• 沒有找到結果。

The Price-Volume Relationships between the Existing and the Pre-Sales Housing Markets in Taiwan

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Price-Volume Relationships between the Existing and the Pre-Sales Housing Markets in Taiwan"

Copied!
15
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

I

NTERNATIONAL

R

EAL

E

STATE

R

EVIEW

2001 Vol. 4 No. 1: pp. 80 - 94

The Price-Volume Relationships between the

Existing and the Pre-Sales Housing Markets

in Taiwan

Ching-Chun Hua

Department of Public Affairs Management, Hsuan Chuang University, Hsin-Chu, Taiwan or cchua@hcu.edu.tw

Chin-Oh Chang

Department of Land Economics, National Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan or jachang@nccu.edu.tw

Chengho Hsieh

Department of Economics and Finance, Louisiana State University in Shreveport, One University Place, Shreveport, Louisiana, 71115, USA or chsieh@pilot.lsus.edu

In Taiwan, the housing market can be separated into the existing housing market and the pre-sales market. The existing market can be regarded as the stock market, and the pre-sales market the flow market. However, some unique characteristics exist in the Taiwan market. Based on these characteristics, we modified the conventional housing stock-flow model to describe the price-volume relationship between the existing and pre-sales markets. Empirical models are constructed to test the relationship. Major findings are: 1) both the pre-sales price and the existing price converge to the long-run equilibrium; however, the pre-sales price adjusts faster than the existing price, implying that the existence of the pre-sales system improves market efficiency; and 2) housing supply from the pre-sales market responds to the housing market surpluses/shortages.

Keywords

(2)

Introduction

In Taiwan, the housing market can be separated into the pre-sales and the existing housing markets. The pre-sales system also plays an important role in housing markets in other Asian countries.1 In the pre-sales market, builders are allowed to sell the housing units, while still at planning stage, right after obtaining the building permits. This practice provides builders the opportunity to assess sales performance before actually committing investment funds. Besides, the down payments made by buyers provide an additional source of funding to the builders. The down payment is paid in installments according to an agreed-upon schedule between the buyer and the builder.2 The buyers, on the other hand, can reduce price risk by locking-in the purchase price. Besides, paying the down payment in installments instead of a lump sum provides a form of financing to the buyer. These advantages have popularized the pre-sales system in Taiwan, and new housing units are marketed and sold predominantly through this system. In addition, the pre-sales market is in nature similar to the futures/forward markets.3

In the existing housing market in Taiwan, the buyers and sellers transact on “housing stock,” which are existing housing units. Meanwhile, in the pre-sales market, the transactions are on “housing flow,” which are new housing units still in the construction or planning stage. The price-volume relationship between the existing and pre-sales markets in Taiwan may be similar to the stock-flow relationship described by the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton (FDW) Model (Fisher [1992]; DiPasquale, et al. [1992, 1994, 1996]; and Renaud, et al. [1996]). However, some special characteristics exist in the Taiwan markets. Therefore, we modified the FDW model based on those characteristics to describe the price-volume relationship between the existing and pre-sales markets. Empirical models are constructed to test the relationship. The major findings are: 1) both the existing price and the pre-sales price converge to the long-run equilibrium; however, the pre-pre-sales price adjusts faster than the existing price, implying that the existence of a pre-sales system improves housing market efficiency, and 2) new housing supply from the pre-sales market responds to housing market surpluses/shortages.

1

For example, Hong Kong, China, and Japan. (See Wang et al. 2000)

2 The total down payment is about 20% to 50% of the sales price of the housing unit. When the

contract is signed, the buyer makes the first payment about 10% of the sales price. The remaining down payment is amortized into monthly payments based on the estimated total number of months for construction. The payments are made along with the progress of the construction.

(3)

The following section reviews the conventional housing stock-flow model. Section III describes the special characteristics of the housing markets in Taiwan. The empirical models are derived in Section IV, and the test results are discussed in Section V. Section VI concludes this paper. The data are described in the Appendix.

The Housing Stock-Flow Model

The Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton (FDW) model analyzes the stock-flow relationship of housing markets. New housing supply through the flow market should adjust to eliminate the shortage/surplus in the stock market to reach the overall equilibrium. The model assumes that housing supply is fixed in the short run, and the price of housing services is determined by housing supply and demand. This price is the market rent. In turn, the market rent and the discount rate determine the price of housing stock, and the price of housing stock and construction costs jointly determine the number of housing starts (Smith [1974] and Smith, et al. [1988]).

The model is later extended to incorporate the concepts of housing consumption and investments.4 The housing stock market is defined as the space market to describe the relationship between rent and housing supply and demand. The housing flow market is defined as the asset market to describe the relationship between housing supply and construction costs/investment profits.

On one hand, the rent level in the stock market affects the price level in the flow market. In addition, adjustment in housing supply by the flow market serves to reduce the housing shortage/surplus in the stock market. In equilibrium, the supply should equal the shortage/surplus. When the market is not in equilibrium, housing prices, and consequently the new housing supply, would adjust via the change in market rents. This process continues until equilibrium is reached as shown in Figure 1.

However, due to incomplete information on the housing market, coupled with the construction lag, the adjustment in new housing supply may not perfectly match the shortage/surplus in the housing market. Therefore, this adjustment in response to the shortage/surplus should exhibit a continuous and dynamic process.

4

Here “housing consumption” means the consumption by the general public; whereas “housing investment” means the investment/construction by the developers/builders. These are not the same as the housing investment and consumption behaviors described by recent literature.

(4)

Figure 1: The price-volume relationship in the FDW model S T P Q N E W R D ¡ µS T = Q N E W - d S T Q N E W = f ( P , C O S T ) P = R / i

P: Housing Price, ST: Housing Stock, COST: Construction Costs, R: Housing Rent, d: Housing Depreciation Rate, D: Housing Demand, i: Discount Rate, QNEW: New Housing

Supply

Using a 1963-1990 American housing data set, DiPasquale, et al. (1994) found that the annual adjustment rate at which the housing price adjusts to the long-run equilibrium is 0.29, and the annual adjustment rate at which the housing supply converges to the long-run equilibrium is 0.02.5 These results indicate that price and volume in the US market adjust to the long-run equilibrium.

Special Characteristics of the Taiwan Housing Markets

In Taiwan, the existing housing market can be treated as the stock market, and the pre-sales market the flow market. Due to the construction lag, newly-completed housing units may not accurately represent the current housing flow in Taiwan. In the pre-sales market, housing units are already put on the market even when they are still at the planning or construction stages. Therefore, housing supply through the pre-sales system can be adjusted according to the changes in housing demand and economic outlook. Consequently, the problem arising from the construction lag may not be so acute. Pre-sales housing supply is also an investment decision for the builders. The decision takes into account the pre-sales housing price, construction and development costs, and other economic factors.

5

The data of current new housing construction are used to proxy housing flow. They are not adjusted for the time lag caused by construction. The reason could be that in the U.S., houses are built in single units and mainly in wood, which take a much shorter time to complete. In contrast, in Taiwan, housing units are built in the form of a large apartment complex and predominantly in concrete.

(5)

In the FDW model, prices of new housing units are determined by discounting the rent. In the pre-sales market, housing price is not determined solely by supply and demand. The pre-sales market is in nature similar to a futures/forward market, and the pre-sales price is determined by the price of the housing stock,6 carrying costs and expected future price changes, and minus a risk premium7 (see Pai [1996], and Chang and Ward [1993]).8 The pre-sales market tends to react to future market conditions, and adjusts the price earlier than the existing market for at least two reasons:

In the pre-sales market, the suppliers are professional developers/builders who market the whole housing project, which typically includes a large number of housing units. Meanwhile, the suppliers in the existing market are individuals who usually just market their own homes. The developers/builders in the pre-sales market are analogous to portfolio managers in the securities market, while the individual suppliers in the existing market are analogous to individual investors. The former is generally deemed more efficient in gathering and using information than the latter for reasons such as economies of scale in information costs. Since prices reflect information, pre-sales price should adjust faster than existing price.

In the pre-sales market, housing supply can be adjusted at a lower cost. In this market, sales can be made as soon as construction permits are obtained. Therefore, if demand rises, housing supply can be increased faster than in the existing market. On the other hand, if demand drops, supply can be reduced by simply canceling the construction project. If the lower demand is due to the switch in consumer preference in product design (e.g., the size of the housing units), the builder can simply redesign the products. The lower adjustment costs also make adjustments in price easier. This also contributes to the faster price adjustment in the pre-sales market.

6

According to Pai (1996) the difference between the pre-sales price and the existing housing price depends in part on expected future economic condition.

7

The risk premium in the pre-sales price reflects the uncertainty in construction quality, the completion and delivery of the house, the title of the property, etc.

8 According to Pai (1996), PP is equal to PS (1+c (!)), where PP is the pre-sales price, PS is the

existing housing price, and c is the coefficient for carrying cost (A). Carrying cost is a function of the existing housing price, down payment ratio, the sum of the monthly payments, interests rates, property taxes, the discount rate, time to completion and delivery of the housing unit, and title insurance fee as a percentage of the sales price. When this coefficient is greater (smaller) than zero, the pre-sales price changes at a rate higher (lower) than the existing housing price.

(6)

As a result, the pre-sales price becomes a leading indicator for the existing price. In summary, the pre-sales price affects the existing price directly due to its leading role, and indirectly through its impact on housing supply. Therefore, the change in housing price may not completely come from the change in rent resulting from changes in housing supply and demand.

Although the pre-sales and the existing markets appear to operate independently, they are in fact mutually related via a number of price-volume relationships. The equilibrium is reached when the adjustment in supply, determined by the price and construction costs in the pre-sales market, equals the shortage/surplus in the existing market. That is, when a surplus (shortage) exists, the price of existing housing falls (rises), and people anticipate a housing market downturn (upturn), which causes a decrease (increase) in the pre-sales price and a reduction (addition) of housing stock in the coming period. This process continues until the equilibrium is reached.

Empirical Models

Relationship Between Housing Price and Supply

The existing research appears to reach the consensus that demand in the existing market (QEtd) is determined by the existing housing price (PS) and

demand propensity, which in turn are determined by the total number of households (H) and income levels (Y); the impact of existing housing price should be negative (a1 < 0) and the impact of demand propensity should be

positive (a2, a3 > 0). When housing demand exists in both the existing and

pre-sales markets, the increase in pre-sales price (PP) would result in the switch of housing demand from the pre-sales to the existing market, and vice versa. Consequently, the change in pre-sales price affects housing demand in the existing market (a4 >0).

QEdt = a0 + a1PSt + a2Ht + a3Yt + a4PPt (1)

On the other hand, short-term supply in the existing housing market depends on how many housing units enter the market for sale. Therefore, supply in the existing housing market (QEst) is affected by both the housing stock (ST)

and the existing housing price (PS).9 The coefficients b1 and b2 in the

following equation are expected to be greater than 0.

9

In the conventional housing stock-flow model, the stock market is determined by aggregate supply and aggregate demand for housing services. Equation (2) however, focuses on the short-term supply; that is, housing units that are already “on the market” or are ready to enter the market in a very short time. In this equation, the existing price (PS) affects the propensity to sell and the housing stock (ST) proxies the potential supply scale.

(7)

QEst = b0 + b1PSt + b2STt (2)

In equilibrium,

QEdt = QEst (3)

Substituting Equations (1) and (2) for (3) yields Equation (4) below, in which the existing price is a function of the number of households, income, pre-sales price, and housing stock.

PSt =(a0-b0)/(b1-a1)+a2Ht/(b1-a1)+a3Yt/(b1-a1)+a4PPt/(b1-a1)-b2STt/(b1-a1) (4)

The demand in the pre-sales market (QPdt) is certainly related to the pre-sales

price, and is also influence by the price in the existing market.

QPdt = c0 + c1PPt + c2PSt (5)

c1 < 0 and c2 > 0.

The supply in the pre-sales market (QPst) is determined by pre-sales prices

and construction costs (COST).

QPst = d0 + d1PPt + d2COSTt (6)

d1 > 0 and d2 < 0.

In equilibrium,10

QPdt = QPst (7)

Substituting Equations (5) and (6) for (7) yields Equation (8) below, where the pre-sales price is a function of existing housing price and construction costs.

PPt = (c0 - d0) /(d1 - c1) + c2PSt /(d1 - c1) - d2 COSTt /(d1 - c1) (8)

Assuming that housing stock at time t represents the equilibrium level (ST*), the FDW model implies that if the existing housing and pre-sales markets clear simultaneously, the difference in housing stock between times t and t-1

10 The equilibrium here does not mean that the supply from the pre-sales market is completely

(8)

should equal the new housing supply at time t (NEWt).11 NEWt is a function

of the housing supply provided by the pre-sales market from current as well as previous periods under the notion of perfect expectation (∑QPsi*, i ≤ t).

Therefore, STt* - STt-1 = NEWt = Q (∑QP s

i*)

After rearranging,

STt*= Q (∑QPsi*) + STt-1 (9)

In equilibrium, the existing housing market and the pre-sales market should clear simultaneously; that is, prices and volumes in both markets should settle at the same time. In order to empirically estimate the price-volume relationship between the pre-sales and the existing housing markets, Equations (4), (8), and (9) are transformed into econometric models (10), (11), and (12) below. PSt = α0 + α1Ht + α2Yt + α3PPt + α4STt + ε1 (10) α0 = (a0-b0) / (b1-a1), α1=a2 / (b1-a1) > 0, α2=a3 / (b1-a1) > 0, α3=a4 / (b1-a1) > 0, α4= -b2 / (b1-a1) < 0 PPt = γ0 + γ1PSt + γ2COSTt + ε2 (11) γ0 = (c0 - d0) / (d1 -c1), γ1 = c2 / (d1 -c1) > 0, γ2 = -d2 / (d1 -c1) > 0 STt = δ0 + δ1QPst + δ2QPst-1 + δ3STt-1 + ε3 (12) δ1 > 0, δ2 > 0, δ3 > 0

Adjustment Rates in Housing Price and Supply

In the FDW model, housing price and supply adjust to the long-run equilibrium, and market supply and demand clear simultaneously. In reality however, due to insufficient information, as well as the construction lag, the market mechanism may not work as perfectly as described by the model. Nevertheless, in theory at least, as long as the market mechanism is working, when the price and volume is not in equilibrium, the price and supply/demand should work to eventually close the gap. If this is true, the

11

In the empirical tests, the data for the housing stock are end-of-period numbers, so the amount of housing demolition is already excluded. In addition, the housing stock is represented by the number of housing units, so depreciation would not be a problem.

(9)

annual change in housing price at time t should be equal to the equilibrium price at time t (Pt*) minus the price at time t – 1 (Pt-1), multiplied by the price

adjustment rate (π).12 Pt – Pt-1 = π (Pt* - Pt-1).

After rearranging.

Pt = πPt* + (1-π) Pt-1 (13)

Substituting Equations (10) and (11) into (13) yields Equations (14) and (15), where Φ and Ψ denote the adjustment rate for existing price and pre-sales price respectively.

PSt = π0 + π1ST1 + π2Ht + π3Yt + π4PPt - ΦPSt-1 + µ1 (14)

PPt = θ0 + θ1COSTt + θ2PSt - ΨPPt-1 + µ2 (15)

The change in housing supply at time t (∆STt) is equal to the equilibrium

housing stock (STt*) minus the housing stock at time t-1 (STt-1), multiplied

by the supply adjustment rate (η). ∆ST is equal to NEWt. Therefore,

∆STt = NEWt = η(STt* - STt-1) (16)

Substituting Equation (12) into (16) yields Equation (17), where Ω is the housing flow adjustment rate.

NEWt = η0 + η1 QPst + η2 QPst-1 + η3 QPst-2 - ΩSTt-1 + µ3 (17)

Ω reveals how fast the pre-sales housing supply adjusts to shortage/surplus. A low Ω indicates that when there is a surplus (shortage) in the existing market, the supply in the pre-sales market decreases (increases) at a lower speed.

12 The adjustment rate tells us the magnitude at which the underlying variable (price or volume)

(10)

Empirical Results

Price-Volume Relationship

We used the two-stage least squares regressions to estimate the log-log form of equations (10) to (12). In this system, the pre-sales price (PP), the existing price (PS), and the housing stock (ST) are simultaneous. A dummy variable is included in the models to account for the structural change in the data.13 Table 1 contains the simple statistics for the variables. The results are shown in Table 2 and are discussed as follows:

Table 1: Simple Statistics for the Variables1973-1999 

pre-sale housing price index existing housing price index housing stock (units) new constructed area (m2) construction permit areas (m2) disposal income per month households construction cost index Average 74.34 80.40 634,315 2,200,211 1,825,963 55,700 685,987 118.04 Standard deviation 35.64 34.38 181,241 1,094,370 1,477,080 27,314 169,406 35.86 Maximum 117.46 122.81 837,553 4,329,046 5,117,398 93,466 869,803 166.39 Minimum 22.54 31.82 191,003 1,000,083 438,778 9,456 142,886 37.49

The change in the existing housing price has a positive impact on pre-sales price with a coefficient of 1.38. The pre-sales price also has a positive impact on existing housing price with a coefficient of 0.64. New housing supply from the pre-sales market significantly affects housing stock with a coefficient of -0.03.

Both the income level and the number of households have a positive impact on the existing price. The coefficient for the income level is 0.09, and for the number of households 1.73. Besides, housing stock exhibits an inverse relationship with the existing housing price with a coefficient of –1.08. These results indicate that the existing housing price is indeed governed by market supply and demand

13

As shown in Appendix, housing price experienced a dramatic change around 1991 and housing stock continued to rise till the same year and then leveled-off. We use the ADF model to perform stationary tests and find that the original data for NEW, ST, PS, and PP exhibit I (1). After taking the log on the variables and adding the dummy variable to account for the structural change, we find that they become I (0).

(11)

Table 2: The Price-Volume Relationship o f P r e - S a l e s a n d E x i s t i n g M a r k e t s V a r i a b l e s E x i s t i n g P r i c e P r e - s a l e s P r i c e H o u s i n g S t o c k I n t e r s e c t i o n - 8 . 2 7 ( - 1 . 4 8 ) - 2 . 8 0 * * ( - 5 . 2 0 ) 1 . 8 9 * * ( 4 . 8 6 8 ) P r e - s a l e s P r i c e ( P P ) 0 . 6 4 * * ( 6 . 8 2 ) E x i s t i n g P r i c e ( P S ) 1 . 3 8 * * ( 8 . 0 5 ) I n c o me ( Y ) 0 . 0 9 * ( 1 . 7 1 3 ) H o u s e h o l d s ( H ) 1 . 7 3 * ( 2 . 3 0 ) C o n s t r u c t i o n c o s t s ( C O S T ) 0 . 2 4 ( 1 . 3 8 ) H o u s i n g s t o c k ( S T ) - 1 . 0 8 * ( - 2 . 5 4 8 ) S Tt - 1 0 . 9 1 * * ( 4 6 . 1 6 ) S u p p l y o f p r e - s a l e s h o u s e s ( Q P ) - 0 . 0 3 * ( - 2 . 4 1 ) Q P t - 1 - 0 . 0 1 ( - 0 . 6 0 ) D u mmy V a r i a b l e - 0 . 1 8 * ( - 2 . 8 5 ) - 0 . 2 9 * ( - 2 . 6 4 ) - 0 . 0 6 * ( - 2 . 4 6 ) R2 0 . 9 5 7 9 0 . 9 5 1 6 0 . 9 9 5 9 ** Significant at 1%. * Significant at 5%. .

The Adjustment Rates of Price and Supply

To test whether price and volume adjust to long-run equilibrium, we used two-stage regressions to estimate the simultaneous system of Equations (14), (15), and (17) in log-log form. In this system, the pre-sales price (PP) and the existing price (PS) are simultaneous. The results (see Table 3) show that the price adjustment rate in the existing market is 0.29, and in the pre-sales market 0.35.14 These numbers indicate that in Taiwan, housing prices work

14 According to the empirical model, the price adjustment rate in the existing housing market is

equal to 1 minus the regression coefficient; that is, 1-0.71=0.29. If the regression coefficient is significantly different from zero, then the adjustment rate is significantly different from 1. The t-values for the regression coefficient for the existing housing market and the pre-sales market are 5.13 and 4.17 respectively. Thus, both coefficients are statistically significant at the 99% level.

(12)

to reduce the gap between demand and supply. The higher adjustment rate for the pre-sales price indicates that it reflects market conditions faster than the existing price. The housing stock at t-1 is related to the new supply from the pre-sales market with a coefficient of –0.36, indicating that new supply from the pre-sales market converges to the long-run equilibrium (see also Wang, et al., 2000).

Table 3: The Adjustment Rates of Housing Price and Volume

Existing Price (PS) Pre-sales Price (PP) Supply of New Constructed Houses (NEW) Intersection -13.92* (-2.70) -1.59* (-2.41) 13.71** (3.04) Pre-sales Price (PP) 0.18* (1.73) PP t-1 0.65** (4.17) Existing Price (PS) 0.85** (3.72) PS t-1 0.71** (5.13) Housing Stock ST t-1 -0.10 (-0.187) -0.36* (-1.77) Income (Y) 0.42 (1.66) Households (H) 1.50* (2.32) Construction costs (COST) -0.08 (-0.39) Supply of pre-sales houses (QP) 0.16 (1.09) QP t-1 0.12 (0.70) QP t-2 0.13 (0.97) Dummy Variable 0.08 (0.70) -0.38** (-3.09) 0.07 (0.225) R2 0.9778 0.9538 0.7138 Adjustment rate 0.29** 0.35** 0.36* ** Significant at 1%. * Significant at 5%.

(13)

Conclusions

The Taiwan housing market can be separated into pre-sales and existing housing markets. This paper redefines the relationship between the housing stock and flow markets based on some special market characteristics in Taiwan. Empirical models are formulated to test the price-volume relationship between the pre-sales and the existing markets. The results are: 1) the pre-sales and existing prices are mutually and positively related; 2) the existing price is governed by supply and demand; 3) both the pre-sales and existing prices converge to the long-run equilibrium; however, the pre-sales price adjusts at a faster speed, implying that the existence of the pre-sales system improves market efficiency in Taiwan; and 4) the pre-sales supply is affected by the previous housing stock, implying that pre-sales supply responds to housing surpluses/shortages.

References

Chang, C. O., and Hua, C. C., (1996), The Relationship between Housing Transaction Price and Volume in Taiwan, presented at the 1996 ENHR Conference in Denmark.

Chang, C. O., (1999), Housing Information Quarterly, the Ministry of Interior Project. (in Chinese)

Chang, C. O. and Lin, C. C., (1995), The Relationship between Real Estate Cycles and Macro Economic Cycles, National Science Council Research Project. (in Chinese)

Chang, C. O. and Ward, C., (1993), Forward Pricing and the Housing Market: The Pre-Sales Housing in Taiwan, Journal of Property Research, 10, 217-227.

DiPasquale, D. and Wheaton, W. C., (1992), The Markets for Real Estate Assets and Space: A Conceptual Framework, The AREUEA Journal, 10, 1, 181-197.

DiPasquale, D. and Wheaton, W. C., (1994), Housing Market Dynamics and the Future of Housing Prices, Journal of Urban Economics, 35, 1-22. DiPasquale, D. and Wheaton, W.C., (1996), Urban Economics and Real

(14)

Fisher, J. D., (1992), Integrating Research on Markets for Space and Capital,

The AREUEA Journal, 20, 1, 161-180.

Lin, Vickey C. C., (1998), Market Efficiency Test of Pre-sales and Existing House on Taiwan Market, Journal of Management, 15, .4 (in Chinese) Muth, R. F., (1960), The Demand for Non-Farm Housing, in The Demand for

Durable Goods, Edited by A. Harberger, Chicago: University of Chicago

Press, 29-96.

Olsen, E. O., (1969), A Competitive Theory of the Housing Market,

American Economic Review, 59, 612-22.

Pai, C. A., (1996), Applying Forwards and Futures Pricing Theories to Study Pre-Sales Housing Price, Ph.D. Dissertation of Department of Land Economics in National Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan. (in Chinese) Renaud, B. M., (1997), The 1985 to 1994 Global real Estate Cycle: An Overview, Journal of Real Estate Literature, 5, 13-44.

Renaud, B. M., Pretorius, F., and Pasadilla, B. O., (1996), The Use of the Modern Real Estate Paradigm in Comparative Work: A Test for Hong Kong, presented at the 5th Annual AREUEA International Real Estate Conference. Smith, L. B., (1974), A Note on the Price Adjustment Mechanism for Rental Housing, American Economic Review, 64, 3, 478-81.

Smith, L. B., Rosen, K. T. and Fallis, G., (1988), Recent Developments in Economic Models of Housing Markets, Journal of Economic Literature, 26, 29-64.

Wang, K., Zhou, Y., Chan, S. H., and Chau, K. W., (2000), Over-Confidence and Cycles in Real Estate Markets: Cases in Hong Kong and Asia,

(15)

Appendix: Data Description

The data set contains annual housing data collected for the Taipei metropolitan area, and covers the period 1974-1999.

1. Existing housing price (PS) and pre-sales price (PP) use the same data as in Chang (1999), in which PS is calculated as the median transaction price in the existing market, and PP is the median transaction price in the pre-sales market. The advantage of this data is that it is calculated by controlling property attributes by employing the hedonic model.

2. Housing stock (ST) uses Housing Census Data in 1990 as the base number. For each year, we adjusted the base number by the total number of usage permit areas and the total number of demolished housing units to obtain the housing stock for that year.

3. Households (H) is the “Total Number of Households” from the Yearbook of Taipei.

4. Housing supply in the pre-sales market (QNEW) uses “Construction Permit Areas” from the Yearbook of Taipei.

5. Income level (Y) uses “Monthly Disposable Income per Household” from the Yearbook of Taipei.

6. Construction Cost (COST) uses “Construction Price Index” from the Yearbook of Taipei.

數據

Figure 1: The price-volume relationship in the FDW model     S TP Q N E WR D¡ µ S T   = Q N E W - d S TQ N E W = f   ( P ,   C O S T )P   = R   /   i
Table 1: Simple Statistics for the Variables  1973-1999     
Table 2: The Price-Volume Relationship  o f   P r e - S a l e s   a n d   E x i s t i n g M a r k e t s V a r i a b l e s E x i s t i n g P r i c e P r e - s a l e sP r i c e H o u s i n gS t o c k I n t e r s e c t i o n - 8
Table 3: The Adjustment Rates of Housing Price and Volume

參考文獻

相關文件

Due to significant price declines in women’s clothing, rent of housing and electric household appliances, the indices of CLOTHING AND FOOTWEAR, RENT AND HOUSING EXPENSES and

On the other hand, the pre-Lunar New Year Sale on clothing, falling price in fresh pork and a waiver of welfare housing rentals by the Housing Institute for the first quarter of

On the other hand, rising prices in new arrivals of summer clothing, men’s and women’s footwear and the expiry of waiver of welfare housing rentals by the Housing Institute after

If land resource for private housing increases, the trading price in private housing market will decrease but there may not be any effects on public housing market 54 ; if we

If land resource for private housing increases, the trading price in private housing market will decrease but there may not be any effects on public housing market 54 ; if

Microphone and 600 ohm line conduits shall be mechanically and electrically connected to receptacle boxes and electrically grounded to the audio system ground point.. Lines in

Based on the tourism and recreational resources and lodging industry in Taiwan, this paper conducts the correlation analysis on spatial distribution of Taiwan

This research studied the experimental studies of integration of price and volume moving average approach in Taiwan stock market, including (1) the empirical studies of optimizing