• 沒有找到結果。

R&D, Strategic Delegation and Market Share Competition

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "R&D, Strategic Delegation and Market Share Competition"

Copied!
14
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)The Economic Society of Australia Inc.. Proceedings of the 37th Australian Conference Economists. of. Papers delivered at ACE 08. 30th September to 4th October 2008 Gold Coast Queensland Australia. ISBN 978-0-9591806-4-0.

(2) Welcome The Economic Society of Australia warmly welcomes you to the Gold Coast, Queensland, Australia for the 37th Australian Conference of Economists. The Society was formed 83 years ago in 1925. At the time, the Society was opposed to declarations of policy and instead focused on open discussions and encouraging economic debate. Nothing has changed today, with the Society and the conference being at the forefront of encouraging debate. This year we have a large number of papers dealing with Infrastructure, Central Banking and Trade. Matters of the greatest global importance invariably boil down to be economic problems. Recent times have seen an explosion of infrastructure spending, after world-wide population growth has seen demand outpace aging supply. The world has become more globalised than at any time since World War I but the benefits of this (and the impact on our climate) has been questioned by some. At the time of preparing for this conference we could not have known that it would have been held during the largest credit crisis since the Great Depression. The general public and politicians both look to central banks for the answers. We are also very pleased to see a wide selection of papers ranging from applied economics to welfare economics. An A – Z of economics (well, almost). Another feature of this conference is that we have gone out of our way to bring together economists from all walks of life, in particular from academia, government and the private sector. We are grateful to all of our sponsors, who are as diverse as the speakers. The Organising Committee James Dick Khorshed Alam (Programme Chair) Michael Knox Greg Hall Allan Layton Rimu Nelson Gudrun Meyer-Boehm Jay Bandaralage Paula Knight. Our Gold Sponsors. Published November 2008 © Economic Society of Australia (Queensland) Inc GPO Box 1170 Brisbane Queensland Australia ecosocqld@optushome.com.au Keynote Sponsors. Special Session Sponsors. Unless we have specifically been requested to do otherwise, all the papers presented at the conference are published in the proceedings in full. A small number of papers will have versions that have also been made available for special editions of Journals, Economic Analysis and Policy, and the Economic Record. Authors will retain the right to seek additional publication for papers presented at the conference so long as it differs in some meaningful way from those published here. The opinions expressed in the papers included in the proceedings are those of the author(s) and no responsibility can be accepted by the Economic Society of Australia Inc, Economic Society of Australia (Queensland) Inc, the publisher for any damages resulting from usage or dissemination of this work.. The Paper following forms part of - Proceedings of the 37th Australian Conference of Economists ISBN 978-0-9591806-4-0.

(3) R&D, Strategic Delegation and Market Share Competition I-Hui Cheng,*a Ying-Yi Tsai b, Leonard F.S. Wang c a. Department of Applied Economics, National University of Kaohsiung, 700 Kaohsiung University Road, Nan-Tzu, Kaohsiung 811, Taiwan, ROC. Email: icheng@nuk.edu.tw. * The corresponding author.. b. Department of Applied Economics, National University of Kaohsiung, 700 Kaohsiung University Road, Nan-Tzu, Kaohsiung 811, Taiwan, ROC. Email: yytsai@nuk.edu.tw.. c. Department of Applied Economics, National University of Kaohsiung, 700 Kaohsiung University Road, Nan-Tzu, Kaohsiung 811, Taiwan, ROC. Email: lfswang@nuk.edu.tw. Abstract This paper investigates the role of spillovers in determining manager's decisions of R&D investment and the owner's choices of incentives between a profit-market share framework. We consider a three-stage game in which two firms with homogeneous products pursue oligopolistic competition in the market and each owner delegates the production and R&D decisions to a manager. Each manager’s objective is guided by an incentive scheme which is a weighted sum of profits and market share. It is found that with higher R&D spillovers both firms commit more competition since rival firms also benefit from cost-reducing R&D spillovers, therefore they invest less in R&D. In this case, the owner may choose higher weights for market share under certain condition. The cost of investment in R&D also affects the weight on market share. When R&D is relatively costly, the owner may choose lower weights for market share.. Keywords: Managerial delegation; R&D spillovers; Oligopoly; Market share. JEL-Classification: D21; D43; C72; L13.. 1.

(4) 1. Introduction In large companies ownership and management are commonly separated, which may lead to additionally problems that are well known in managerial incentive literature (see, e.g., Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Demsetz, 1983; Fama and Jensen, 1983). In these studies, the owner and manager relationship is treated as a conventional principal-agent issue in which the compensation scheme is proposed to solve manager’s incentive problem. However, as argued in the strategic delegation literature, the owner-manager relationship can be described as a delegation problem in which owners delegate the production and other managerial decisions to managers. Thus, for instance, the managerial contracts considering for sales and market share may direct managers to allow for non-profit maximization (see, Lackman and Craycroft, 1974; Vickers, 1985; Fershtman and Judd, 1987; Sklivas, 1987; Goering, 1996). Zhang and Zhang (1997) combine the strategic delegation in Fershtman-JuddSklivas framework with the aspect of R&D spillovers, adopting the cost-reducing R&D model of d’Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988). By doing this, they discuss how the ownership structure affects firm’s R&D and production decisions, and examine the social welfare effects under two different ownership structures. This paper investigates the role of spillovers in influencing owner’s incentive schemes and manager’s R&D choices. Using the framework developed by Fershtman and Judd (1987) and Skilvas (1985), we consider that owner links to market share of the incentive scheme, that manager decides whether or not engaging in cost-reducing R&D to increase the market share, in the presence of spillovers. We are able to highlight the role of R&D spillovers in a strategic delegation framework with market share competition a la Zhang and Zhang (1997) and Jansen et al (2007). The rest of paper is organized as follows. In Section two, the three-stage duopolistic model with strategic delegation and cost-reducing R&D is described. The 2.

(5) third section presents the results of the model. The final section provides concluding remarks.. 2. The Model We consider a three-stage model in which two firms with homogeneous products pursue oligopolistic competition in the market. We assume each firm has a risk neutral owner and a risk neutral manager. In the first stage, two owners simultaneously choose the incentive schemes for their managers, which is a linear combination of profit and market share. In the second stage, the two managers simultaneously make their cost-reducing R&D decisions noncooperatively given the incentive schemes. At the third stage, the two managers simultaneously make their output decisions in a Cournot-Nash game given the incentive schemes and R&D investment of both firms. In the first stage, owner i (i = 1,2) chooses incentive scheme α i to maximize a linear combination of profit ( π i ) and market share ( si ): Vi = π i + α i si ,. (1). where si = qi Q , si′(Q) > 0 and si′′(Q) < 0 , and Q denotes the industry output, Q = q1 + q2 . Each owner can only proposes its incentive scheme, but not determine. the R&D and sales. Here, unlike Fershtman and Judd (1987) and Skilvas (1985), we particularly consider the case where the exerting effort to win a higher market share is considered in the managerial compensation contract. By doing so, owner i uses market share si as a strategic instrument to influence the performance of each manager. In the second stage, manager i decides whether or not to engage in cost-reducing R&D activity. Following d’Aspremont and Jaquemin (1988), we assume manager i chooses R&D investment xi to maximize Vi . If both managers i and j undertake the 3.

(6) cost-reducing R&D activity, then the post-innovation marginal cost of production is given by ci = k − xi − βx j , where xi are x j the sizes of R&D cost-reducing by firms i and j, respectively. xi + βx j is the total amount of marginal cost reduction for firm i, where k > xi − βx j to assure positive marginal cost. β is used to measure the size of R&D spillover effect between two firms, β ∈ [0, 1] . Thus, a large value of. β implies that a firm’s R&D investment has a greater cost reduction on the other’s marginal production cost. And in the final stage, given the incentive schemes ( α i and α j ) and effective production costs ( ci and c j ) the managers i and j choose the quantity and compete for market shares in the product market. Manager i chooses output qi to maximize Vi :. Vi = (P − ci )qi − X i + á i qi /Q; i = 1,2,. (2). where P denotes price, P = 1 − Q , X i is firm i’s R&D cost, and 0 < k < 1 . Note ′ that Pi′(Q) < 0 and Pi′(Q) + Pi′(Q)q i < 0 . In the following, we solve for a subgame. perfect equilibrium to characterize the strategic delegation game with R&D spillovers.. 3. Results We employ the method of backward induction to solve for the three-stage game. In the stage of market competition, the outputs in the Cournot-Nash equilibrium, denoted by ( q1* ( c1 ,c2 ), q2* ( c1 ,c2 )) , must satisfy the following system of equations: ∂V1 = P′(Q)q1 + P(Q) − c1 + á1 s11(Q), ∂q1 ∂V2 g (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ = P′(Q)q2 + P(Q) − c2 + á 2 s22(Q). ∂q2 f (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫. 4. (3).

(7) Equation (3) characterizes the best output response function of firm 1 and 2, respectively, at the market stage. It is evident that f (⋅) and g (⋅) have at most one solution for any qi since ∂f / ∂qi < 0 and ∂g / ∂qi < 0 .1 The details are shown in Appendix A. Using Implicit Function rule, that is, df (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ f1dq1 + f 2 dq2 + f 3 dc1 + f 4 dc2 = 0, dg (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ g1dq1 + g 2 dq2 + g 3 dc1 + g 4 dc2 = 0,. (4). thus, we have:  f1   g1. Therefore,.  ∂q1    f 2  ∂c1   1   = . g 2  ∂q2   0   ∂c   1. ∂q1 (P′′(Q)q2 + P′(Q) + α 2 s21 (Q) ) = < 0 if q1 < q2 , and ∂c1 ∆(> 0). ∂q2 − (P′′(Q)q2 + 2 P′(Q) + α 2 s22 (Q) ) = > 0 . That is, a decrease (increases) in firm ∂c1 ∆(> 0). 1’s marginal cost of production increases (decreases) firm 1’s output and decreases (increases) firm 2’s output. This implies that an increase in cost-reducing R&D by firm 1 may increase firm 1’s equilibrium output, by contrast, reduce firm 2’s output. Next, we solve the manager’s problem for the R&D stage of the game for further discussion. In the R&D stage, the managers decide the size of cost-reducing R&D investment. Assume firm i’s R&D cost function X i is convex in R&D investment 2. xi , e.g. X i = 0.5γxi . Then, using q1* ( c1 ( x, k , β , γ ), c2 ( x, k , β , γ )) and q2* ( c1 ( x, k , β , γ ), c2 ( x, k , β , γ )) , we solve for x * (k , β , γ ,α 1 , α 2 ) . Differentiating equation (2) with. respect to x leads to: ∂V1 ∂V1 ∂q2 ∂V1 ∂q1 ∂X 1 = + − . ∂x ∂q2 ∂x ∂q1 ∂x ∂x 1. (5). Jansen et al (2007) investigate a concave reaction function with identical marginal cost between two competing firms. 5.

(8) By using the first equation in (3), all the expressions involved in equation (5) can be rearranged as:     ∂c  ∂V1 α s  ∂q α s  ∂q ∂c  ∂X 1   = q1   P′(Q) + 1 12  2 − 1 1 +  P′(Q) + 1 12  2 2  − . ∂x q1  ∂c1 ∂x  q1  ∂c2 ∂x  { ∂x  44444  1 3 cos t effect 244444 3 1444424444   share − adjusted spillover effect share − adjusted strategic effect. (6). The detailed calculation of equation (6) is shown in Appendix B. Next, using Implicit Function rule, we have dh( x; k , β , γ , α1 , α 2 ) ∫ h1dx + h2 dk + h3 dβ + h4 dγ + h5 dα1 + h6 dα 2 = 0 ,. (7). where h1 ∫. ∂ 2V1 ∂ 2V1 < 0 h ∫ <0, , 2 ∂x 2 ∂x∂k. h3 ∫.  ∂ 2V1 α s  ∂q ∂ 2 c2 = q1  P′(Q) + 1 12  2 < 0, ∂x∂β q ∂ c ∂ x ∂ β 1 { 2 1 144244 23 3 <0. <0. <0.      2 2  ∂ V1 α s  ∂q ∂ c1  α s  ∂q ∂ c2    h4 ∫ = q1   P′(Q) + 1 12  2 − 1 +  P′(Q) + 1 12  2 < 0,   ∂x∂γ  ∂x∂γ ∂c1 q ∂ c ∂ x ∂ γ 1 { 1 2   14424q4 3 1442443 { 123  3  12 >0 <0 = <0   <0 <0  0  2.    ∂ 2V1 s12   ∂q2 ∂c1 ∂q2 ∂c2  h5 ∫ = q1  P′(Q) +   + >0 ∂x∂α1 q1   { ∂c1 { ∂x { ∂c2 { ∂x  14 4244 3 <0 <0   >0 <0  <0. As we see,. if. á 2 s22 <β. á1 s11. h ∂x = − 3 < 0 . This implies that with higher R&D spillovers both ∂β h1. firms commit more competition since rival firms also benefit from cost-reducing R&D investment through spillovers, therefore they are less willing to investment in cost-reducing R&D.. h ∂x = − 4 < 0 , indicating that firms are unwilling to when R&D ∂γ h1. is relatively costly. In addition,. h ∂x á s = − 5 > 0 if 2 22 < β , i.e. the incentive á1 s11 ∂α 1 h1. scheme, proposed by firm 1’s owner for its manager, puts a relatively higher weight. 6.

(9) on market share, firm 1’s manager will invest more in R&D. In the first stage, the two owners simultaneously choose the incentive schemes for their managers. Using x * ( β , γ , k , α1 , α 2 ) , we solve for α1* ( β , γ , k ) and. α 2* ( β , γ , k ) . The optimal values of the incentive schemes can be determined by solving the following system of first-order conditions (see Appendix C for the detailed calculation):   ∂V1 ∂x   α 1 s12  ∂q2  ∂c1 α s  ∂q  ∂c  = − 1 + q1  P′(Q) + 1 12  2  2 − γx  + s1 (Q) , q1  P′(Q) + ∂α 1 ∂α 1   q1  ∂c1  ∂x q1  ∂c2  ∂x     ∂V2 α 2 s21  ∂q1  ∂c1 α s  ∂q  ∂c ∂x    = − 1 + q2  P′(Q) + 2 21  1  2 − γx  + s2 (Q) . q2  P′(Q) + ∂α 2 ∂α 2   q2  ∂c1  ∂x q2  ∂c2  ∂x  . (8) Applying Implicit Function rule to the above equations, we can write: dm(α 1 ,α 2 ; k , β , γ ) ∫ m1dα 1 + m2 dα 2 + m3 dk + m4 dβ + m5 dγ = 0,. (9). dn(α 1 ,α 2 ; k , β , γ ) ∫ n1dα 1 + n2 dα 2 + n3 dk + n4 dβ + n5 dγ = 0,. where ∂ 2V1 ∂ 2V2 ∂ 2V1 ∂ 2V2 m1 ∫ < 0 , n1 ∫ < 0 , m2 ∫ < 0 , n2 ∫ <0, ∂α12 ∂α 22 ∂α 1∂α 2 ∂α 2 ∂α 1 ∂ 2V2 ∂ 2V2 ∂ 2V2 ∂ 2V1 ∂ 2V1 ∂ 2V1 m3 ∫ , n3 ∫ , m4 ∫ , n4 ∫ , m5 ∫ , n5 ∫ . ∂α1∂k ∂α1∂β ∂α1∂γ ∂α 2 ∂k ∂α 2 ∂β ∂α 2 ∂γ. As the determinant of the system of first-order conditions is strictly positive,. ∆ s1 = m1n2 − n1m2 > 0 ,. using. ∂α1 = (n3 m2 − m3 n2 )/∆ s1 , ∂k. the. Implicit. Function. ∂α 2 = (n1m3 − m1n3 )/∆ s1 , ∂k. Theorem. we. have:. ∂α 1 = (n4 m2 − m4 n2 )/∆ s1 , ∂β. ∂α 2 ∂α 1 ∂α 2 = (n1m4 − m1n4 )/∆ s1 , = (n5 m2 − m5 n2 )/∆ s1 , and = (n1m5 − m1n5 )/∆ s1 . ∂γ ∂β ∂γ. As shown in the second stage, with higher R&D spillovers both firms commit more competition since rival firms also benefit from cost-reducing R&D spillovers, therefore they invest less in R&D. In this case, the owner may choose higher weights. 7.

(10) for market share if (n4 m2 − m4 n2 ) > 0 . Similarly, the owner of rival firm choose higher weights for market share if (n1m4 − m1n4 ) > 0 . The cost of investment in R&D also affects the weight on market share. When R&D is relatively costly, the owner may choose lower weights for market share if n5 m2 < m5 n2 .. 4. Conclusion In this paper, we explore strategic delegation game with market share in the presence of spillovers. Specifically, we reconsider the three-stage model of Zhang and Zhang (1997), but adopt the managerial incentive scheme of Jansen et al (2007). The results show that with higher R&D spillovers both firms commit more competition since rival firms also benefit from cost-reducing R&D spillovers, therefore they invest less in R&D. In this case, the owner may choose higher weights for market share under certain condition. The cost of investment in R&D also affects the weight on market share. When R&D is relatively costly, the owner may choose lower weights for market share The managerial contracts considering for sales and market share may direct managers to allow for non-profit maximization. In the literature on the managerial incentive schemes, Zhang and Zhang (1997) pioneered in combining the strategic delegation in Fershtman-Judd-Sklivas framework with the aspect of cost-reducing R&D spillovers. It is well known that in the game of strategic delegation with R&D spillovers there are two counter effects. Strategic delegation may direct managers to act more aggressively. On the other hand, R&D spillovers reduce incentives to act aggressively since each firm can also benefit from its rival’s cost-reducing R&D. The results obtained in this paper suggest that industry-specific primary cost and its interaction with the level of spillovers determine the manager's R&D choice. Further, the choice of R&D investment need not be influenced by the degree of 8.

(11) spillovers when the owner's incentive scheme is market share based. This result offers an alternative explanation for the selected negotiations over intellectual property rights infringement between the developed countries and their developing counterparts.. Our model can be extended to the study of trade policy in the light of. cross-border intellectual property violations. Indeed, if owner’s choice in the first stage is replaced by government decisions over policy measures, such as tariff or subsidy, the current model can easily project into analyses of trade-related intellectual property protection.. 9.

(12) Appendix A. The outputs ( q1* ( c1 ,c2 ), q2* ( c1 ,c2 )) in the Cournot-Nash equilibrium satisfy the equations in (3). Then, ∂ 2V1 f1 (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ = P′′(Q)q1 + 2 P′(Q) + α1 s11 (Q) , 2 123 ∂q1 <0 f 2 (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫. ∂ 2V1 = P′′(Q)q1 + P′(Q) + α1 s12 (Q) , 123 ∂q1∂q2 < 0 if q1 < q2. f 3 ( q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫. ∂ 2V1 ∂ 2V1 = −1 , f 4 ( q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ = 0. ∂q1∂c1 ∂q1∂c2. ∂ 2V2 g1 (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ = P′′(Q)q2 + 2 P′(Q) + α 2 s22 (Q) , 2 123 ∂q2 <0 g 2 (q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫. ∂ 2V1 = P′′(Q)q2 + P′(Q) + α 2 s21 (Q) , 123 ∂q2 ∂q1 < 0 if q1 < q2. g 3 ( q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫. ∂ 2V2 ∂ 2V2 = 0 , g 4 ( q1 , q2 ; c1 , c2 ) ∫ = −1 . ∂q2 ∂c1 ∂q2 ∂c2. Appendix B. ∂V1  ∂P(Q) ∂c1  ∂q ∂q  ∂X  ∂q = − q1 + (P(Q) − c1 ) 1 + α1  s11 1 + s12 2  − 1 ∂x  ∂x ∂x  ∂x ∂x ∂x  ∂x   ∂P(Q) ∂q1 ∂P(Q) ∂q2 ∂c1  ∂q ∂q ∂X q1 + (P(Q) − c1 + α1 s11 ) 1 + α1 s12 2 − 1 =  + − 1 4 4 4 2 4 4 4 3 ∂q2 ∂x ∂x  ∂x ∂x ∂x  ∂q1 ∂x ' = − P ( Q ) q1.     ∂ q ∂ c ∂q2 ∂X 1 ∂ P ( Q ) 2 1  = − q1 + α1 s12 −  ∂q2 ∂x ∂x  ∂x ∂x { { 4243 size{effect  1 market share effect cos t effect  strategic effect      ∂P(Q) α s  ∂q  ∂c1  ∂P(Q) α1 s12  ∂q2 ∂c2  ∂X 1 1 12 2  = q1   + − 1 + + −   ∂ q q ∂ c ∂x  ∂q2 q1  ∂c2 ∂x  { ∂x 1  1  442 4442  1 444443 14444244443 cos t effect   share − adjusted spillover effect share − adjusted strategic effect. 10.

(13) Appendix C.. ∂V1  ∂c  ∂q  ∂q  ∂X 1 =  P ′(Q) − 1 q1 + (P (Q) − c1 + α 1 s11 ) 1 +  s1 (Q) + α 1 s12 2  − 144 42444 3 ∂α 1  ∂α 1  ∂α 1  ∂α 1  ∂α 1 − P′ ( Q ) q1  ∂P (Q) ∂q1 ∂P (Q) ∂q 2 ∂c1  ∂q  ∂q  ∂X 1  − P ′(Q)q1 1 +  s1 (Q) + α 1 s12 2  − = q1  + − ∂q 2 ∂α 1 ∂α 1  ∂α 1  ∂α 1  ∂α 1  ∂q1 ∂α 1 ∂q ∂c ∂X 1 = (P ′(Q)q1 + α 1 s12 ) 2 − q1 1 − + s1 (Q) ∂α 1 ∂α 1 ∂α 1  ∂q ∂c ∂x ∂q 2 ∂c2 ∂x  ∂c1 ∂x ∂X 1 ∂x = (P ′(Q)q1 + α 1 s12 ) 2 1 + − + s1 (Q)  − q1 ∂x ∂α 1 ∂x ∂α 1  ∂c1 ∂x ∂α 1 ∂c2 ∂x ∂α 1    ∂q 2 ∂c1 ∂q 2 ∂c2  ∂c1 ∂x  = + − γx  + s1 (Q) (P ′(Q)q1 + α 1 s12 )  − q1 ∂α 1  ∂x  ∂c1 ∂x ∂c2 ∂x   =. α 1 s12 ∂x    q1  P ′(Q) + ∂α 1  q1  .  ∂c   ∂q 2 αs  − 1 1 + q1  P ′(Q) + 1 12 q1  ∂c1  ∂x .   ∂q 2  ∂c2   − γx  + s1 (Q)    ∂c2  ∂x . ∂V2 ∂q ∂c ∂X = (P′(Q)q2 + α 2 s 21 ) 1 − q2 2 − 2 + s 2 (Q) ∂α 2 ∂α 2 ∂α 2 ∂α 2  ∂q ∂c ∂x ∂q1 ∂c2 ∂x  ∂c2 ∂x ∂X 2 ∂x = (P′(Q)q2 + α 2 s 21 ) 1 1 + − + s 2 (Q)  − q2 ∂x ∂α 2 ∂x ∂α 2  ∂c1 ∂x ∂α 2 ∂c2 ∂x ∂α 2    ∂q1 ∂c1 ∂q1 ∂c2  ∂c2 ∂x  = + − γx  + s 2 (Q) (P′(Q)q2 + α 2 s 21 )  − q1 ∂α 2  ∂x  ∂c1 ∂x ∂c2 ∂x     α 2 s21  ∂q1  ∂c1 α s  ∂q  ∂c ∂x    = − 1 + q2  P′(Q) + 2 21  1  2 − γx  + s 2 (Q) q2  P′(Q) + ∂α 2   q2  ∂c1  ∂x q2  ∂c2  ∂x  . Reference D’Aspremont, C., Jacquemin, A., 1988. Cooperative and noncooperative R&D in duopoly with spillovers. American Economic Review 78, 1133-1137. Demsetz, H., 1983. The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm. Journal of Law and Economics 26, 375-390. Fama, E.F., Jensen, M.C., 1983. Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301-325.. 11.

(14) Fershtman, C., 1985. Managerial incentives as a strategic variable in duopolistic environment. International Journal of Industrial Organization 3, 245-253. Fershtman, C., Judd, K.L., 1987. Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly. American Economic Review 77, 927-940. Georing, G.E., 1996. Managerial style and the strategic choice of executive incentives. Managerial and Decision Economics 17, 71-82. Jansen, T., van Lier, A., van Witteloostuijn, A., 2007. A note on strategic delegation: The market share case. International Journal of Industrial Organization 25, 531539. Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360. Kopel, M., Riegler, C., 2006. R&D in a strategic delegation game revisited: A note. Managerial and Decision Economics 27, 605-612. Krakel, M., 2004. R&D spillovers and strategic delegation in oligopolistic contests. Managerial and Decision Economics 25, 147-156. Lackman, C.L., Craycroft, J.L., 1974. Sales maximization and oligopoly: A case study. Journal of Industrial Economics 23, 81-95. Sklivas, S.D., 1987. The strategic choice of managerial incentives. RAND Journal of Economics 18, 452-458. Vickers, J., 1985. Delegation and the theory of the firm. Economic Journal 95, 138-147. Zhang, J., Zhang, Z., 1997. R&D in a strategic delegation game. Managerial and Decision Economics 18, 391-398.. 12.

(15)

參考文獻

相關文件

It is interesting that almost every numbers share a same value in terms of the geometric mean of the coefficients of the continued fraction expansion, and that K 0 itself is

The presentation or rebranding by a company of an established product in a new form, a new package or under a new label into a market not previously explored by that company..

Setting 1997 Q3 as the dividing point, we compare two cases of labor rent: “domestic and foreign labor market” and “domestic labor market”, before and after the minimum wage

The share of India &amp; Taiwan in the World economy and discussed how world export-import market is increasing year by year.. The data shows us that the business between these

Regardless of the assumed copula functions, we consistently find that the Chinese market experiences not only a higher degree of dependence but also a higher variation of

With a service driven market and customer service being of the utmost importance to enterprises trying to gain and maintain market share, the building and implementing of

Under the multiple competitive dynamics of the market, market commonality and resource similarity, This research analyze the competition and the dynamics of

The results show that (1) vertical integration, investment intensity and debt ratio have significantly negative impacts on ROE, (2) capital intensity and market share rate