBD codes is extremely low and is basically determined by the size of a cyclic difference family upon which a block design is based, or by the

Proof : It is clear that three numbers are vertices of triangle inscribed in the unit circle with center at the origin... So, it is clear that axiom

提名單位為機關、團體、公司行號及廠商時,需加附農民保險卡影印本或由

After lots of tests, we record two players’ winning probabilities and average number of rounds to figure out mathematical principles behind the problems and derive general formulas

By correcting for the speed of individual test takers, it is possible to reveal systematic differences between the items in a test, which were modeled by item discrimination and

第六章 其他相關規定 第一節 獲配股利或盈餘所得 壹、 「公司組織」獲配股利或盈餘及其所含的可扣抵稅額之課稅規定48

基於 TWSE 與 OTC 公司之特性,本研究推論前者相對於後者採取更穩定之股利政 策 (Leary and Michaely, 2011; Michaely and

Third, during period of DPP as ruling party, little evidience shows that connecting with DDP increases dividend, yet there is significance negative relationship between the