• 沒有找到結果。

論高齡化社會的教育政策與社會安全制度

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "論高齡化社會的教育政策與社會安全制度"

Copied!
41
0
0

加載中.... (立即查看全文)

全文

(1)

國立台灣大學社會科學院經濟學系 碩士論文

Department of Economics College of Social Sciences National Taiwan University

Master Thesis

論高齡化社會的教育政策與社會安全制度 Education Systems and Social Security in an

Aging Economy

研究生 : 楊子霆 Yang, Tzu-Ting 指導教授 : 陳虹如 博士

Advisor: Chen, Hung-Ju, Ph.D.

中華民國 977

July, 2008

(2)

謝詞

如果說現在是因為過去的種種所導致的,在台大6年的學生生活,會因為 這篇論文的完成而結束,那我想我應該要感謝這篇論文,為了要走到今天 這一步,過程中我認識了許多好朋友。

首先是 「虹門」 的大家長,幫主兼指導教授陳虹如老師,我必須說,這一 年幫主辛苦了!您犧牲自己的空閒時間,收留並教養咱們孤苦無依的4, 希望您回首過去一年的辛苦,能與我們一樣覺得是值得回憶的,也希望幫 主與我們在人生的道路上一同繼續奮鬥努力。 此外,藉由這次論文,我也 多認識經濟系其他認真努力的好老師,我的口試委員毛慶生教授與王泓 仁教授,你們的認真閱讀讓我感動萬分。

說真的,我覺得寫論文能擁有師兄師姐師弟師妹是一件幸福的事。 不 像理工科系, 能一夥人在實驗室裡分工合作進行研究, 做社會科學的研 究, 其實是很孤單而且寂寞,但這一年來, 因為有你們, 很多想法就是在 跟你們討論中得到進展,也因為你們,在寫作的過程中,才會覺得那麼安 心且愉快。

二年前,我忘記報名預官考試, 因為如此,我沒先去當兵,當時很懊悔, 但也因為這樣,我成了95級經研所的一員,認識了那麼多tone很合的朋 友,相處的很easy很舒服,跟你們出去玩都不會擔心無聊,進研究所前,有 朋友跟我說,研究所的生活是各過各的,我想我們班是個反例。

另外,需要補充說明的是, 二年前一次隨機過程, 讓我得到 r95323010 這個學號,這個學號除了保佑我能在二年研究所課程能夠pass, 也在 我即將離開這個學號時,給了我它的分身,繼續陪在我身旁。

六年前,我進入了台大政治系,說實話,身為大學生的日子是我人生最 重要的4, 謝謝這些政治系與社會系的好朋友與老師,以及在師大附中 畢業後就一直保持聯絡的四人幫,因為你們,我才是現在的我。

最後,二十四年前,我爸媽生下了我,支持我這個尼特族生活上的所有 需要,在即將入伍報效國家的同時,我要說:爸、 媽、 弟,我愛你們。

(3)

論文摘要

本文旨在探討高齡化社會下教育政策與養老金制度的關係。 我 們利用一個內生化生育決策的三期疊代模型,分析在不同的預 期壽命與養老金所得替代率下, 實行公立教育體制、 私立教育 體制與補貼私立教育政策對經濟成長的影響。 結果發現若政 府沒有實施 「隨收隨付制」 的養老金制度,由於公立教育體制 會使得家計單位錯估教養小孩的成本,導致家計單位撫養過多 小孩, 造成教育資源的稀釋, 故在此一情況下, 採行私立教育 體制能得到較高的經濟成長。 但若政府實施 「隨收隨付制」 的 養老金制度,現在撫養較多小孩意味著未來能擁有較多勞動力 去分擔養老金的稅負,則何種教育體制能夠誘發較高的經濟成 長,取決於這個經濟社會的平均預期壽命與所採取的養老金政 策,我們發現由於公立教育體制或補助私立教育政策能鼓勵家 計單位撫養較多小孩,進而減低養老金稅率對經濟成長的負面 影響。 故模擬結果發現當一個經濟社會擁有足夠高的平均預 期壽命或養老金所得替代率,公立教育體制或補助私立教育政 策能導致較高的經濟成長。 因此,我們建議政府當局若是要促 進長期經濟成長,必須同時考慮教育與養老金政策。

關鍵字:人口老化;教育體制;養老金制度 JEL分類: J14, J13, J18。

(4)

Abstract

This paper studies the interaction between two main public policies, edu- cation and social security, in an aging economy. We compare the balanced growth rate between different education systems (a private education sys- tem, a public education system and a voucher program) at steady state with various life expectancies and pension replacement rates. The results suggest that if govenment does not implement pay-as-you-go (PAYG) social secu- rity program, a private education system can induce higher growth at any degree of longevity. In contrast, as government implements PAYG social security program, which education systems can enhance economic growth depends on the life expectancy of an economy and the policy of pension benefit. Our calibrated results reveal that a public education system or a voucher program can yield higher growth than a private education system by encouraging parents to raise children and then reducing the adverse im- pact of PAYG social security on capital accumulation and growth when an economy with sufficiently high life expectancy and pension replacement ratio. The implication of our analysis indicates that in order to promote economic growth, policy makers should consider these two public policies jointly.

Key Words: Ageing;Education systems;Social security JEL Classification: J14, J13, J18

(5)

Contents

1 Introduction 1

2 The Model Economy 5

2.1 Production . . . 6

2.2 PAYG Social security system. . . 7

2.3 Education Systems . . . 8

2.3.1 A private education system. . . 8

2.3.2 A public education system . . . 11

2.4 Growth . . . 14

3 Computational Experiments 17 3.1 Calibration . . . 17

3.2 Comparing private and public education systems . . . 19

3.2.1 The effect of longevity . . . 19

3.2.2 The effect of replacement ratio . . . 21

3.3 Policy Implication: Subsidizing Private education . . . 23

4 Empirical Implications 25

5 Conclusion 28

6 Technical Appendix 30

7 Reference 32

(6)

List of Figures

1 Dependency ratio age 65 above . . . 1

2 Life expectancies and education systems . . . 20

3 Replacement ratios and education systems . . . 22

4 Fertility rate and private funding on education . . . 27

5 The increase in social security program and private funding on education 27

(7)

List of Tables

1 Calibrated values of baseline model . . . 19

2 Longevity and educational systems . . . 21

3 Replacement ratio and educational systems . . . 23

4 Longevity and subsidy of education . . . 24

5 Replacement ratio and subsidy of education . . . 25

6 Education systems, fertility rate and social security . . . 26

7 Fertility rate and private educational funding . . . 26 8 Growth of social security program and private educational funding 28

(8)

1 Introduction

The phenomenon of population aging has been undergoing in most in- dustrial countries from 1980s. Fig. 1shows that the ratios of the old (65 year above) to total population in OECD countries in 1960 are below 10%

but in 2005 these ratios are nearly 20% because longevity is increasing steadily and birth rate is declining dramatically.

Figure 1: Dependency ratio age 65 above

19605 1970 1980 1990 2000 2005

10 15 20

Dependcy Ratio (65 years old eldery)

Spain Japan Italy OECD

Soouce: World Development Indicators

Such big change in population structure leads to so-called ”an aging economy (society)” and brings many challenges and debates for public policies, especially, the design of social security systems and educational policies. For example, the financial sustainability of pay-as-you-go (PAYG) social security systems, which have been adopted by most developed coun- tries virtually (Breyer and Craig 1997), confronts many doubts since pop- ulation aging leads the more needs (old retiree) for pension benefits but the fewer contributions (young employees) to pension funding (see, such as, Zhang, Zhang and Lee, 2001; Pecchenino and Pollard, 2002).

Another issue rised from this demographic change is whether the in- creasing olds tend to be against distributing resources on public education for young generation. Several theortical and empirical researches dis- cussed this topic but did not achieve consensus (see, for example, Poterba, 1997; Harris, Evans and Schwab, 2001; Zhang, Zhang and Lee, 2003 ,

(9)

Gradstein and Kaganovich, 2004; Grob and Wolter, 2005).

Different from previous studies considering educational policies and social security systems separately, this paper addresses the importance of the coordination between educational policies and social security systems in an aging economy and answer the following questions. First, which education systems is favoring for enhancing economic growth in an aging economy with or without PAYG social security program? Second, can government use educational policies to ease off the heavy tax burden of PAYG social security program accompanied by population aging?

More recently, some studies investigated the link between educational policies and PAYG social security system (see, for example, Kaganovich and Zilcha, 1999; Kemnitz, 2000; Pecchenino and Pollard, 2002; Rojas, 2004; Soares, 2006). On the one hand, most studies in this topic dis- cussed the effect of PAYG social security system on public education pol- icy and assumed fertility is exogenous. Kaganovich and Zilcha (1999) studied the optimal allocation of tax revenue between public education and PAYG social security. Their results suggested that if agents have high levels of altruism toward children and significant concern for their re- tirement income, then it is optimal to provide PAYG social security pro- gram. Because PAYG social security makes agents save less for retiring period and invest more in offspring human capital, which can enhance economic growth and social welfare. Kemnitz (2000) and Soares(2006) also argued that implementing PAYG social security system may generate political support for public education since public education can broaden future PAYG social security benefit of pensioners. Pecchenino and Pol- lard (2002) considered that if the quality of public education is sufficiently high, lowering PAYG social security tax and increasing the public educa- tion funding can uplift economic growth and social welfare.

On the other hand, very few researches think about reverse causality of both policies, that is, how education policies influence PAYG social secu- rity system, especially PAYG social security tax burden. To the best of our

(10)

knowledge, only Rojas (2004) was from this point of view. Rojas (2004) analyzed the economic effect of subsidizing higher education. He showed that subsidizing higher education not only directly raises the average edu- cational level of the economy but also indirectly leads population aging by reducing average fertility rate, and then resulted in heavier tax suffering of PAYG social security system. Our work also starts from this point of view and we use a three periods overlapping generation model with en- dogenous fertility to show the possible link between education systems and PAYG social security program in an aging economy.

There has been much recent interest in modeling the impact of ed- ucation systems on long-run economic growth and income distribution (see, for example, Glomm and Ravikumar 1992; Zhang 1996; Croix and Doepke 2004; Chen 2005). Most of them use the model with exogenous fertility and find public education regime can result in more equal income distribution and bring higher economic growth than private education regime when the initial income inequality is sufficiently high.

However, de la Croix and Doepke (2004) argued that it is worthy to consider fertility behavior and educational policies at the same time. They use the framework of Glomm and Ravikumar (1992) but with endogenous fertility to highlight the fertility differential between the poor (unskilled workers) and the rich (skilled workers) is a key factor when analyzing economic consequence of education systems. They argued that in a pub- lic education regime, which provides free education, all parents have the same number and educational investment of their children but in a pri- vate education regime, where parents can determine the amount of ed- ucational investment for their children, due to quantity-quality tradeoff caused by difference of the opportunity cost of raising children, poor par- ents have more children and invest less in education per child. Accord- ingly, if the initial income inequality is sufficiently high, the effect of fer- tility differential in a private education regime may lead unskilled work- ers become the majority of labor force, which downsizes average human

(11)

capital, and then results in lower economic growth than public education regime.

In this paper, the theoretical model used here is similar to de la Croix and Doepke (2004) but our model adds the setting of the longevity and PAYG social security system, which lets us compare the economic per- formance between different education systems in an aging economy with or without PAYG social security. At first, we compare the implications of a public and a private education regime for economic growth in an aging economy without PAYG social security program. The closed form solu- tions reveal that in a private education regime individual will have fewer numbers of children and invest more in education per child. This will generate the higher growth than in a public education regime. Our find- ing is consistent with the result of homogenous agents case in Glomm and Ravikumar (1992) and low income inequality case in de la Croix and Doepke (2004). However, while considering an economy with PAYG social security system, we find that if longevity or pension replacement rate is sufficiently high, providing public schooling or voucher program (subsidy of private education) may stimulate higher economic growth than adopting private education system by increase fertility rate and then lighten the heavy burden of PAYG social security program.

This paper contributes several new directions to the researches of edu- cation systems and social security. From the view of the literatures on ed- ucation systems, many previous studies pointed out initial income distri- bution plays an important role in comparing economic growth between a private and public education regime. Our model shows that even if there is no income inquality a public education system still can generate higher growth than a private education system when we consider the factors of longevity and PAYG social security. In other words, our model points out that longevity and PAYG scoial security program matter in comparison of different education systems.

On the other hand, many previous studies try to provide several policy

(12)

tools for solving the financial crisis of existing PAYG social security sys- tem. For instance, Groezen, Leers and Meijdam (2003) and Oshio (2005) suggested that if government implements PAYG social security system, it has to provide childcare support, such as child allowance, simultaneously for giving incentive to fertility. Because under PAYG social security sys- tem children are not only a private good but also a kind of ”public good”, private optimal number of children is smaller than social optimum (see, for a review, e.g. Cigno, 1992; Groezen and Meijdam, 2008).

Besides providing child allowance to influence fertility behavior, in- spired by the wisdom of family economics (Becker, 1973), we know that parents would determine the number of children and the educational in- vestment of children jointly, that is the famous conjecture of quantity- quality tradeoff. Consequently, government can also use educational poli- cies to affect individual fertility behavior. Our results reveal that offering free public education or subsidy of private education can encourage par- ents to give more births and then alleviate the financial vulnerability of PAYG social security system.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents our model economy Section 3 gives the calibration of the model. We com- pare the economic growth between different educational systems under various longevity and pension replacement ratio. Section 4 shows some empirical supports of our model. Section 5 concludes this paper.

2 The Model Economy

We consider an economy populated by infinite homogeneous agents who live for three periods. Each period is around 30 years, referring to youth, adulthood, and old age. But only p percent adults can survive in their old age1. Young agents study in the school, middle-aged agents raise their children and work, and old agents retire to enjoy leisure and survive on

1Here, we use p to represent the average life expectancy of an economy. For example, given p= 0.5, an economy will have 50% population with life expectancy of 75 years and 50% population with life expectancy of 50 years, which means the average life expectancy in this economy is 62.5 years.

(13)

their saving and government transfer. Agents have the same preference and make all their lifetime decisions in adulthood. They care about con- sumption in middle age cmt , consumption in old age cot, how many chil- dren they raise nt, and the human capital of their children ht+1. We can use the following function to represent an individual’s utility.

lncmt  + pσ lncot + γ lnnt + β lnht+1 (1) where subscript t represents ”generation t” which means agents are in their adulthood at time t. The parameter σ is the discount factor of the utility for the consumption in old age. The parameters γ and β respec- tively denote the strength of preference over the number of children and the human capital of children. The human capital of the children ht+1depends on parental human capital ht and school expenditure et, which deter- mines the quality of education received from school.

ht+1= λetδht1−δ (2) where λ is positive constant and δ  0, 1. The parameters δ and 1 − δ measure the elasticity of school expenditure and parental human capi- tal on human capital per child, repectively. This human capital accumu- lation technology is constant return to scale in school expenditure and parental human capital. We divide the school expenditure funded pri- vately and publicly, which will be discussed more details about two edu- cation regimes in the section 2.3.

2.1 Production

Assume that there are many homogenous firms producing single goods to maximize their profit in a prefectly competitive market. Their produc- tion technology is Cobb-Douglas function and satisfies constant return to scale. Hence, aggregate production function in economy become:

Yt=F(Kt,Lt)=AKθtL1t−θ (3)

(14)

where A 0 is the total factor productivity; θ is elasticity of capital stock on output; Ktis aggregate capital stock at time t; Lt= Ntlthtis the aggre- gate effective labor supply; Nt is total working population (the numbers of adults at time t). We assume that each adult is endowed with 1 unit of time and spend ϕnt of the time (ϕ  0, 1) to raise their offsprings and the remaining time lt = 1 − ϕntis an individual labor supply. We define per effective labor capital stock (physical-human capital ratio) mt= NtKlttht so Eq.3 can be rewritten in intensive form:

yt= Amθt (4)

where yt = NtYlttht. Since the market structure in the economy is prefect competitive, firms take the wage rate, wt and interest (rental) rate, Rt, as given. Firms employ each production fator at the price where is equal to its marginal product:

wt= 1 − θAmtθ (5)

Rt= θAmtθ−1 (6)

2.2 PAYG Social security system

Assume that government always maitain a balanced budget to finance the PAYG social security program. Government levies a propotional wage income tax τt1 − ϕntwthton adults at time t to transfer Vtfor elderly at the same time. Social security budget constraint is:

Ntτt1 − ϕntwtht= Nt−1pVt (7) in which Nt−1p and Nt2 can be interpreted as the beneficial and con- tributed population, respectively. Following Cooley and Soares(1999) and Pecchenino and Pollard(2002), we denote the pension replacement rate B as follows:

2We know that Nt= Nt−1nt−1

(15)

B= Vt

1 − ϕntwtht

(8) The replacement rate B is the ratio of pension transfer Vt to the wage income of current employees 1 − ϕntwtht and government adjust the social security tax rate τt to keep this ratio constant. We can learn the relationship between the demographic structure and the tax rate τtfrom substituting Eq.8 into Eq.7 :

τt= Nt−1pB Nt = pB

nt−1 (9)

Eq.9 indicates that life expectancy increasing or fertility rate declin- ing will lead heavier PAYG social security tax burden.

2.3 Education Systems

2.3.1 A private education system

In a private education regime, an adult needs to choose consumption in the middle age crtm, saving for old age srt, the number of children nrt, and education expenditure per child ert. Their wage income is taxed at the rate of τrt for social security. Notice that we denote the variables with subscript r to represent private education regime and u to represent pub- lic education regime The budget constraint for an adult is:

cmrt+ srt+ ertnrt = 1 − τrt1 − ϕnrtwrthrt (10) The elderly consumption deponds on their middle age saving and so- cial security transfer.In this model, we assume that agents invest their saving in a mutual fund. Only agents surviving to old age can get the re- turn from mutual fund. Thus, the gross rate of return of mutual fund for surviving old is rrt+1 = Rr t+1p . The budget contraint in an agent’s old age become:

cort = rrt+1srt+ Vt+1 (11)

(16)

According to Eqs.10 and 11 we can drive the intertemporal budget constraint for an adult:

crtm+ ertnrt+ cort

rrt+1 = 1 − τrt1 − ϕnrtwrthrt+ Vrt+1

rrt+1 (12) Hence, under private education regime an adult at time t solves the following lifetime utility maximization problem:

sr tmax,er t,nr tUrt = lncmrt + pσ lncort + γ lnnrt + β lnhrt+1

subject to cmrt + ertnrt+ cort

rrt+1 = 1 − τrt1 − ϕnrtwrthrt+ Vrt+1

rrt+1 (13) Definition 1 (Under a private education regime equilibrium) Given the initial human capital endowments h0 , preferences ,longevity ,human cap- ital accumulation technology ,production technology, an equilibrium con- sists of aggregate capital stocks{Hrt ,Krt}, sequences of prices {wrt ,Rrt}, household decisions {crtm ,cort srt ,nrt ,ert}, and policy variables {Vrtrt} such that :

1. given factor prices{wrt,Rrt} and policy variables {Vrtrt}, the house- hold decisions {cmrt ,crto srt ,nrt ,ert} maximize utility subject to the con- straints Eq.(2) and (12);

2. factor prices{wrt ,Rrt} clear markets;

3. labor market clear : Lrt= Nrt1 − ϕnrthrt

capital market clear : Krt+1= Nrtsrt3

goods market clear : Yrt= Nrtcmrt+ pNrt−1cort−1+ Krt+1

4. the government’s budget constraint Eq. (7) is satisfied;

The first-order conditions for an adult’s optimal choices of life-cycle saving srt, number of children nrt, and educational investment per child ertunder a private education system are:

3We assume 100% depreciation for physical capital because one period in our model is 30 years

(17)

1 cmrt = σ

crto rrt+1 (14)

1

cmrt1 − τrtϕnrtwrthrt= γ nrt

(15)

1

crtmnrt = β

hrt+1λδertδ−1hrt1−δ (16) For maximizing utility, according to Eq.14, individuals balance the loss in utility from reducing middle age consumption (marginal cost of saving) and the gain in utility from increasing old age consumption (marginal benefit of saving) to determine the quantity of saving for retirement. By Eq.15 individuals choose the number of children and middle age con- sumption such that equate the loss in utility from diminishing consump- tion in adulthood to spend time caring children (marginal cost of rais- ing one child) to the gain in utility from one more child (marginal ben- efit of raising one child). Under a private education system, adults face the ”quantity-quality” tradeoff of their offspring, which is depicted by Eq.16. Eq.16 means the loss in utility from cutting the consumption of middle age for financing educational expenditure of children (marginal cost of increasing the level of human capital per child) should be equal to the gain in utility from improvement of offspring human capital (marginal benefit of increasing the level of human capital per child). That is, once adults decide to have more children and then will invest less on offspring human capital.

From the first order conditions of utility maximization Eqs.14–16, budget constraint Eqs.10–11 ,and capital market clear condition Krt+1= Nrtsrt, we can derive an adult’s optimal choices of life-cycle saving srt, ed- ucation expenditure per child ert, and the number of children nrtunder a private education system:

srt= pσθ1 − τrtwrthrt

τrt1 − θ1 + γ + θ1 + pσ + γ (17)

(18)

ert = βδϕ1 − τrtwrthrt

γ− βδ (18)

nrt = γ − βδτrt1 − θ + θ

ϕτrt1 − θ1 + γ + θ1 + pσ + γ (19)

2.3.2 A public education system

The only difference between public education system and private edu- cation system is that adults do not need to choose school expenditure for their children under public schooling regime. Instead, educational spending is funded through another proportional wage income tax ηut

and public school is provided free for all households. Government runs balanced budget to finance public education expenditure.

eutnut= ηut1 − ϕnutwuthut (20) where eutis public education expenditure per child. Educational tax rate ηutis determined by political process, which will be discussed laterly. The budget constraint for agents in their middle age and old age become :

cmut+ sut= 1 − τut− ηut1 − ϕnutwuthut (21)

cuto = rut+1sut+ Vut+1 (22) From Eqs.21 and 22 we can drive the intertemporal budget con- straint for adults under public schooling system:

cutm + cuto

rut+1 = 1 − τut− ηut1 − ϕnutwuthut+Vut+1

rut+1 (23) Consequently, an adult at time t solves the following lifetime utility maximization problem:

smaxut,nutUut= lncmut + pσ lncout + γ lnnut + β lnhut+1

(19)

subject to cutm+ cuto

rut+1 = 1 − τut− ηut1 − ϕnutwuthut+ Vut+1

rut+1 (24) Definition 2 (Under a public education regime equilibrium) Given the ini- tial human capital endowments h0, preferences ,longevity ,human capital accumulation technology ,production technology, an equilibrium consists of aggregate capital stocks{Hut,Kut}, sequences of prices {wut,Rut}, house- hold decisions {cutm ,cuto sut ,nut}, and policy variables {Vututut ,eut} such that :

1. given factor prices {wut ,Rut} and policy variables {Vutut}, the households’ decisions{cutm ,coutsut,nut ,eut} maximize utility subject to the constraints Eq.(2) and (22);

2. factor prices{wut,Rut} clear markets;

3. labor market clear : Lut= Nut1 − ϕnuthut

capital market clear : Kut+1= Nutsut

goods market clear : Yut= Nutcmut+ pNut−1cout−1+ Kut+1

4. the government’s budget constraint Eqs.(7) and (20) are satisfied;

5. given households’ decisions, the policy variables{ηut,eut} maximize the utility of adult agents;

The first order conditions for an adult’s optimal choices of life-cycle saving srt and number of children nrt under a public education system are:

1 cutm = σ

coutrut+1 (25)

1

cutm1 − τut− ηutϕnutwuthut= γ nut

(26) The economic intuition of Eqs.25–26 are similar to Eqs.14–15

,respectively. The individuals equate the marginal rate of substitution be- tween current and old age consumption to the return rate of mutual fund and the marginal rate of substitution between current consumption and a child to the marginal cost of bearing an extra child. The most important

(20)

difference between two education systems is that under public education system adults do not need to consider the ”quantity-quality” tradeoff of children (Eq.16). In other words, since public education is provided free, adults do not think that the gain in utility from an extra child is at expense of the decline of the quality of school of ”all households”. There- fore, adults in the public education regime have more children than ones in the private education regime because marginal cost of an extra child under public schooling system is cheaper.

From the first order conditions of utility maximization Eqs.24–25, budget constraint Eqs.21–22, and capital market clear condition Kut+1= Nutsut, we can derive an adult’s optimal choices of middle age saving sut

and the number of children nutunder a public education system:

sut= pσθ1 − τut− ηutwuthut

τ1 − θ1 + γ + θ1 + pσ + γ (27)

nut= γτut1 − θ + θ

ϕτut1 − θ1 + γ + θ1 + pσ + γ (28) Next, we describe the political process for educational tax rate. The educational tax rate ηutis determined by majority voting. The adults vote on the ηutto maximize their life-time utilities. The preferred tax rate is chosen by the following indirect utility maximization problem:

maxηut Uut= lncmut + pσ lncout + γ lnnut + β lnhut+1

subject to Eqs.2, 20 and 27–28 (29) We can obtain the preferred education tax rate as follows:

ηut= βδ1 − τut

1+ pσ + βδ (30)

where ηut< 1. Substituting Eq.30 to the government budget constraint Eq.20 and the resulting choice for public education expenditure per children is:

(21)

eut= βδ1 − τutwuthut1 − ϕnut

1 + pσ + βδnut

(31) Proposition 1 For both education regimes, an economy with longer life ex- pectancy has lower fertility rate and higher PAYG social security tax rate.

Proof. See Appendix

Proposition 1 is very intuitive. When a rational individual knows that he/she has longer life span, he/she will work hard and save more for ”live- long” retirement. Increasing labor supply is at the cost of bearing fewer children. Consequently, the extension of life expectancy not only results in more living olds directly but also alters an adult’s fertility decision, to have fewer offspring, and thereby leads aging population. The implica- tion of population aging for PAYG social security system is that more retiree need for pension benefits but fewer labor force (employees) can contribute pension funding, namely, the tax burden of PAYG social secu- rity program will be heavier.

2.4 Growth

In this section, we use the steady-state balanced growth rate to com- pare the economic performance between private and public education regimes. Along the balanced growth path, the growth rate of physical capital per worker and the growth rate of individual human capital ac- cumulation will be the same as the growth rate of output per capita. The following equations express the above concepts:

1+ gk=

Kt+1 Nt+1 Kt

Nt

= A1 − θmtθ−1St

nt

(32)

1+ gh= ht+1

ht = λA1 − θmtθEtltδ (33)

1+ g =

Yt+1 Nt+1 Yt Nt

= 1 + gk= 1 + gh (34)

(22)

where St= 1−ϕnstiwthtis the ratio of saving to wage income, Et=1−ϕnettwthtis the ratio of education expenditure to wage income, ntis fertility rate,and lt = 1 − ϕnt is an individual labor supply. Eq.32 devides into Eq.33

yields the law of motion of mt.

mt+1= A1 − θst

λA1 − θetltδnt

mθt1−δ (35)

At steady state, the fertility rate ntis a constant and we can neglect the time subscript. From Eqs.9 and 20, we know that the tax rates τtand ηt depends on n. Therefore, the tax rates τt and ηt are time-invariant.

In addition, the physical-human capital ratio is also constant over time, mt+1= mt= m. We substitute mtin either Eq.32 or Eq.33 and obtain the balanced growth rate of output per capita 1+ g:

1+ gi = HSi

ni

θδEiδ1−θliδ1−θ1−θ1−δ1 , i= r, u (36) where i = r, u indicates the private and public education regimes respec- tively, H= λ1−θA1 − θδis a constant. Eq.36 shows that Si, Eiand ni

are three determinants of growth. 4 The ratio of saving Si and education investment Eito labor income both cause positive effect on the balanced growth rate obviously. However, fertility rate ni has both positive and negative impacts on the balanced growth rate. Negative one is so-called

”resource-dilution effect”, that is, bearing more children dilutes educa- tional resources at present time and output per capita in the future. Pos- itive one is ”tax-sharing effect”; a higher number of children also implies that there are more labor force for sharing PAYG social security burden in the future.

Proposition 2 Without PAYG social security program (B = 0), that is, an economy with fully-funded social security system or without offering any social security program, given any life expenctancy p an economy with pri- vate education system has higher balanced-growth rate than the one with public education system.

4Since labor supply liis a function of fertility niwe do not treat lias another growth determinant.

(23)

Proof. See Appendix

Proposition 2 indicates that when longevity increases but government does not implement PAYG social security program, private education sys- tem can stimulate higher economic growth than public education system does. The reason is that the education expenditure in public schooling regime is financed by tax revenue not households themselves, it gives par- ents incentive to have more children and free ride educational resource.

High fertility rate leads ”resource-dilution effect” and thereby has nega- tive impact on balanced growth rate. This result is consistent with the ho- mogenous agent case in Glomm and Ravikumar (1992) and low income inequality case in de la Croix and Doepke (2004). However, as Zhang and Zhang (2001) points out that an increase in longevity also has indi- rect effect on growth through the higher burden of PAYG social security system. Therefore, it is necessary and interesting to see whether the re- sult will be changed when considering PAYG social security system in our model economy.

Proposition 3 When implementing PAYG social security system (B  0), an economy with private education system has higher level of PAYG social security tax than the one with public education system. Moreover, a higher social security tax rate reduces the steady-state capital accumulation and balanced growth rate.

Proof. See Appendix

If government implements PAYG social security program,raising more children will have ”tax-sharing effect” by broadening future tax base of PAYG social security program and give posititve impact on economic growth. On balance, implementing PAYG social security system makes children involve a positive externality (Groezen, Leers and Meijdam, 2003).

Hence, government can use several policy tools to ”correct” the external- ity resulted from public pension policy, such as child allowance, which is

(24)

discussed a lot by previous studies (Groezen, Leers and Maijdam, 2003 ; Oshio, 2005). Proposition 3 suggests that providing public education may be another policy instrument to encourage parents to bear children and then mitigate the heavier and heavier PAYG social security burden in an aging economy. Furthermore, it also reveals that high level of PAYG social security tax has a negative impact on capital accumulation and balanced growth rate, for this reason, public education system may have possibil- ity to stimulate higher economic growth than private education system if ”tax-sharing effect” dominates ”resource-dilution effect”. The following section, we present the calibrated version of our model to obtain clearer picture of the above two opposite effects when comparing the economic performance between public and private education systems.

3 Computational Experiments

3.1 Calibration

In order to obtain credible quantitative results of our theory, we calibrate our model to match the growth features of the US or other OECD coun- tries. There are five features that we want to match: life expectancy, annual growth rate of output per capita, total fertility rate per woman (TFR=2nt 5), the share of education expenditure on output and the tax rate of PAYG social security. Because public school enrollment rate is higher than pri- vate school enrollment rate in most countries (Chen, 2005 ; de la Croix and Doepke, 2007), our baseline model, which is calibrated to fit the real world data, is an economy with public education system.

One preiod (generation) in our model is assumed 30 years and agents can survive safely for two preiods, that is, life expectancy in our model economy is at least 60 years old. We set p = 0.5 to match life expectancy in the United States at 2000 (about 76 years old). According to standard real business cycle literatures (Docquier and Paddison,2003), we set discount

5Since at least two people (a male and a female) can give a birth in the real world, but our model economy is ”asexual reproduction” (an agent can have his/her offspring individually.) Therefore, to match the data of total fertility rate per woman, we need to let n multiply 2.

(25)

factor (the weight of old age consumption) σ= 0.9930.

The parameter A= 5 in production function and λ = 3.5 in human cap- ital accumulation function, which does not influence qualitative results of our model, is used to match long-run growth rate of per capita out- put 2.5% (i.e. in the US 2.11% and 2.53% in Germany, Zhang and Zhang, 2003).

To calibrate total fertility rate, we need to adjust ϕ the fraction of time devoted to raise children and γ the weight of offspring quantity in the utility function. The studies of Robert Haveman and Barabra Wolfe(1995) and John Knowles(1999) show that parents spend about 15% of their time raising children.Accordingly, we choose ϕ = 0.15. The parameter γ is assigned to 0.26 (de la Croix and Doepke, 2003) to achieve average total fertility rate per woman 2.11 in United States during 2000− 2005.

Next, we use the elasticity δ of future human capital (wage income) with respect to public education expenditure and the weight of offspring quality in the utility function β to determine the ratio of public educa- tion expenditure to output. Johnson and Stafford(1973) estimated income elasticity for education expenditure was 0.198, another estimation of this figure provided by Card and Kreuger(1992) is 0.2. Since these estimations are similar, we set δ= 0.2.We choose β = 0.72 such that public education expenditure as a fraction of output fits the corresponding figure (public education expenditure for all level) in high income OECD countries at 2000, which is 4.8%.

The income replacement ratio of PAYG social security B is set to 0.43, which follows Pecchenino and Pollard(2002), for matching the social se- curity contribution rate 19%; this value is between the rates in France and US (Zhang and Zhang, 2003).

The remaining parameter θ is the share of income that goes to physical capital, following the previous literatures (see, for example, Boldrin,2005), we set θ = 0.3 as the calibrated value.The parameters of baseline model is summerized in Table 1.

(26)

Table 1: Calibrated values of baseline model

p= 0.5 λ = 3.5 A= 5 B = 0.43 θ = 0.3 δ= 0.2 ϕ = 0.15 γ = 0.26 β = 0.72 σ = 0.8 3.2 Comparing private and public education systems

In this section, we compare economic performance between public and private education regimes on the balanced growth path. From propsi- tion 2, we know that a private education regime at steady state has higher growth rate than a public education regime for any degree of longevity in an economy without PAYG social security program.

However, many developed countries execute PAYG social security sys- tem, whose tax rate is positive related to life expectancy and pension re- placement rate nowadays but negative related to labor force at present (the number of children in last generation). Proposition 3 indicates that an economy with a private education system has to suffer more PAYG so- cial security tax burden than one with a public education system. When the tax burden expands, it will bring about larger distortion of economic activity and slow down the growth rate of GDP per capita. This opens the possibility for a public education system boosting higher economic growth even if there is no income inequality in our simple model.

Next, we want to show that the institution of PAYG social security mat- ters when analyzing the economic effects of two educational systems. The way we use here is by changing two key parameters of PAYG social secu- rity tax rate, life expectancy and pension replacement ratio, to emphasize the importance of joint consideration of these two policies.

3.2.1 The effect of longevity

To investigate the effect of longevity under different education regimes, we take balanced growth rate comparison by varying the life expectancy over the interval from 63 years to 90 years (p= 0.1 to p = 1.0).

Fig. 2a shows given the ratio of earning replacement B = 0.43, the tax burden of PAYG social security increase with the extension of life ex-

(27)

pectancy. Due to low fertility rate, a private education regime (green line) has higher level of the PAYG social security tax rate than a public educa- tion regime (blue line) and the gap of tax rate between two regimes en- larges as life expectancy raise. Heavy tax burden of PAYG social security program has a very strong negative impact on investment in human and physical capital accumulation.

Figure 2: Life expectancies and education systems (a)

63 66 69 72 75 78 81 84 87 90

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

Life Expectancy

PAYG Social Security Tax Rate, %

Public Education Private Education

(b)

63 66 69 72 75 78 81 84 87 90

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18

Life Expectancy

Saving Rate, %

Public Education

Private Education

(c)

63 66 69 72 75 78 81 84 87 90

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Life Expectancy

Education Investment Ratio, %

Public Education Private Education

(d)

63 66 69 72 75 78 81 84 87 90

2 2.5 3 3.5

Life Expectancy

Balanced Growth Rate, %

Private Education

Public Education

Hence, we can find that a private schooling regime has less physcial capital investment than a public schooling regime at any extent of longevity (see Fig. 2b) and has less human capital investment than a public school- ing regime at sufficiently high level of life expectancy (see Fig. 2c). Be- cause of slow capital accumulation at the stage of high life expectancy (about 87 years), a private education system results in lower economic growth than a public education system (see Fig. 2d).

Table 2 gives two numerical examples to summerize the above find- ings. As shown in the first row of table 2, parents in a public school-

(28)

ing regime bear almost twice more number of children than in a pri- vate schooling regime. High fertility rate causes two opposite impacts on economic growth, the ”resource-dilution effect” and the ”tax-sharing effect”. However, the relative size of two effects depends on what degree of longevity an economy stays at. In a ”young” economy (life expectancy is 63 years), the ”tax-sharing effect” is smaller than the ”resource-dilution effect”, a public education system reuslts in less educational investment and then lower economic growth than a pirvate education system. On the contrary, in an ”old” economy (life expectancy is 87 years), the ”tax- sharing effect” dominates the ”resource-dilution effect”. A public educa- tion system leads faster capital accumulation and higher growth rate than a private education system. In sum, which education systems is better for long-run growth should hinge on how ”old” an economy is (the life ex- pectancy of an economy).

Table 2: Longevity and educational systems

Variables low longevity (p=0.1) high longevity (p=0.9) Private Public Private Public

FertilityTFR 1.16 2.59 1.01 2.10

Social Securityτ 7.38 3.31 76.04 36.78

SavingS 5.21 5.89 4.43 16.29

Education InvestmentE 18.89 8.75 4.82 4.64

Balanced Growthg 3.28 2.53 2.42 2.49

1 Except longevity, all parameters are the same as the setting in baseline model.

3.2.2 The effect of replacement ratio

In this section, we allow government can change her pension policy through varying pension replacement ratio from 10% of average earnings to 100%

of average earnings (B = 0.1 to B = 1.0).

If government raises pension replacement ratio (pension benefit for the aged), the level of PAYG social security tax will become higher and then have adverse impacts on physical capital accumulation (see Fig. 3b),

(29)

human capital accumulation (see Fig. 3c) and balanced growth rate (see Fig. 3d). Comparing two education systems, we find that a private ed- ucation system is more sensititve to the change of pension replacement ratio than a public education system, and furthermore a public education system can boost higher economic growth than a private education when government decides to provide sufficiently ”rich” pension benefit to the old.

Figure 3: Replacement ratios and education systems (a)

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

Replacement Ratio

PAYG Social Security Tax Rate, %

Public Education Private Education

(b)

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

0 5 10 15 20 25

Replacement Ratio

Saving Rate, %

Private Education Public Education

(c)

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Replacement Ratio

Education Investment Ratio, %

Public Education

Private Education

(d)

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4

Replacement Ratio

Balanced Growth Rate, %

Private Education Public Education

Table 3 gives two specific cases to illustrate that for maximizing eco- nomic growth what is the favored choice of education systems under dif- ferent policies of pension replacement rate. If govenment chooses the policy of low pension replacement ratio (B=0.2), growth rate in a pri- vate schooling regime is 3.52% higher than 2.86% in a public schooling regime. Contrariously, if govenment carries out the policy of high pen-

(30)

sion replacement rate (B=0.9), it is preferred to adopt a public education system (2.34%) rather than a private education system (2.02%). To sum up, in order to promote economic growth, government should coordinate educational policy and the benefit scheme of PAYG social security.

Table 3: Replacement ratio and educational systems

Variables low replacement (B=0.2) high replacement (B=0.9)

Private Public Private Public

FertilityTFR 1.01 2.18 1.11 2.35

Social Securityτ 19.82 9.17 81.35 38.20

SavingS 15.46 20.41 2.01 9.78

Education InvestmentE 16.15 7.76 3.78 4.89

Balanced Growthg 3.52 2.86 2.02 2.34

1 Except replacement ratio, all parameters are the same as the setting in baseline model.

3.3 Policy Implication: Subsidizing Private education

In previous section, we find that, because of low birth rate, a private ed- ucation system is more sensitive to the variation in life expectancy and pension replacement ratio than a public education system and then leads lower balanced growth rate when an economy with sufficiently high life expectancy and pension replacement rate. For this reason, it seems in- teresting to see whether growth can be promoted by implementing some policies, such as voucher program (subsidy of private education), which eliminates the educational expenditure per child and then encourage par- ents give more birth for sharing pension burden in an economy with

”great” PAYG social security program.

The intertemporal budget contraint for the households in a private schooling regime with voucher program can be revised as follows:

crtm+ 1 − vrtertnrt+ cort

rt+1 = 1 − τrt− qrt1 − ϕnrtwrthrt+ Vrt+1

rt+1 (37)

(31)

where vrt is subsidy rate of private education expenditure and qrt is a propotional tax for financing voucher program. Government also runs balanced budget to subsidize private education and the budget constraint of voucher program is:

vrtertnrt= qrt1 − ϕnrtwrthrt (38) where assume that the scale of voucher program is determined exoge- nously by government not by voting process.

Table 4 and 5 indicates that compared to private schooling regime (no subsidy, v=0), subsidizing educational fee per child can raise about 0.05–

0.07 (50% of subsidy, v=0.5) and 0.09–0.12 (90% of subsidy, v=0.9) total fertility rate and then reduce the tax burden of PAYG social security. The results also reveals that the relationship between the level of subsidy for private education and economic growth depends on the life expectancy of an economy and the policy of pension benefit.

In the case of low longevity or small pension replacement ratio, where

”resource-dilution” effect dominates ”tax-sharing” effect, more subsidy of educational investment results in lower economic growth. On the con- trary, when an economy has high life expectancy or implements the pol- icy of providing large pension benefit for old, ”tax-sharing” effect is stronger than ”resource-dilution” effect, government should provide more subsidy of educational investment to raise growth rate.

Table 4: Longevity and subsidy of education

Variables low longevity (p=0.1) high longevity (p=0.9) v=0 v=0.5 v=0.9 v=0 v=0.5 v=0.9

FertilityTFR 1.16 1.23 1.28 1.01 1.06 1.10

Social Securityτ 7.38 6.98 6.67 76.04 72.80 70.22

SavingS 5.21 5.27 5.32 4.43 5.14 5.73

Education InvestmentE 18.89 17.94 17.18 4.82 5.22 5.49 Balanced Growthg 3.28 3.23 3.19 2.42 2.49 2.54 1 Except longevity, all parameters are the same as the setting in baseline model.

(32)

Table 5: Replacement ratio and subsidy of education

Variables low replacement (B=0.2) high replacement (B=0.9)

v=0 v=0.5 v=0.9 v=0 v=0.5 v=0.9

FertilityTFR 1.01 1.06 1.10 1.11 1.16 1.21

Social Securityτ 19.82 18.94 18.24 81.35 77.42 74.29

SavingS 15.46 15.81 16.10 2.01 2.50 2.91

Education InvestmentE 16.15 15.55 15.08 3.78 4.34 4.73

Balanced Growthg 3.52 3.49 3.46 2.02 2.15 2.24

1 Except replacement ratio, all parameters are the same as the setting in baseline model.

4 Empirical Implications

The prediction of our model implies that comparing to a private school- ing system, a public schooling system can encourage parents to have more births and then leads to a lower tax rate of PAYG social security in the fu- ture. Due to the lack of data, there are few empirical studies examining the impact of educational systems and policies on macroeconomic variables or demographic structure across countries. In this section, we use the in- ternationally comparable data provided by OECD and WDI (World De- velopment Indicators) to investigate preliminary relationships between educational systems, birth rate and social security burden.

Table 6 lists the whole 17 countires in our sample. We especially choose these high income OECD countries for two reasons. First, the life ex- pectancy at birth in these countries are sufficiently high and similar to each other, which matches the demographic feature of our model and also controls the effect of longevity on fertility rate and social security tax rate. Second, some countries, for example Italy and Germany, also satify our standard but their data is not reliable6.

6we also use secondary private school enrollment rate in 1985 from UNSCO to check the reliability of our classification for education systems

(33)

Table 6: Education systems, fertility rate and social security

Country Percentage Share of Total Fertility Rate Chnage in Social security

Private Funding,% tax rate 1990-2003, %

Australia 15.93 1.87 1.62

Belgium 52.38 1.61 1.38

France 13.11 1.65 2.36

Netherlands 66.72 1.57 0.01

Spain 18.95 1.27 0.70

UK 31.04 1.82 2.64

US 18.44 2.02 2.27

Japan 24.92 1.46 5.51

Denmark 5.89 1.75 0.71

Canada 3.28 1.7 0.19

Luxembourg 4.37 1.69 -3.74

Norway 6.86 1.86 1.97

Finland 5.42 1.81 -1.90

Iceland 1.95 2.22 1.92

Swedn 1.31 2.00 1.13

New Zeland 1.01 2.05 -2.25

Switzerland 6.56 1.51 3.39

To classify education systems in our sample, we follow de la Croix and Doepke (2007) and choose 90% of the public share in all level educaton as a criterion. If an economy has ”more” than 90% of public funding for education in 1993, we assort this country to a group of public educaton system. If an economy has ”less” than 90% of public funding for education in 1993, we assort this country to a group of private educaton system.

Table 7: Fertility rate and private educational funding

Size of N.obs Average Share of Total

Private Edu. Private Funding,% Fertiltiy Rate

Large( 10%) 8 30.19 1.66

Samll( 10%) 9 4.07 1.84

Mean difference test -0.18 (t-stat=-1.67)

Fig. 4 and table 6 reveal that the countries with larger share of private funding for education ”seem” to have lower birth rates than those with larger share of public funding for education. Computing the correlation between the propotion of private educational spending in 1993 and total fertility rate in 1993, we find that the correlation coeffcient is −0.4070, which is moderately negative. Table 7 provides the mean difference test and shows the difference of total fertility rate between the countries with larger private sector and those with larger public sector is−0.1845, whose

數據

Figure 1: Dependency ratio age 65 above
Figure 2: Life expectancies and education systems (a) 63 66 69 72 75 78 81 84 87 900102030405060708090 Life Expectancy
Figure 3: Replacement ratios and education systems (a) 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.00102030405060708090 Replacement Ratio
Table 3: Replacement ratio and educational systems
+6

參考文獻

相關文件

社會 文化 意圖 手法.

第十條 香港特別行政區應當通 過學校、社會團體、媒體、網絡 等開展國家安全教育,提高香港 特別行政區居民的國家安全意識

社區 社會 社會氣氛整體良好 出現了不同的行業 。 ,以切合社區的需要 弱勢社群

五、第十二款經濟弱勢戶 與第四款中低收入戶 資格重複,又配合行 政院強化社會安全網 計畫,高度風險家庭 納入危機家庭之保護

個人、社會及人文教育 |英國語文教育| 藝術音樂教育 | STEM 教育 全球意識與文化敏感度 |體驗學習| 接觸大自然

[r]

甲、 秦朝的統一及其統治措施 乙、 漢武帝的統治政策與疆域拓展 丙、 昭宣以後的政治與社會的發展

結合 NPO 或 NGO 團體基於組織使命及發展推動文化與教育、觀光與